Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Minutes of Evidence


Joint memorandum submitted by Defra and HM Treasury (CAP 30)

  1.  This joint memorandum provides Defra's and HM Treasury's written evidence to the Committee's Inquiry into the UK Government's paper "A Vision for the Common Agricultural Policy".

  2.  The paper was designed as a contribution to the debate already underway on how to achieve a sustainable future for agriculture and to help answer those who have asked what the UK Government means when it calls for further CAP reform. It raises questions about the effectiveness, sustainability and affordability of the current Common Agricultural Policy, presents a vision for what a sustainable model of European agriculture might look like and considers the implications of further reform. It further examines agricultural protectionism at a global level, with a particular focus on the impact of developed country policies on developing countries.

  3.  Radical change of the sort proposed in this paper has to be seen in the longer-term perspective. The vision in this paper focuses on where we need to be in 10 to 15 years time, and why. It does not set out a detailed route map for getting there.

  4.  This memorandum addresses the issues raised by the Committee in its press notice. The evidence and the Government's position are set out more fully in the paper.

EXPENDITURE ON "PILLAR 1" OF THE CAP

  5.  The Government's vision questions the justification for existing expenditure in Pillar 1 of the CAP (market support and direct payments) and recommends phasing out all support by 2020. The EFRA Committee is interested in the likely impact of these proposals, with specific reference to:

Food security—does the Government remain committed to UK food production?

  6.  The Government will always seek to promote sustainable UK food production. This is clear from the work we have undertaken in collaboration with the farming industry to implement the Strategy for Sustainable Farming and Food. One of the key principles for that strategy is the production of safe, healthy food in response to market demands, and we continue to support this. Whilst the Government does not have a self-sufficiency target, in 2003, the UK was 76.9% self sufficient in respect of "indigenous type food and drink," and of the indigenous type food and drink imported into the UK, the other 24 members of the EU accounted for 72.9% by value. Research suggests (see paragraph 3.44 of the vision paper) that agricultural self-sufficiency of richer countries would decline only modestly as a result of liberalisation. Furthermore, the position of UK farmers at the heart of one of the world's richest markets should not be overlooked.

  7.  However, it is important not to equate food security with self-sufficiency. As the vision paper sets out (p 47), domestic production is neither a necessary nor sufficient condition for food security. For example, many of the inputs used by UK farmers are sourced from overseas, and trying to ensure food security solely by promoting domestic production would ignore the global dimension of modern food production. Furthermore, relying on domestic production alone does not insulate a country from risks such as climate change, natural disasters, fluctuations in world markets, health crises etc The widening of trade opportunities should be good for international food security, and thus for UK food security.

  8.  It is also worth noting that the number of farmers or farms is not a direct indicator of food security or self-sufficiency. Over 80% of UK food production now comes from just one quarter of all farms, with the largest 10% of farms producing over half of total food output.

Potential distortions and inequality of treatment of farmers across the EU

  9.  Phasing out market support and direct payments would reduce distortion and inequality of treatment of farmers across the EU. The CAP has traditionally favoured certain products over others, and prevented farmers from responding to market signals. As the vision paper notes, the CAP is an inefficient way of supporting farmers, and many of the benefits accrue to landowners, who may or may not be farmers. Phasing out market support and direct payments and moving towards the more sustainable vision for agriculture presented in the paper would reduce these existing distortions, and lead to a situation where farmers in the EU were competing solely on the basis of price, quality and other market demands.

  10.  It would be important to ensure that EU state aid rules for agriculture, as for other sectors, were fit for purpose and rigorously enforced, in order that any national aids such as those to secure environmental objectives did not create new distortions.

Possible environmental consequences of the proposals

  11.  The intensification of agriculture in the EU over the last 20 to 30 years has caused significant environmental problems such as water pollution and damage to wildlife and bio-diversity, as evidenced by the steep decline in farmland bird populations across the EU. Cleaning up diffuse water pollution caused by agriculture is estimated to cost £211 million a year in the UK, another cost ultimately borne by all citizens in their water bills. This intensification has been amplified by the high levels of market price support in the CAP: an incentive our vision would remove. Whilst aspects of the CAP such as cross-compliance and set-aside can have positive environmental benefits, these could be secured in a more efficient and targeted way.

The extent to which the proposed changes to the CAP would result in lower food prices and (through reduced public spending on the CAP) a lower level of taxation

  12.  The financial costs of the CAP are set out in some detail in the paper, and are estimated by the OECD at around €100 billion for the EU25, half due to higher food prices and half due to taxes. It is difficult to predict the precise extent to which further CAP reforms would lower food prices, as other macroeconomic factors will also have an effect on future food prices. However, as the vision paper notes (p 20), it has been estimated that the CAP is equivalent to a value added tax on food of about 15%. Reform away from price support would lead to a fall in average prices (as measured by the Consumer Price Index) throughout the EU of around 0.9%. It would also enable a substantial reduction or redirection of the EU budget and consequent alleviation of the burden on the UK taxpayer.

