Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 1 - 19)

WEDNESDAY 14 JUNE 2006

MR DAVID FURSDON, PROFESSOR ALLAN BUCKWELL AND DR DERRICK WILKINSON

  Q1  Chairman: Good afternoon, ladies and gentlemen. Welcome to our first evidence session on the Committee's inquiry into the UK Government's vision for the Common Agricultural Policy. We welcome old friends of the Committee, the Country Land and Business Association, and in thanking them very much for their comprehensive and interesting written evidence we welcome David Fursdon, their President, Professor Allan Buckwell, the Chief Economist and Head of Land Use, and Dr Derrick Wilkinson, their Senior Economist. Gentlemen, one of the things which has been going through my mind as I have looked at the evidence for this inquiry was—and indeed the Committee had the pleasure of visiting Poland and Romania last week in pursuit of further background for this inquiry—what actually do we think the purpose of the Common Agricultural Policy is, because the "Vision" document is strong on drawing up lists of what a reformed Common Agricultural Policy might look like and it lists some of the things it would like to see coming out of it, but it made me ask myself the rather more fundamental question, what should this Common Agricultural Policy's purpose now be? Perhaps you might like to supply me with an answer?

  Professor Buckwell: Thank you, Chairman. If I could kick off on that one, in a word, changing. The purpose of the CAP is changing and that is the difficulty in a sense and the reason we are having a debate. The objectives are laid down in Article 39 of the Treaty of Rome, which is all to do with agriculture, food production and ensuring the standards of living of those engaged, stabilising supplies, and so on. Those were objectives which were absolutely understandable in the late fifties, early sixties, when it was set up and even for one or two decades thereafter, but what has happened since then is that we have added significant other demands which society places on its rural areas and its agriculture, and that increasingly involves delivering environmental services. So this did not figure at all in the original Articles, but it is now a core part of the current and future purpose of the policy, whilst at the same time trying to stimulate and encourage the industry to deliver food supplies, because that is what the fundamental job of agriculture is, and to improve quality, to improve marketing, and so on, but now increasingly to deliver these wider what I would call environmental and cultural landscape objectives.

  Q2  Chairman: Do you think it is quite important in a way that before one gets into the detail, the delivery mechanisms—which is what the "Vision" does in its long, what I call shopping list analysis—I looked around to see if they could define with some degree of clarity what the CAP's purpose actually is and it is very fuzzy. I could not quite get to the definitive paragraph. I have lists of what it might look like, but they talk about, in paragraph 1.32, "Against this background a sustainable CAP would comprise," and then there is a long list of what it would comprise of, but you are still left asking the question, what is the purpose?

  Professor Buckwell: We felt exactly the same, what is the purpose of this document? It is not a vision for agriculture, it is not a vision for land management or the countryside, which is where you might have thought we would have started with our vision for that and then said, what policy do we need to deliver that? This document does not provide this. To our reading, this is a list of what the Treasury and some Defra officials think is wrong with the current financing of the CAP. It is a rather narrowly focused document about the financing issues, and there is a very strong thrust in this that they want to significantly reduce the public expenditure cost of the countryside, which we think would be a huge mistake.

  Q3  Chairman: Did you make a cockshy yourself at remedying that failure of the document? I know you have produced your evidence, but you have been kind enough, if you like, to follow the mantra we laid down and answer the questions we put down. I just wondered if you had come back to a simple question of what is the purpose of the CAP? You have talked about the delivery of environmental goods—and we will come on to discuss that in some detail—but everybody talks about these environmental goods as if there was a pre-determined list of what it was we wanted.

  Professor Buckwell: You are absolutely right, Chairman. That is a complicated question to answer, if you want to start it now, but in terms of the purpose of the CAP there is a requirement—it is perfectly reasonable and sensible that the largest economic block in the world, the European Union, would want to have a policy for secure, stable supplies of its food, of high quality and food safety, and so on. So it is not at all surprising, particularly within a single market, that the European Union would want to have a policy covering that area. This is the basic needs of the population. When you add to that that Europe is unusual in many parts and most regions of the world in that its rural areas are also its playground. A huge amount of tourism and recreation takes place in the countryside. It is a managed countryside very largely, particularly in this country, less so in some of the other Member States but still to a high degree, and so of course this policy nowadays, given what society expects from the countryside, we would expect to have a very significant element of how that countryside is managed. I do not just mean agriculture, but of course that includes agriculture.

  Q4  Chairman: I suppose what was at the back of my mind was how common the policy needed to be, because one of the things which comes out from a lot of the evidence is that when you had a CAP which was production-focused then a common approach had some appeal. But now you have decoupled, if you like "doing your own thing" becomes more appealing as opposed to acting on commonality.

