Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Written Evidence


Supplementary memorandum submitted by Sandy Luk (ELD 20a)

IN RESPONSE TO EVIDENCE SESSION OF 13 JUNE 2007

  Please note that the text in italics reflects the author's understanding only of the evidence given by Mr. Ian Pearson, MP, Mr Nigel Atkinson and Ms Caroline Connell to the EFRA Committee on 13 June 2007.

1.  THE HIGH DAMAGE THRESHOLDS

  According to the UK Government's analysis of the potential economic and practical impact of the Environmental Liability Directive (ELD), it would seem that the ELD will have very little effect in the UK, only applying in less than 1% of all environmental damage cases. This assessment is made because the damage thresholds under the ELD are perceived to be extremely high ("significant adverse effects" etc).

  There are a number of problems with this approach:

  (a)  Although the thresholds are undoubtedly high, both the threshold in relation to wildlife damage and the one relation to water damage are intended to be set at too high a level. Indeed, in evidence it was admitted that "favourable conservation status" might be applied to a field, South East England or more, as appropriate. However, if transposed as planned (as evidenced in the Government's first consultation paper), this could mean that the UK will be in breach of the ELD and the Habitats Directive 1992, with the possibility of infraction proceedings being brought against the UK.

  Another important point to make in this context is a legal/practical one. Under the requirements of the ELD, operators are under an immediate obligation to take control and containment measures if they cause environmental damage. It will be impossible for an operator to wait until it is established whether this damage is significant, if he is to comply with the provisions of the Directive and not expose himself to significant additional liabilities. In the case of prudent operators this will mean that the high damage threshold, at least in relation to immediate control measures, will not be as important as it is made out to be by the Government, but in any case imposing a very high or unnecessarily complex damage threshold will make it very much harder for operators to assess the significance of damage themselves and come to the right decision in this context.

  Set at the appropriate (and practical) levels, damage thresholds may still be high, but may well allow for more cases to be caught by the ELD. Also, lower thresholds would make for more clarity, certainty and predictability for operators in practical terms, fewer breaches of the ELD with less onerous long-term liabilities.

  (b)  In addition, Defra's analysis of the likely number of cases that would be caught by the ELD shows a strong reliance on cases that fall within existing legislation. However, the ELD operates differently to existing legislation. Unlike the Water Resources Act 1991, for example, the ELD covers all types of environmental damage, not just pollution damage. In relation to wildlife damage, the ELD could also cover development. Moreover, it covers protected habitats and species outside Natura 2000 sites, as well as on such sites.

  It is very difficult to assess the significance of these issues and make a reliable prediction of future cases, but what is clear is that the Government has probably under-estimated the number of cases that could fall within the ambit of the ELD.

  (c)  There will be significant over-lap and conflict between the ELD and national law, which will lead to confusion and a possible eroding of national laws over time. The imposition of high thresholds in the ELD is not a good reason to let this happen. Rather it would make sense to take a robust approach that ensures a high level of environmental protection, clarity and predictability.

  (d)  The meaning of "significant", particularly in relation to wildlife damage, is a partly legal, mainly scientific question, and, especially in relation to ELD damage, which has already happened and is not a matter of future conjecture (as opposed to future damage under the appropriate assessment mechanisms of the Habitat Directive), is not a matter of value judgement, except to a very minor degree.

BETTER REGULATION AND REASONS FOR NOT OVER-IMPLEMENTING

  From the evidence given, it would appear that there are two main reasons against "over-implementation" of the ELD (in spite of the over-all benefits identified in the Regulatory Impact Assessment's (RIA's) cost-benefit analyses in relation to some of the "environmental" options). They relate to the marginal benefits of the environmental options and the lack of support for better fitting laws:

  (a)  The benefits identified in the RIA are so marginal that they are not worth pursuing, and it is felt that in that situation additional costs to business are not justified. The Government consultation is said not to have identified any major additional benefits, and the figures in the cost-benefit analyses were not challenged.

  In this context, it should be noted that some of the NGO responses (eg the RSPB's), did challenge the RIA and the cost benefit analyses, as well as the underlying minimum implementation approach applied to the ELD (see first part of the RSPB's response). They identified a probable over-estimation of costs and under-estimation of benefits in the cost benefit analyses, as well as instances where costs appear to have been taken into account more than once in the underlying calculations (thereby de-creasing benefits). In addition, they questioned the compatibility of this approach with true "better regulation" principles and with the UK Government's Sustainable Development Strategy and the application of the "polluter pays principle".

