Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 320 - 333)

WEDNESDAY 18 OCTOBER 2006

MR PETER KENDALL, MR MARTIN HAWORTH AND MS CARMEN SUÁREZ

  Q320  Mr Drew: Presumably they did not take the practice from Accenture, but we will pass on from that quickly. In terms of decoupling (and what I asked Mrs Fischer Boel), the difficulty I have is that one could understand if the EU was a static organisation and you could move all the vehicles on the track eventually in the same direction, but it is not a static organisation. We are, by definition, now about to see another group of new entrants coming in who have a view, at least initially, on getting support, direct payments to their farmers as an incentive to enter into the EU. How can we pretend that we can see, within the foreseeable future, full decoupling? She was very honest and said 2008 will be a mixture of review and it will be exactly that, there will be no principal alterations, but she then qualifies that by saying we will get to full decoupling, but how and when and where is the evidence that this is going to start moving quicker rather than at the very slow rate at which it is happening at the moment?

  Mr Kendall: I think it is easy enough to do. I do not see because we are an expanding EU that should be break-off point. We have always had countries that have joined the European Union, we have accession periods. What we do have is a single market where we have single regulations. We do have tariff protection around the whole European Union. That is what makes it so important that we do have a single set of rules within that European market. We know that as countries join the EU they sometimes have a six or eight year period of transition where they have a chance to adapt to our CAP rules and regulations. So, I think we should set a bold target when we move to full decoupling. As a country (and we have had it in the United Kingdom) that has absorbed full decoupling, I would like that to be sooner rather than later, and I think we should encourage all the Member States to do that. The accession countries would obviously be given time to adjust to that as their payments increase.

  Mr Haworth: Could I add a supplementary as well. I do not see the enlargement of the European Union as making it more difficult to get to a common policy; indeed, I would say it would make it easier because eight of the ten new Member States have got an even more decoupled system than we have, the two new Member States coming in next year will also have that, and the direction of travel is clearly that, in fact, all Member States will move over to the system which is now being implemented in the new Member States. That is the only way in which you are going to get back to a common policy. The question really is one of timing, when that can be achieved. I think you have to acknowledge that the new Member States have got a far more decoupled policy than even we have in this country.

  Q321  David Taylor: Two brief questions, Chairman, to Mr Kendall, I think. I hope I am not going back too far. You referred to the dilemma that your Welsh members will encounter. Are you at this point actively promoting or hoping for a cut in those area payments for your Welsh members so as to achieve uniformity and parity with their English counterpart?

  Mr Kendall: No, we are not. We have a relationship with Wales where they have their own policy-making council, but I certainly acknowledge their concerns about moving to a flat-rate system. I think they acknowledge that, in the fullness of time, they will make adjustments to their system to receive payments based on 2001-02 history. When we get to 2013 it is going to become increasingly untenable, so they accept that at some point this debate will have to occur. At the moment, and you can understand their real concern, they see a system implemented in England that gives them absolutely no confidence whatsoever that this is realistic or even welcome, particularly when you see in England we had 40,000 new claimants, which has acted as an absolute bottleneck to the delivery of a single payment this last year.

  Q322  David Taylor: I take that as a, "No", then. There is obviously quite a wide range of single payment models and rates of modulation across the EU. Does the existence of that position significantly affect the production decisions of your own members and, if so, how?

  Mr Haworth: One thing that is absolutely certain is that, once you have got lots of different systems operating across a single market, there is a strong perception that these things are affecting competition. It is actually often quite difficult to pin it down. There are some things that certainly do affect production, and the clear ones here would be different levels of cross-compliance where some countries have much more onerous levels than others, there would be differences in that some countries have decoupled fully and some have not. These are clearly distortions. You come into more difficult territory where you have got single farm payments being implemented in a different way which, on the face of it, probably seem to advantage some people and disadvantage others in some Member States and against others. From an economic point of view, it is quite difficult to pin that down and say this is definitely a distortion, but certainly all farmers across Europe think there are distortions, and maybe that amounts to the same thing. For that reason alone, we are keen to get back to a much more common system.

  Q323  Chairman: I think I sense that you think that farming in the United Kingdom could not survive without any kind of Pillar 1 support. Is that right?

  Mr Kendall: I think I tried to point out that while the rest of the world is supporting its agriculture, we would not want to see the UK agriculture thrown to some New Zealand—

  Q324  Chairman: When you say "the rest of the world", the Cairns Group might take issue with that statement, might they not?

