Further supplementary memorandum submitted
by the Micropower Council (Cit 34b)
EXPORT REWARD AND FEED IN TARIFFS
EXPORT REWARD
1. The Committee has asked for clarification
of the arrangements for "export reward".
2. As Dr MacLean noted, the Electricity
Networks Strategy Group (which is co-chaired by the DTI and Ofgem)
established a project to consider the issues associated with payment
to domestic scale generators for electricity exported to the grid.
3. The project team was drawn from a wide
spectrum of industry players including suppliers, generators,
trade associations, the EST, Ofgem and DTI. The initial phase
of this project, to understand the current arrangements for export
reward and identify possible options for change that would improve
suppliers' ability to offer a "fair reward", is now
complete and the final report from the project has been published.
The report can be found at: http://www.ensg.gov.uk/assets/dgdti0007701.pdf
4. The conclusions that the Micropower Council
draws from the work of this project are given below.
5. In summary:
most large suppliers and some small
suppliers operating within the domestic market are offering to
buy exported energy from customers with microgeneration but the
structure and value of the tariffs vary considerably;
the tariffs for exported electricity
range from just under 4p/kWh up to the price charged for the import
(roughly 9-11p/kWh depending on region);
transaction costs mean that, in many
cases, the direct commercial value to suppliers purchasing from
domestic scale customers is much less than the tariff offered
and can even be negative (particularly for the very smallest exports);
arrangements where suppliers pay
more for the electricity than it is worth are unlikely to be sustainable
in the long term; and
an additional payment may be available
for renewable generators who are entitled to ROCs.[37]
However, transaction costs and complexity of the Renewables Obligation
mean that many do not claim the ROCs they are entitled to.
6. In light of the above, the Micropower
Council believe that further changes are required to minimise
the transaction costs associated with processing exports. However
even if these measures are fully implemented the commercial value,
to a supplier, of electricity exported from microgeneration is
likely to remain relatively low. Consequently, further Government
intervention is required to promote the uptake of these technologies.
A mechanism, which we support, is to extend our proposals for
the treatment of renewable heat under the Energy Efficiency Commitment
(which we have previously shared with the Committee and which
is also described in further detail in the accompanying Appendix
Two) to micro-electricity.
7. Further detail on the current treatment
of exported electricity to support these high level conclusions
is given below.
WHAT SUPPLIERS
CURRENTLY OFFER
8. The export of electricity from domestic
scale installations is still relatively new and the volumes of
electricity being exported make up an extremely small amount of
the total electricity mix; consequently purchase of export from
these generators has not been a major element of all suppliers
activities and not all suppliers systems are designed to easily
accommodate customers that export as well as import power at the
domestic level. In addition, the arrangements that would allow
suppliers to gain any direct financial benefit from the electricity
they purchase are quite complex with high associated transaction
costs (relative to the value of the electricity produced).
9. Nevertheless, most of the large suppliers
and a number of smaller suppliers already offer to purchase electricity
exported from microgeneration.
10. Separately, generators that produce
electricity from renewable sources are also able to claim Renewable
Obligation Certificates (ROCs) for each MWh of electricity they
produce[38]
and these also have a financial value to suppliers. Most suppliers
that offer to purchase the export from domestic scale generators
also offer to purchase their ROCs; in some cases the price offered
is included within the export tariff and in other cases an additional
payment is made for the ROC.
11. The following table provides a summary
of the type of tariffs that are available although please note
it is not fully comprehensive and tariffs do change.
Comment | Price per kWh
|
Bespoke pricedepending on technology
| Varies |
For renewable electricity onlyprice for ALL electricity produced (not just export) no separate payment for the ROC
| 4.5p/kWh |
Exported electricity
ROCs (on total renewable electricity)
| 3.8p/kWh
4p/kWh |
Exported electricity | Export = import price (approx 9-11 p/kWh depending on region)
|
Separate additional payments may be made for ROCs (at least one of the suppliers offering this type of tariff will make an additional payment for ROCs)
| |
Quarterly/annual payment independent of actual amount of electricity produced/exported
| £?/yr |
| |
COMMERCIAL VALUE
OF EXPORT
TO SUPPLIERS
12. The full commercial value of the export to the supplier
is complex to analyse and assess. The ENSG project concluded that
where a supplier registers the customer within the industry's
settlement arrangements then the exported electricity is likely
to be worth, very roughly, 4p/kWh.[39]
However, this value has to be set against the costs suppliers
incur when they register the customer. These costs include the
costs of the agents they must use to process customer meter information
(estimated to be somewhere between £10 and £20 per year)
and suppliers' own processing costs (which are much harder to
estimate but could be approximately £15 per year or even
higher). The table below shows the net value of each unit of electricity
exported as a function of the amount of electricity the customer
exports, based on these indicative costs and values.