  Professor Buckwell: There are two reasons why we would be very cautious about that. First of all, as more of the policy is justified in environmental terms and as most of that environmental regulation is European—these are European standards, rightly, within a European market because you are regulating businesses within an open market—that is part of the justification. A huge element of these environmental concerns is trans-boundary. Insects, birds, and so on, do not respect national boundaries and water flows across national boundaries. These are the fundamental reasons why a very strong element of commonality is justified, but likewise we would be suspicious because there is a much stronger taste in other Member States to put public expenditure into agriculture per se, but it is necessary to have a common policy to hold the ring for competition reasons within the single market. Therefore, it is vital, in our view, that we cannot just simply walk away from a common policy, from where we are now within the European single market with all its regulation.

  Q5  Chairman: This document sort of came a bit like a bolt out of the blue. Why do you think it was produced when it was produced?

  Mr Fursdon: It was very surprising to us the way it arrived, the fact that it arrived without any prior consultation, without any obvious attempt to take the stakeholder group with them on this, and it was produced at comparatively short notice for us during the period of the UK presidency, and no doubt there were lots of political reasons why it came out in the way it did, but for us that was one of the big problems with it. Allan has already said that it was not a document about a vision for the future of agriculture, but for an awful lot of people in agriculture to suddenly have this document appear at the same time as—they had just gone through the mid-term review and the proposals from that—the Prime Minister was taking every opportunity to say that we needed further reform, when we had just been through it, this actually was part of the problem. It just heaped one sort of set of difficult circumstances on another for the farming industry. So it was a strange emergence for the paper, I have to say.

  Q6  Mr Williams: For the sake of clarity, I would like to put on the record that I am a member of the Country Land and Business Association, but I hope that will not deflect me from the questions I am going to put to you. You are critical of the paper for a number of reasons, but one in particular is that there is a lack of analysis as to the effect the "Vision" will have on the UK farming structure, employment, output, on the upstream and downstream effects of these changes and what will happen to the environment. Although you are critical, actually when we talked informally to the authors of the paper they felt that actually all the literature tended to show that the effects would be fairly minimal. How would you react to that?

  Dr Wilkinson: I wish they had put that evidence in the document then. It is clearly not here. There is a chapter, chapter 3, the implications of further CAP reform, which I assume is where their analysis on the consequences of their view lies. Let us, for example, talk about the upstream and downstream linkages, the implications for the rural economy. In paragraph 3.34 they begin by citing an OECD study of the region in England which concludes that agriculture has strong rural links, and then with the sleight of hand of a magician in the next paragraph suddenly in fact OECD available evidence says that this is all fairly stable or even increased in a number of Member States. So from one paragraph to the next they have got this sort of sleight of hand. Their entire analysis of the upstream and downstream linkages is, what, five short paragraphs and it cites three studies, only one of which relates to England, notwithstanding the fact that Defra has commissioned a lot of studies and it is quite capable of commissioning the relevant studies. They go on to talk about the consequences for the environment. We are treated to, what, four paragraphs on the environment where they do not seem to quite know whether or not they think that further CAP reform would lead to further intensification or not, but they certainly do not cite any work one way or the other. So we are talking there about the consequences of their vision for the rural economy, the English landscape and countryside, and we have got a total of nine paragraphs out of this entire document. I do not think that that is an appropriate analysis, quite frankly. What they are suggesting, if we have a look in here, is that agricultural spending should be reduced to the current levels of Pillar 2 funding, that is to say a 90% reduction in support over a 10 to 15 year period. What are the consequences of that? Absolutely no analysis whatsoever. That seems to me, if it is not too strong, a dereliction of their duty as a department to put forward policies which are based upon careful, well-thought out and balanced analyses. This, sadly, is lacking.

  Q7  Mr Williams: So what would your assessment be of the impact if the "Vision" was implemented as far as the CAP is concerned?

  Dr Wilkinson: Quite clearly the CLA does not have the resources of Defra and the Treasury combined, so we are not in a position to offer you a clear analysis of that. What we could say, I think, at this point is that we do understand the imperatives in terms of the budget and the changing needs of society, and so forth, but we also understand that the Pillar 1 funding, the support, if you take that away from farmers right now—the core business of farming lost £500 million last year. It loses money year in and year out, that is the core business, without support. We all buy into the fact that farming needs to be better connected to the market, it has to find market opportunities for a sustainable future, but over a 10 year period? Is there any analysis anywhere which suggests that market returns to farmers, whether from commodity production, from diversified activities, or even indeed from the new non-food opportunities, are going to provide an increase of, let us say, two to £3 billion a year on a stable basis over the next few years? I have not seen any of that analysis. What we would like to do is engage in that discussion to see some of that work being done and to have a sensible debate about what the future for farming and the countryside is.