  In terms of the importance of the benefits identified in the RIA, it is questionable whether they really are "marginal". In fact, all the alternative options taken together are shown to be of a beneficial value of £4.8 million per year which amounts to roughly 23% of the total annual benefits identified for the minimum implementation option—not merely a marginal increase (see summary table on p 8 of the consultation document).

  Moreover, in relation to wildlife protection and set against the annual spend on wildlife protection and, in particular, damage restoration, £1 million per annum, for example (roughly the value of the benefit identified in the RIA for including SSSIs), constitutes a significant amount. As an example, the water vole is a species subject to widespread decline and needing vital recovery work, and therefore subject to much higher spending than other species protected under the UK Biodiversity Action Plan. The Environment Agency estimates that plans that are intended to improve the status of the water vole amount to £1.2 million per annum. On average, yearly spending is around £56,000 per action plan. Clearly, £1 million a year in this context is not a marginal sum.

  (b)  There is no intention to change existing laws and no strong case was made in the consultation responses to make the laws fit together better, even if the law will not be "as clear and transparent as could be".

  Many of the responses to Defra's consultation high-lighted concerns about the potential overlaps and conflicts between different laws on the same kind of environmental damage, which may lead to an erosion of stronger national laws over time. Of equal, but possibly more immediate importance, though, are the several instances identified by consultees, where the Government's current approach would lead to breaches of the ELD itself or of other European laws, leading to the possibility of infraction proceedings being brought by the Commission (for example, in relation to the thresholds, or in relation to applying the permit defences before remedial measures have been taken).

  In addition, it would be worth considering the discussions in relation to the "disproportionate costs derogations" under the Water Framework Directive 2000 and ensuring consistency of approach to these kinds of considerations where the value of environmental benefits is set against the relevant costs.

INCLUDING SSSIS, UK BIODIVERSITY ACTION PLAN HABITATS AND SPECIES AND RAMSAR SITES
  (a)  Including SSSIs within the ambit of the ELD rules will only be of marginal benefit (see arguments above) and will only lead to a 1% improvement in meeting the Government's Performance Services Agreement (PSA) target of bringing 95% of SSSIs into favourable or recovering condition by 2010, which is also felt to be of marginal value.

  It is mistaken to see a 1% improvement in meeting the 95% target as a marginal improvement only. At the moment, the Government is struggling to reach this PSA target, and has yet to improve performance by roughly another 20% to actually meet this target. To the same degree as improving performance becomes more difficult (as is witnessed by current status), every additional percentage gain is harder to achieve and more valuable, so where first improvements of SSSI condition were relatively easy to achieve, any additional improvement now is becoming harder and harder and any gain is extremely important. Therefore, a 1% improvement to meeting the Government's PSA target is extremely important, and more so the closer the target becomes to being met. If it is true that the damage thresholds have been over-estimated and the benefits of the environmental options under-estimated, this percentage may be higher in any case.

  (b)  It is argued that 90% of SSSIs will contain some kind of EU feature in any case. However, it is also stressed that it will only be the EU features, which will benefit from protection under the ELD, not any of the remaining protected SSSI features. Similarly, Ramsar sites are covered if an EU feature is at stake.

  The figure of a 90% "overlap" appears to be a new one, which has not so far been mentioned in any official documentation that the author of this note is aware of. The Defra consultation paper refers to a figure of a 70% overlap between SSSIs and Natura 2000 sites (by area), and the Government's answers to parliamentary questions show that 3,300 SSSIs will not be covered at all by the ELD. It is quite likely that the 90% figure is an over-estimate, but even if it is not, it must be remembered that the ELD will only apply if an EU interest has been damaged, but not if a nationally important feature is damaged.

THE POLLUTER PAYS PRINCIPLE

  In its assessment of the provisions of the ELD, the Government appears to be focusing very much on what it perceives to be "fair" on industry, particularly in the application of fault-based and strict liability, ignoring the extent to which principles of strict liability are already anchored in UK law, and ignoring its commitment to the "polluter pays principle" in relation to environmental protection and as part of its Sustainable Development Strategy. This is of particular relevance in the field of GMOs and similar technologies.

UN-REMEDIED DAMAGE

  There still has not been enough focus on the problem of un-remedied damage under provisions of the ELD. It is clear that the ELD does not impose, and the Government does not accept, the concept of "subsidiary state responsibility" in relation to environmental damage that falls under the Directive but where the operator cannot be found or cannot pay. Unless such a principle is accepted, at least to an extent, it will be impossible to operate a regime that contains fault-based liability concepts, and that incorporates defences such as in relation to compliance with permit or operation according to the state of scientific and technical knowledge at the time.

June 2007






 
previous page contents

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2007
Prepared 12 July 2007