Estimated net commercial value of export to a supplier in
p/kWh exported per year for different levels of export and cost
assuming an energy value of 4p/kWh
| Costs to be covered
|
Units exported
kWh/pa |
Agent costs only (£15 pa)
| Agent costs and
supplier costs (£30 pa)
|
| Net commercial value per unit in p/kWh
|
250 | -2.0 | -8.0
|
500 | 1.0 | -2.0
|
1,000 | 2.5 | 1.0
|
2,000 | 3.3 | 2.5
|
3,000 | 3.5 | 3.0
|
| | |
13. As the table shows, the impact of the agent and supplier
costs quickly absorbs most of the value of the exported electricity
where export volumes are low. For comparison, 1kWp of PV produces
approximately 800kWh of electricity not all of which would be
exported.
14. In practice, for a variety of reasons, most suppliers
do not to register their customers' export and so receive no direct
financial value for the electricity they buy.[40]
Any value they do receive is likely to be indirect via the error
smearing arrangements in the industry's settlement arrangements,
customer retention, and the value of information obtained under
customer trials.
15. A similar problem exists under the RO and one supplier
has advised us that only approximately 1% of its customers with
eligible renewable technologies actually claim the ROCs they are
entitled to.
GERMAN FEED-IN
TARIFFS
16. The Committee has also asked for further information
on the feed-in tariff arrangements in Germany. As the Micropower
Council is not familiar with the detailed operation of the German
arrangements we sought the advice of a Dutch colleague who has
far greater expertise in this area and we would therefore like
to acknowledge and thank Mr Michael Colijn for his assistance
in helping us to prepare the following summary.
Legal basis of feed in tariffs
17. The payments that must be made for electricity from
renewable and gas fired CHP are covered by two laws. The first
(the Renewable Energy Law) covers payments to producers of renewable
electricity and, at the householder level, covers electricity
from PV and biomass fired CHP. The Act also covers wind connected
at medium level voltages but, as yet there is no specific provision
for electricity from domestic scale wind installations. The second
(the CHP Law) covers electricity produced by gas fired CHP, including
domestic scale micro CHP.
Description of mechanism
18. Both laws specify the amount that must be paid to
the electricity producer and require suppliers to levy a charge
on all consumers to cover this cost. The current charge is approximately
0.1 cents/kWh, or roughly 10-15/customer/year.
This means that, as with the UK's Renewables Obligation, the cost
falls on all customers rather than the tax payer.
Feed in Tariff
19. The tariffs are technology specific and are paid
for each kWh of electricity EXPORTED to the grid system. The consequence
of this is that where the feed in tariff is higher than the price
the customer pays for imported electricity (PV and biomass fired
CHP) the generators are connected so that all the output is exported
to the grid. The tariff the customer receives is guaranteed for
10 years from the time at which the generator is connected, so
that the customer/generator has a guaranteed income stream, per
kWh, for the first 10 years. It is not clear what happens at the
end of this 10 year period.
20. The domestic tariffs for the different technologies
are summarised in the table below (with the price in p/kWh based
on an exchange rate of £1 = 1.5).
Domestic scale
Technology |
cents/kWh
| p/kWh |
PV | 50 | 33 p/kWh
|
Biomass fired CHP | 25 |
17 p/kWh |
Gas fired CHP[41]
| Approx 10 | 7 p/kWh |
Cost of imported electricity | Approx 20
| 13 p/kWh |
| | |
21. For comparison, the UK's Renewables Obligation subsidy
(which is additional to any value obtained from the electricity
produced) is worth something less than 5p/kWh for renewable electricity
technologies.