  Mr Kendall: I am sure they would.

  Q325  Chairman: You cannot say "the rest of the world", some bits of the world.

  Mr Kendall: Absolutely correct. I am sorry.

  Q326  Chairman: There has been a lot of emphasis on movement into Pillar 2. Do you think that the environmental payment structure as currently constituted is going to be sufficiently robust to address the land abandonment issue that you mentioned in your opening remarks?

  Mr Kendall: We are still awaiting a review of the HFA scheme which is currently being talked about within Defra. I am not aware of what the full implications will be of agri-environment schemes for the hill farming areas, so I cannot really comment. I do think we now have a problem with funding of Pillar 2 and the agri-environment schemes and I do not see it necessarily is a key part of preventing land abandonment. I think the hill farming replacement scheme would be absolutely critical and how we can find ways of supporting production in more remote areas, but I think for tourism and land management they deliver very real public goods. That is the challenge we are going to face.

  Q327  Mr Drew: Just answer the question. Does land abandonment matter, in the sense that we are talking about very isolated land, because otherwise, by its very nature, there will be alternative uses? Have you done any work on the implications for farmers who remain of the impact of land abandonment?

  Ms Suárez: I think that there are two issues that we need to distinguish. One is what is the implication of land abandonment for the countries that do stay in production in those areas? There you could argue that it is going to be lack of access to facilities of production, lack of infrastructure, and so on, that would actually make things more difficult for the people that stay in production. In terms of what is the actual social and environmental value of maintaining land in production, there have been studies that have been done by Defra and other government departments, and that informed the revision of the HFA Policy Review, that have put a value to that land and to that land being maintained in production. I suppose that the short answer is, yes, we do believe that land abandonment does matter.

  Mr Kendall: The figures I have seen certainly indicate the value of rural tourism is rated at about £14 billion, and I think that is a big indication of the way the land is managed and looked after. I see certain parts of the country. In my part of the world I have seen where set-aside has been poorly managed and the papers are full of criticism of land being managed in a laissez-faire manner; so I do think we produce a fantastic British countryside, as farmers, and that is valuable to the tourist industry.

  Ms Suárez: There is another issue also. Land is not an input of production that you can switch on and off. To some extent there are some consequences of land abandonment that would be quite difficult to rectify later on. I think, because of that, any policy decision that may lead to land abandonment has to be considered with special care.

  Q328  Chairman: Could we move on to your assessment of the move towards Pillar 2. First of all, the United Kingdom, until fairly recent times, was not wildly interested in rural development activities. It now is, and you are presented with the UK proposal to have up to 20% voluntary modulation as a way of funding, as I see it, the deficit in the rural development budget. Given the emphasis in the `Vision' document on Pillar 2, it would be interesting to have your observations, if you like, on the short-term over the 20% modulation issue. The second one is perhaps to give us a flavour of how the NFU sees the overall rural development programme. I recently had a look at the 2005 report, and I think that my initial concern was limited amount of jam spread thinly, particularly when it came to economic activity other than those programmes which were specifically focused on environmental outcomes. The question really is: is Pillar 2 a viable vehicle for helping to sustain the rural economy in England and Wales either (a) in the way it is presently funded or (b) taking into account the kind of modulation proposals the Government has or (c) Mrs Fischer Boel's idea of an increase in modulation but a statutory one up to 10%?

  Mr Kendall: I certainly favour Mariann Fischer Boel's view of going to 10%. Of course the European uniform level, what level it is, is to be determined by our partners in Europe. What bothers me about 20% modulation is, I have talked already about disparity between systems, between favouring one country against another, and if I could see an English farmer having 20% modulation and on a regional trajectory, he could find himself receiving half the payment of a farmer doing exactly the same in the Paris basin, for example. That is a big distortion. You talk about whether the Pillar 2 money is the correct way forward. I still see, as a priority, profitable agricultural production as being important vehicle. So, to take money off a farmer who is doing exactly the same in the same market place (the European market) as a competitor I see as a dangerous move that could risk us losing production within that market place. However, the entry level scheme and the higher-tiered scheme, I think, are delivering real benefits. They are certainly now a part of a lot of our work on managing nutrients more effectively, on reversing the decline in certain farmyard bird numbers; so we see the entry level scheme and higher tiered scheme as valuable tools. But it does worry me, because of historic rural development funding, because of the fact that money now does not have to be match-funded because of the bad CAP budget deal that was done prior to Christmas—we can have 20% take-up for the UK with no match-funding—that is very worrying. So, as to your point about the Commissioner's proposal of uniform modulation to fund Pillar 2, it is certainly beneficial. I think, because of historic rural development funding, we cannot do the additional work you talk about where the jam is being spread thinly. We cannot do that because of our poor historical allocation, but we should be able to fund, I hope, our agri-environment schemes, which I see as being very important to the plans we have for agriculture.