  Q8  Mr Williams: I think some of the models which were put forward by the academics were of countries where agricultural support had been eliminated or greatly reduce, that there was not much effect really on agriculture?

  Dr Wilkinson: Indeed.

  Q9  Mr Williams: I guess we are looking at New Zealand?

  Dr Wilkinson: Correct.

  Q10  Mr Williams: Could you suggest any other countries?

  Dr Wilkinson: No. New Zealand is an interesting example on several counts. First of all, it is a small country. Nobody else has ever done it or even tried, or even contemplated it. We have to remember, when we are talking about New Zealand, it is different. There are differences and those differences are not often brought out. For example, when they did their overnight liberalisation, withdrawal of support if you will, they also did a number of other things. They did provide exit grants for those who wanted to leave, but—and this is crucial, and interestingly not mentioned in here when they went on at some length about New Zealand—if you have a look at the exchange rate (and remember 90% of New Zealand's farm output is exported so the exchange rate is critical), as you lead into that it was very, very low. The New Zealand dollar was very low, so farm incomes were reasonably good. It then peaked in about 1988 when they did this liberalisation. Quite how they timed it, I do not know, but it was brilliant timing. They had this lovely run-up of good farm incomes up to a peak and then it went right down again. There was about 15% devaluation within 12 months, which stayed there until only about two years ago. So the exchange rate really worked for them. They also have a government and a ministry which supports them, which is actually proud of them and tries to help them. It has got a competition policy which allows their companies to grow up to world-scale, such as Fonterra, where we do not have that here. So there is a number of differences which need to be borne in mind. Yes, as I said, we do understand that farming needs to be more engaged with the market and get better market returns, we all want that, but we have to be realistic about it.

  Q11  Mr Williams: When the Committee visited Brussels recently, senior members of the European Union Commission were critical of the "Vision" document in the sense that it did not give an indication of how farm structures would be involved as a result of this implementation, if it was implemented. That is critical to our understanding of rural communities, particularly in some more rural countries like France, for instance. Have you got any ideas? You have not got the capacity of Defra, but you might have the imagination to tell us how farm structures could be affected by these proposals.

  Dr Wilkinson: Probably the beginning assumption is that the trends in farm structures would accelerate very, very rapidly, and those trends briefly, as far as farm size, are that we have got a very, very rapid growth of the very tiny, what some people call "hobby farms", and a fairly stable number of the very large farms, although they are getting bigger. They are the ones which produce 80% of the food supply of this country. There are about 10,000 of them. We are losing that middle ground, the family farms. That will accelerate under this type of scenario. There are some 550,000 jobs, farmers and jobs directly in farming. The loss of farmers and farm workers will accelerate. The knock-on in the broader rural economy is that we have got about 50,000-odd in the food supply chain—I am thinking there of the farm suppliers and the wholesalers, just one away from farms—and clearly they are going to get hurt as well. So there is going to be a lot of unemployment, a lot faster unemployment, and we have to remember that while those figures might not seem very large in the scheme of things, this is going to be largely out in the more rural areas where there are fewer opportunities for people to do things there, so then they will have to leave those areas, and again you are going to end up with all the problems of people having to leave the countryside because they cannot afford to be there any more, and so on and so forth. There is a number of working assumptions we could begin with, but, as I say, we have not been able to do the analysis. We want to see the analysis done and we want to see the debate begin.

  Q12  David Taylor: It is about 1% of GDP, is it not?

  Dr Wilkinson: It is less than that, actually, it is about 0.7, 0.9. It depends which year we are talking about. Farm incomes have fallen back again the last three years in a row.

  Mr Fursdon: Chairman, could I just add one point to that? Part of what lies behind this whole thing is that it will be better for the environment if we go down this route, and yet you would expect also some analysis to have been done on how the effects of these changes in structure might affect the environment as well, and the assumption that if people are going to have to compete in a world market they are not going to be intensive and that the only intensive agriculture is associated with the CAP supported agriculture is, I think, simplistic.

  Q13  Mr Drew: If I could just take up your point about your views on the "Vision" document, the problem is that in a sense the historic contradictions of the way in which the CAP has operated, and will operate, inevitably means that you have got a very divergent series of countries now within the CAP. Why is it we cannot look at options including, on the one hand, complete repatriation of the monies to national agriculture and, on the other hand, something to the extent that we might have a fully integrated market where you give every encouragement to those less developed countries to change their agriculture rather than a dependent income and production-based scenario, one which actually moves in the direction we all seem to want to go, which is to pay farmers to do things which are public goods and produce the alternatives to food production which everyone seems to crave after? Is that something the CLA has been interested in and done some work on?