Other European Feed-in tariffs
22. A number of other European countries also have similar
arrangements in place including, for example:
France which currently pays 53 cents /kWh
for PV (35p/kWh);
Spain which currently pays 40 cents /kWh
for PV (27p/kWh);
Switzerland (rate not known);
Italy (although the administrative arrangements
are very complex) ; and
Netherlands which allows "net metering"
up to 3000kWh/year for renewables.
SUPPLEMENTARY EVIDENCE
FROM MR
SOWDEN
23. When I gave evidence on 29 November to the committee
under its "Climate Change: The Citizen's Agenda" inquiry,
I undertook to follow up in writing on two specific points. With
apologies for taking some time to do so, I hope the following
helps.
Micropower Council proposal to promote renewable heatclarification
24. The first of these related to the table in our submission
whose purpose was to provide an indication for comparison purposes
of the relative costs of different measures to reduce carbon.
There was some confusion during the oral evidence session, including
on my part, that the "cost" of our proposed mechanism
to promote renewable heat was negative. On further examination,
I can confirm this is not the case, but that the cost of our proposed
heat measure is indeed a positive costwe simply included
the approximation symbol "~" to indicate this was the
case. This was incorrectly read, including by me, during the evidence
session, as a minus sign, "-".
25. Assessing that cost is quite difficult; a robust
analysis would entail assessment of all the costs and benefits
of the measure to determine the net cost of carbon saved. It is
beyond the resources of the Micropower Council to undertake such
assessments ourselves which is why, in part, we have relied on
the analysis of others for the other support mechanisms.
26. Our own calculations are somewhat simpler and relate
solely to the theoretical cost a supplier might incur in supporting
a micro-heat technology under the EEC arrangements after application
of the "weighting factors" we are proposing (see our
second point of response below). Our analysis takes no account
of the costs to the customer of installing such measures or the
value of the benefits that they obtain from having installed them
so the true cost of carbon after accounting for the cost and benefits
to the consumer could be higher or lower than our quoted value.
This uncertainty is why we were keen to ensure that our figures
were shown as an approximationin future we will write this
in full to avoid this pitfall.
Micropower Council proposal on renewable heatsupplementary
detail
27. The second follow-up relates to the chairman's request
to follow up with a more detailed supplementary piece of evidence
on the precise nature of our renewable heat proposal. I have appended
to this Appendix a copy of the proposal, now formally submitted
as a joint proposal from ourselves, the Renewable Energy Association,
the Solar Trade Association, and the Combined Heat and Power Association,
to Governmentan earlier version of which was also provided
with the Micropower Council's evidence to the Committee.
28. Based on our experience of other mechanisms, we believe
that any effective support mechanism for domestic-scale renewable
heat must:
be simple, transparent and cost effective.
It is essential that transaction costs are kept to an absolute
minimum so that any value is not lost in administration (this
is a key and critical lesson we have learnt from the operation
of the RO for small players);
have a clearly defined future (at least
10 years and preferable much longer) and should not be subject
to the stop start vagaries of Government funding requirements
in order to create long term market confidence. This implies an
internally funded scheme independent of Government funding;
provide an upfront cost reduction for customers.
A key barrier to uptake of renewable heat, particularly for
domestic consumers, is the higher capital cost of renewable heat
technologies. Even where economic, long pay back periods (real
or perceived) can act as a barrier to uptake. It is therefore
essential that, for small customers, any support is accessible
at the point of installation and does not take the form of a future,
variable, small annual revenue stream. Again this is a major disadvantage
with the RO for the smaller player;
deliver an appropriate level of support and
alleviate current market distortions. Support should be sufficient
to catalyse the development of the renewable heat market and ensure
the evolution to a mass market demand/capability as early as possible.
This would also help to alleviate current distortions between
the renewable heart and renewable electricity markets; and
ensure there is a clear route to market for
these products through installers and product suppliers. The
majority of domestic scale heat systems are replaced when a system
fails rather than as part of a planned replacementit is
therefore essential that any support mechanism also ensures that
there is a clear route to market for these products through installers
and product suppliers.
29. Our proposal on renewable heat for the domestic sector,
we believe meets all these criteria and a brief overview is attached
below, with the full proposal attached as a supplementary brief
to this letter:
(a) The proposal is based on the Energy Efficiency Commitment
(EEC) the current main programme for delivery of energy efficiency
in the household sector.