How such a revised CAP would enable the EU's farmers to be more competitive

  13.  At present the CAP regulatory framework acts as a barrier to entrepreneurship and the natural evolution of the industry. The benefits of the CAP accrue primarily to the initial owners of land and other inputs, inflating costs and making it difficult and expensive for others to enter farming, or for more efficient producers to expand their operations. The support currently provided by the CAP allows farms to continue operating inefficiently at relatively high costs of production.

  14.  In a liberalised CAP, these barriers would be removed and the industry would adjust, be free to grow and make efficiency gains like any other industry. The reforms of 2003 are a significant step in reconnecting farmers with markets, and further liberalising reforms would carry on this trend. This does not mean that farms would necessarily become more intensive (indeed there are good reasons to believe that many would become less intensive, as explained in the paper).

How the proposals would differently affect the tenanted and non-tenanted sectors across the EU

  15.  Adjustment in agriculture is the norm. The sector is constantly adjusting, even when it benefits from high levels of support. Policy reform is but one additional (although significant) source of adjustment pressure. A reduction in agricultural prices as a result of reduced levels of support would reduce agricultural profitability in the short term, until agricultural costs are bid back down. As the paper notes, well functioning land markets are critical to the process of structural change, to securing economies of size, to diversification, to maintaining international competitiveness and to securing credit. If the Government's vision were implemented, the tenanted sector across the EU would experience a temporary fall in profitability before benefiting from lower rents. Owner-occupiers and non-farming landowners would see the agricultural value of their farmland fall, although it should be remembered that the agricultural value of land is only part of the price of agricultural land.

  16.  The impact on individuals would also depend in part on the time at which the land had been purchased. As explained in the paper, capitalisation of support means that the benefits have accrued primarily to those in farming when the various elements were introduced. Those who have held land all this time have had a windfall gain and would have a windfall loss.

The implications of the proposals for the applicant countries to the EU

  17.  As it currently exists, the CAP does not provide the right framework for agriculture to restructure and modernise and actually works against sustainable rural development. Like the 10 new Member States, Bulgaria and Romania should gain from a reformed CAP which targets resources at the development of rural infrastructure, services and the creation of diverse employment opportunities. The same applies to Croatia and Turkey.

THE RURAL ECONOMY

  18.  The Committee is interested in how the UK's rural economy would fare under the changes proposed in the report.

  19.  The paper notes that even in the most rural regions agricultural employment is by no means dominant. In areas defined as "predominantly rural" in the UK in 2001, the rate of agricultural employment was only 7.2% (Table 3.5). While agriculture has strong links with other rural industries, the paper quotes an OECD study which found that while farm employment has been on a long term decline, employment in closely related industries has remained stable or even increased (3.35). And over the past decades there has been a strong trend of a shift of employment from agriculture to other industries. This suggests that the rural economy has already adjusted to changes in the agriculture industry, and will do so in future. Furthermore, the vision paper states (1.32) that future EU spending on agriculture should be based on the current Pillar II. Pillar II funding is directly targeted at agri-environment schemes and other public goods which stimulate the rural economy.

INTERNATIONAL ISSUES

  20.  The Committee is interested in the report's assessment of the impact of CAP reform on developing countries, and its conclusions about the erosion of trade preferences and the potential benefits of a liberalised agricultural market in the EU and other OECD countries. The Committee is also interested in the effect the proposals would be likely to have on the global economy more widely.

  21.  The paper sets out (4.4 onwards) how EU protectionism and market price support in particular are damaging to developing countries. The paper cites IMF predictions that suggest that while preference erosion will cause serious adjustment problems for a relatively small number of countries, it is unlikely to be a significant problem for the majority. The challenge will be to ensure that complementary policies and additional finance is provided alongside agricultural reform, in order to alleviate the short to medium term shock of preference erosion.

  22.  Most of the available studies assume agricultural liberalisation as part of a wider WTO round, and it is therefore difficult to say what the effects on the EU, other OECD countries and the global economy would be. The paper quotes World Bank figures which suggest that global income could increase by $290 billion by 2015 if trade-distorting policies in merchandise trade including agriculture were eliminated (4.3).

THE WIDER DEBATE ON FUTURE FINANCING OF THE CAP

  23.  The EFRA Committee is interested in how the reforms proposed in the report could be achieved in practice, and how these changes relate to the ongoing debate surrounding the future financing of the CAP. What barriers might be put in the way of implementing such reforms by other EU member states?

  24.  The Government set out broad parameters of how its vision could be achieved in practice in its paper, particularly in paragraphs 1.33 to 1.37. Gradual and carefully managed change will be important to give clear signals and time for farmers to adjust their businesses.

  25.  One important component of the Government's vision is an end to the market support mechanisms and direct payments. The elimination of export subsidies following completion of the Doha Round, a move the Government has championed, will provide a major impetus for reform of the first. Direct payments could be phased out in a number of different ways. For example, the House of Lords European Union Committee recommended that the single farm payment should continue only until 2013[1]. Other approaches might involve different profiles. The vision paper was published to stimulate debate, and these are the kinds of issue which will need to be debated with stakeholders in the UK and in the EU, including with other Member States in the context of the review of the EU budget in 2008-09.

March 2006





1   House of Lords European Union Committee, 2nd Report of Session 2005-06, The Future Financing of the Common Agricultural Policy, HL Paper 7-I. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2007
Prepared 24 May 2007