  Q329  Mr Williams: The Single Farm Payment goes straight on the bottom line of farmers' accounts. Pillar 2 expenditure is not so simple. We know how much is spent on Pillar 2, but have you done any work estimating how much sticks to farmers' profitability in terms of the percentage of the total expenditure?

  Mr Haworth: You are right to say that there is a much bigger cost involved in Pillar 2 than there is in Pillar 1. So, yes, less of it goes to the bottom line, but the agri-environment schemes, so long as co-funding is maintained—I would emphasise that—we do think there is a net benefit to the farmers involved here.

  Mr Kendall: As somebody who is engaging at the moment on looking at entry level schemes—I still have not been accepted into an entry level scheme, but we are doing the work—in the early years the costs are more significant. Preparing margins in a good and fit state: they actually want managing pretty intensively for the first year—the seed the planting and all the rest of it. I do not see any positive gain from my entry level scheme probably until year three, and so I think it is a very valid point that Pillar 1 does stick to the bottom line and is helping contribute to my income.

  Q330  Mr Williams: Have you any plans to try to estimate what the effect on profitability of Pillar 2 expenditure is?

  Mr Haworth: We have done some work and Carmen may want to comment on it, but by and large I would say the costs involved to a farmer in Pillar 1 are probably around 5%, in Pillar 2 they would vary, and, as Peter said, they are probably higher in the earlier years, but we would say that they would not be higher than 40%.

  Ms Suárez: The other issue that is probably quite interesting to point out is that, as you have indicated, Pillar 1 goes to the bottom line of the business and as such the existence of Pillar 1 supports itself and makes the uptake of Pillar 2 programmes more likely, i.e. if Pillar 1 payments were not there in the first place people would not be signing up to an entry level scheme, to a higher level scheme at the same level of payments and at the same level of uptake that we have right now. So the separation in the `Vision' document between Pillar 1 and Pillar 2 payments is to some extent simplistic because there is a connection between Pillar 2 payments and the delivery of public goods and services.

  Q331  Chairman: In other words, you cannot have one without the other.

  Ms Suárez: You cannot have one in its present form without the other. If so, one of the things that is quite interesting, for lack of a better word, in the document is that it does talk about the delivery of public goods and services through Pillar 2, but it does not define what is the kind of Pillar 2 that we are likely to have in place by then, and it does not indeed define what is understood by public goods and services. How do we define them and how do we go about rewarding for the provision of public goods and services?

  Q332  Chairman: We have made this point in our reports before. Defra, as I understand it, has made some attempt to quantify the value that non-agricultural people put on these public goods, but I am not aware of any effort to define what the public good output should be, how much of these things that we want and, therefore, how much should we pay for them. Do you think that there should be an exercise to try and answer that question in the context of developing Pillar 2 activity?

  Ms Suárez: I have not got any exercise whether it derives to an act or a number or not and whether there are going to be questions around that number, but I think that is an intellectual exercise. It will, indeed, be very valuable and I think that it will help to focus the debate about the original document, because at this stage it is very difficult for us to talk in very general terms about public goods, public services, Pillar 1, Pillar 2, without having more detail of what it implies.

  Mr Haworth: Your question is a very good one, and what we must avoid is to repeat the mistakes of the old CAP, where people were encouraged to produce physical goods which actually there was not a market for. We do not want to make the same mistake, encouraging people to produce what are called non-market goods for society which actually society does not value. So, I think it is a very important point that you made.

  Q333  Chairman: Forgive me; I am going to stop your evidence session at this stage. We have got two other sets of witnesses we have to get through and I am very conscious that, if we do not try and squeeze everybody in by about half past five, we are going to find ourselves in a series of votes which will disrupt everything for the rest of the day. Thank you very much indeed for your contribution and also for your supplementary evidence which I think brings up to date some of your commentary on particularly the remarks that Mrs Fischer Boel will be making, so thank you very much for that.





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2007
Prepared 24 May 2007