(b) EEC operates by taking the annual energy savings from
a measure (for example cavity wall insulation), and estimating
a single value for them that takes account of the expected lifetime
of the measure, the carbon intensity of the fuel they displace,
and using a 3.5% discount rate. In this way, EEC is based on a
"present value" of the expected, carbon-weighted, lifetime
savings.
(c) DEFRA estimated when setting out the statutory instrument
for the current EEC programme that the 2005-08 cost of the programme
would be £1.25 billion, delivering 130TWh of "fuel standardized
lifetime discounted" savings. This equates to approx £10
for each MWh of so-called "EEC credits".
(d) On its own, this level of support would not yield
sufficient incentive to make a tangible difference to the uptake
of renewable heat micropower technologies.
(e) The Micropower Council proposal is that weighting
factors could be used within EEC in order to boost the level of
support available to renewable heat micropower technologies to
a level more likely to influence take-up (perhaps with current
grant levels being a useful starting point).
EXTENSION OF
THE ENERGY
EFFICIENCY COMMITMENT
TO CREATE
AN EFFICIENT
AND FAIR
SUPPORT MECHANISM
FOR RENEWABLE
HEAT
30. Renewable Heat is a major component of the micropower
portfolio and can be used to displace fossil fuels through domestic
installations and/or via renewable fuel based CHP and community
heating systems. Renewable heat technologies can play a major
role in meeting all four of Government's White Paper objectives
through, for example:
Reducing Emissions: ~1MtC of annual carbon
savings can be achieved by any of:
1 million domestic biomass-fired heating systems (1
in every 26 homes); or
7 million solar hot water systems (1 in every 3-4
homes); or
1 million heat pumps displacing electrical heating
systems (1 in every 26 homes);
Supply Security: ~1GW of new CCGT baseload
power station's electricity (or the gas to needed to produce this
amount of electricity) would be displaced by any of:
1 million domestic biomass-fired heating systems (1
in every 26 homes); or
7 million solar hot water systems (1 in every 3-4
homes); or
1 million heat pumps displacing electrical heating
systems (1 in every 26 homes);
Home Heating and reducing fuel poverty: fuel
consumption, and therefore fuel costs, may be either eliminated
or permanently lowered,[42]
particularly when micropower technologies are combined with energy
efficiency measures. In addition, many micropower technologies
are particularly suited to tackling fuel poverty in hard-to-treat
and off-gas network properties;
Competitiveness: The use of micro renewable
heat technologies enhances competition in the energy sector and
has the potential to provide a real alternative to network-based,
gas and electricity and other conventional heating fuels.
31. This analysis only considers the smaller end of the
micropower marketthe market for domestic scale appliances.
The total potential contribution from renewable heat production
which includes larger applications and community schemes is considerably
greater.
32. The Micropower Council considers that it is essential
that new measures, tailored to the needs of the renewable heat
industry, are introduced to support its development for two critical
reasons:
first, the heat market in the UK is enormous and
the potential for energy and carbon savings that can be delivered
by tackling even a relatively small proportion of the heat market
using renewable heat is a prize that must be won; and
second, to enable the renewable heat market to
evolve quickly into a mainstream industry delivering early access
to the benefits of economies of scale and consumer choice that
will make low energy/low carbon heating solutions a real, cost
effective, alternative to conventional fuels.
33. Such measures could also be used to address some
of the current disparities between the treatment of renewable
heat and other renewable solutionsleading to more efficient
long term outcomes and the removal of short term distortions.
34. Therefore the Government needs to act quickly to
implement a support mechanism (or mechanisms[43])
for renewable heat to help catalyse the development of this important
part of the energy industry. We are supportive of work by the
Renewable Energy Association to try to find an appropriate mechanism
for supporting larger scale renewable heat technologies.
35. Based on our experience of other mechanisms, the
Micropower Council believes that to provide effective support
for domestic-scale renewable heat any support mechanism must:
be simple, transparent and cost effective.