  Professor Buckwell: Yes, we are interested in that and, yes, we have done work on this. You made some very important points there. First of all, that there are quite different requirements around the European Union. This is absolutely true and it is quite hard, as the Chairman was saying earlier, to see what is the commonality. My answer is that we need a common framework, and insist on that, but in fact it is not the current CAP. There has to be a common framework all the while we are in a single market with common regulation. The point about repatriation—and I do not like the use of that word—is that it has been agreed, we thought, in principle, and we are shocked at the way Defra and the Treasury threw away the principle in December that Pillar 2, in a sense the good CAP, the rural development, the agri-environment part of the CAP, was traditionally co-financed and the principle was precisely because the requirements amongst the various measures offered in Pillar 2 are different. The different Member States choose differently from the menu there and they should, of course, quite reasonably tip in some of their own funds to ensure that they only go in for programmes which make good value for money.

  Q14  Mr Drew: As usual, when it came to the budget renegotiations, it was the rural dimension which was the main—

  Professor Buckwell: It was cut.

  Q15  Mr Drew: That is where all the cuts were across the board. We in Britain were as guilty as the traditional agriculture subsidy nations and unless you can change that mindset—and to be fair it is totally unhelpful, going through Romania and Poland last week, to be leading them in a direction in which we do not want them to go, but they have to go there to move in our direction later, which seems a completely barmy way of undertaking policy.

  Professor Buckwell: I quite agree, which is why we put on the table for discussion last summer, when these discussions were still at an early stage, that rather than reducing the co-financing of Pillar 2 we should talk about increasing the co-financing of Pillar 1, and then the Member States such as France and Spain, who are some of the biggest beneficiaries of it, might take a different attitude if they had to pay more for it themselves. That is one of several ingredients which will certainly be discussed in the next review in two or three years' time, but the fact is that the opportunity to do that was not taken this time and instead we have gone almost in the reverse direction, reducing the co-financing in Pillar 2, which we are very upset about for the same reasons as Mr Drew mentioned.

  Chairman: We will come back and look at this matter again a little later on.

  Q16  Lynne Jones: In terms of reducing the spending on Pillar 2, the Government says that that was not their idea and it was the inevitable consequence of trying to negotiate for a budget reduction overall and it was a presidency compromise. Do you accept that position? If so, did the Government have any alternative?

  Professor Buckwell: It is an incredible way of describing it. The reality was that there was a decision to reduce the overall budget and there was an acceptance that Prime Ministerial agreement had already been made to maintain the Pillar 1 budget, so therefore the consequences of that was inevitably a slashing of Pillar 2 funding. It was as sure as night follows day that would come from those two policy decisions which this Government took, so there can be no pretending that we were surprised and we were not really wanting that outcome. It was a deliberate contrivance or outcome of the decisions it had made. So the question is, what do we do about that now? This is why we are saying what we do not like about this whole "Vision" document is that it is just hell-bent on reducing public expenditure on the countryside, instead of standing back and asking the question which the Chairman did at the outset, "What do we want the policy to do?". We in the CLA have certainly said that the way we are supporting the countryside has to change.

  Q17  Lynne Jones: So you are saying that the Government should have predicted that that would be the inevitable outcome and therefore to blame the presidency is really disingenuous?

  Professor Buckwell: They were the presidency, as far as I know.

  Q18  Lynne Jones: To blame the Commission, sorry.

  Professor Buckwell: Yes, I agree.

  Q19  Lynne Jones: Moving back in terms of Pillar 1 and Pillar 2, the Government's line is that spending directly on targeted agri-environment schemes is more effective in providing environmental goods and services than the imposition of cross compliance measures for Pillar 1. Do you accept that as a point of principle?

  Professor Buckwell: We accept that the payment for public services is going to be a major part (not the whole part, but a major part) of the enduring public support for rural areas. The question now is, how do you do that? The problem, as we see it, is that you would not start from where we are, but the trouble is we are where we are. We are paying large sums of money, roughly £200 per hectare in England, on the Pillar 1 schemes. It is a bit less than that after deductions, but as a round figure. We are paying £30 per hectare for entry level stewardship, and then varying larger sums on a much more selective basis for the higher stewardship. Those figures do not make any sense. Had the £200 per hectare in the Pillar 1 payments not been there, you would have had to have paid an awful lot more than £30 per hectare to have got the delivery from the basic stewardship scheme, but the reason why you only need £30 is because you are giving them £200. Trying to unravel that knot is the challenge and all we are saying is that you do not unravel that mess by just saying, "Slash Pillar 1, end of story." We have got to find a way of either targeting the environmental payments in Pillar 1 or switching the money to Pillar 2, but there are all these co-financing problems about doing that. That is the knot we are trying to untie.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2007
Prepared 24 May 2007