It is essential that transaction costs are kept to an absolute
minimum so that any value is not lost in administration (this
is a key and critical lesson we have learnt from the operation
of the RO for small players);
have a clearly defined future (at least
10 years and preferable much longer) and should not be subject
to the stop start vagaries of Government funding requirements
in order to create long term market confidence. This implies an
internally funded scheme independent of Government funding;
provide an upfront cost reduction for customers.
A key barrier to uptake of renewable heat, particularly for
domestic consumers, is the higher capital cost of renewable heat
technologies. Even where economic, long pay back periods (real
or perceived) can act as a barrier to uptake. It is therefore
essential that, for small customers, any support is accessible
at the point of installation and does not take the form of a future,
variable, small annual revenue stream. Again this is a major disadvantage
with the RO for the smaller player;
deliver an appropriate level of support and
alleviate current market distortions. Support should be sufficient
to catalyse the development of the renewable heat market and ensure
the evolution to a mass market demand/capability as early as possible.
This would also help to alleviate current distortions between
the renewable heart and renewable electricity markets; and
ensure there is a clear route to market for
these products through installers and product suppliers. The
majority of domestic scale heat systems are replaced when a system
fails rather than as part of a planned replacementit is
therefore essential that any support mechanism also ensures that
there is a clear route to market for these products through installers
and product suppliers.
A PROPOSAL FOR
RENEWABLE HEAT
36. Working with our members, other industry players,
and trade associations the Micropower Council has developed a
model which meets these criteria based on the simple expedient
of extending the current EEC arrangements to include additional
provisions for renewable heat technologies that displace conventional
fuels for heating in domestic premises. The key elements of this
model are summarised below.
Installation of new renewable heat to meet domestic
heat demand will qualify for inclusion in the EEC based on an
assessment of the net carbon saving over the expected life of
the renewable heat system compared to the heating system being
displaced. For premises that are currently unheated, the savings
would be assessed against an assumed carbon burden for a typical
heated household. All forms of renewable heat would be eligible,
subject to meeting appropriate accreditation requirements and
forming part of a "scheme" approved by the regulator.
Renewable heat solutions are currently less cost
effective, for suppliers, than other forms of action available
to them under the Energy Efficiency Commitment. Therefore, to
ensure that renewable heat can compete with other energy efficiency
measures (or other carbon reduction actions available to suppliers
under the EEC), renewable heat measures should automatically qualify
as a specific form of innovative actionattracting a larger
credit towards a supplier's EEC target than some other forms of
action via use of some form of weighting factor(s). This approach
is directly analogous to proposals being developed for "banding"
under the RO and recognises that different technologies may need
differing levels of support at different stages of their evolutionary
cycle.
Over time, as the cost of energy efficiency measures
increase, and the market capability for renewable heat expands,
bringing down costs, the weighting factors would be expected to
decrease. In order to facilitate this we suggest there should
be a regular review, say every five years, of the weighting factors.
This review would also be used to ensure that the mechanism does
not lead to an unnecessarily high reward for any technologies
that are, or are almost, competitive without support.
To give confidence to the market, Government should
commit to a long term future for the scheme. We note Government
commitment to extending the EEC to at least 2020.
The overall EEC target, for EEC3, should be set
to a level that recognises the contribution micro-heat technologies
can make to reducing carbon emissions under this proposal, with
any additional obligations being allocated between the domestic
gas and electricity markets in proportion to the total carbon
contribution from use of gas and electricity to provide heat to
the domestic sector. It will be essential to ensure that the targets
are set at a level that ensures that the EEC brings forward both
energy efficiency and micro heat measures and delivers real market
transformation.[44]
The mechanism could be introduced fairly easily
using the provisions within the Climate Change and Sustainable
Energy Act, together with appropriate changes to the EEC secondary
legislation.
COST OF
MECHANISM
37. The cost of the support to renewable heat will depend
on the weighting factors that are set and the total energy savings
delivered using heat rather than measures available to suppliers
under EEC.
38. An indication of the relative costs[45]
of different mechanisms for displacing carbon are shown in the
table below; the figures are not directly comparable because of
difference in the calculational methodologies.
Measure | Cost of Carbon
(£/tonne C)[46]
|
Renewables Obligation (NAO/Oxera)[47]
| 180-510 |
Renewables Obligation (DEFRA)[48] includes assessment of benefits and costs
| 175 |
Renewable Heat displacing gas (EEC with weighting factor 3cost to suppliers only, ignores benefits)
| approx £200 |
RTFO[49] (DfT)
| Slight -ve to 350 |
Social Cost of Carbon (Government Economic Service)[50]
| £35-£140 |
| |
BENEFITS OF
THE PROPOSAL
39. The move to mass market capability should deliver
lower costs to consumers earlier than would otherwise occur and
allow micro-renewable heat technologies to contribute to meeting
Government energy and environmental policy objectives:
It is simple, transparent and cost effective with
minimal transaction costs. Use of an existing mechanism will allow
early adoption and reduce the administrative costs of creating
and maintaining a new scheme. Suppliers are expected to be keen
to ensure that costs of providers and installers of equipment
are maintained at a competitive level ensuring that the benefit
of the scheme is shared with the consumer.
It provides a stable long term funding framework
independent of the stop start vagaries of Government funding requirements
providing confidence to the market to invest to expand capacity
and bring down costs in the longer term. The weighting and review
mechanism ensure that the benefits of cost reductions can be passed
through to customers over time.
The use of a lifetime discounted energy saving
delivers the value up front which can be used to mitigate the
higher upfront cost of renewable heat technologies that currently
act as a barrier to uptake.
The use of appropriate weighting factors can be
used to provide appropriate rewards to ensure the take up of renewable
heat measures; weighting factors can also be used to deliver parity
with the existing support mechanism for renewable electricity.
It creates an incentive for gas and electricity
suppliers to promote the installation of micro renewable heat
which will help to deliver a route to market for these products
through creating commercial alliances with installers and product
suppliers.
WIDER ISSUES
40. Looking beyond renewable heat, if this proposal is
adopted, it may be appropriate to consider expanding it to accommodate
renewable electricity in a similar mannerwith weighting
factors designed to give an equivalent reward to that would have
been available under the RO with substantially reduced transaction
costsand possibly allowing the EEC to evolve into an efficiency
and microgeneration (heat and power) commitment.
The Micropower Council
February 2007
37
Renewables Obligation Certificates. Back
38
NB: ROCs are available for all eligible electricity produced,
not just the electricity that is exported. Back
39
The range of values is quite wide and depends on a number of
different factors. It should also be noted that wholesale prices
have fallen since this analysis was completed. Back
40
We understand that by November 2006 only 17 export meters had
been registered although that number may be higher by now. Back
41
The price for electricity from gas fired chp is made up of three
different components: the f-i-t; a payment from suppliers (the
law specifies what the minimum payment must be); and a tax rebate
on the gas. Back
42
Many renewable heat technologies rely on wind and solar energy
where the fuel is free. Other technologies such as, for example,
biomass and heat pumps use clean fuels and/or use less fuel than
the heating source they are displacing. Back
43
Our proposals focus on the needs of the smaller, domestic scale,
end of the renewable heat industry. A different mechanism may
be more appropriate for larger scale renewable heat technologies. Back
44
Longer term targets should reflect any statutory targets introduced
under the provisions of the Climate Change and Sustainable Energy
Act. Back
45
For example, the DEFRA methodology includes both costs and benefits
in the analysis whereas the assessed cost of the proposed mechanism
takes no account of the benefits delivered. Back
46
Current costs quoted for EEC 2 indicate that energy efficiency
measures cost ~£10/MWh per fuel standardised lifetime discounted
TWh saved (based on an assumed cost of £1.25 billion and
a total supplier target of 130 fuel standardised lifetime discounted
TWh). This equates to ~£3.50/MWh of gas displaced once the
fuel standardisation factor has been taken into account implying
a cost to suppliers of carbon saved in the region ~£65/tonne
(the effect of discounting has not been taken into account). The
calculation does NOT take any account of the costs and benefits
to consumers installing these technologies. Back
47
http://www.nao.org.uk/publications/nao_reports/04-05/0405210_uk_renewables.pdf Back
48
http://www.defra.gov.uk/environment/climatechange/uk/ukccp/pdf/synthesisccpolicy-evaluations.pdf Back
49
http://www.dft.gov.uk/stellent/groups/dft_roads/documents/pdf/dft_roads_pdf_610329.pdf Back
50
http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/media/209/60/SCC.pdf Back
|