Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted by Air Travel—Greener by Design Group, Royal Aeronautical Society (Cit 50)

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

  To echo the Secretary of State, green taxes are only worth imposing if they influence environmental performance. Paying to cover costs where there is no link to a reduction in the polluter's (or another polluter's) impacts is no more than an empty benefit to the Exchequer (paras 2-3).

  It is important to assess the likely effectiveness of green taxes sector by sector, not on the basis of broad economic theory. No evidence has yet been produced by Governmental, parliamentary committee, NGO or even expert body advocates of green taxes or charges that the imposition of a financial penalty would make a material difference to aviation's climate change impacts (7).

  Ahead of next generation technologies coming on stream, if green taxes were to stimulate an improvement in environmental performance they would have to prompt a reduction in demand to the extent that load factors would fall to a level at which services would be consolidated or cut. The reverse has occurred. While this may be an inconvenient truth to advocates of green taxes on aviation, market evidence suggests that Government's elasticity assumptions have been over-optimistic and that the sector has been highly resistant to classical economic signals in the face of significant cost increases—akin to taxes and charges and that such instruments would be unlikely to pass the Secretary of State's test. A tax imposing a burden at even the high level experienced by the market over the past two years would not be sufficient to cap or reverse emission growth. It would have to be levied at a very high rate—perhaps upwards of 150% on fuel—in order to prompt a demand reduction sufficient to cut load factors to a level where flights become uneconomic and are consolidated or cancelled (8-15).

  The November 2006 DfT review of Continuous Descent (so-called "clean flying") and the introduction of the EU Single Sky system will, in our assessment, do more than any tax to reduce fuel burn (18).

  It is possible that for journeys of under 400km where rail and bus alternatives are available, increasing the cost of air travel might be effective in encouraging a shift to lower-emission transport modes (22).

  Offsets, while not influencing aviation's performance, are an example of beneficial green taxation provided the efficiency of the funded projects is properly assessed (23).

  There may be a role for hypothecated charges in order to accelerate improved efficiency; but taxes and charges are unlikely to persuade manufacturers to accelerate development of step-change technologies because the opportunity costs of not optimising revenues from current and planned aircraft models are so high. An approach focusing on regulation and incentives is needed (24).

BASIS OF SUBMISSION AND STATUS OF RESPONDENT

  1.  This submission, covering the relationship between green taxes and aviation's environmental performance, responds to the Committee's extension of its inquiry to include the issue of the extent to which "green taxation" is an effective driver of behavioural change. It is made by the Air Travel—Greener By Design Group ("GBD"), a DTI-funded advisory body that seeks to establish and promote technological, operational and market-based options to address aviation's climate change impacts. GBD is administered by the Royal Aeronautical Society and although its advisory group covers Government Departments, air traffic managers, the airport, airline, and manufacturing sectors and the research and academic communities, its executive function is independent of any industry or NGO interest.

THE OBJECTIVE OF GREEN TAXES

  2.  The Committee's question echoes David Miliband's recent statement that green taxes are only worth imposing if they influence behaviour. In the case of aviation, the behaviour to be influenced is

    —  Direct—with the objective of stimulating a reduction in flight or airport climate change impacts.

    —  Indirect—with the objective of stimulating passenger action that influences direct behaviour.

  3.  On the Miliband basis, it is not enough to impose taxes to cover external costs or to satisfy the Polluter Pays principle if they only raise revenue without affecting impacts. The principles of Polluter Pays or the covering of external costs work best where there is a clear relationship between payment and remedy—for example, where a factory pays a levy or fine for riparian discharge, with the revenue funding restocking or cleanup. Paying to cover costs where there is no link to a reduction in the polluter's (or another polluter's) impacts is no more than an empty benefit to the Exchequer. If, for various reasons, it is not possible for an aviation polluter's payments to remedy its impacts, the two principles are inappropriate for that sector.

  4.  In the case of aviation, although there is still uncertainty over the extent (and possibly the nature) of impacts, mitigation of impacts can be achieved through

    (i)  technological development and application—optimising combustion and airframe design;

    (ii)  operational measures—for example, avoiding areas of cold air in which cirrus cloud is most likely to be stimulated; and reducing energy use at stands, in taxiing and on approach to land;

    (iii)  optimising Air Traffic Control to reduce delay or diversion-related fuel burn;

    (iv)  replacement of inefficient aircraft with more efficient types; and/or

    (v)  consolidation of or reduction in services; and indirectly through

    (vi)  (indirectly) offset schemes that take into account non-CO2 climate effects of aviation.

  5.  The options for reducing CO2, NOx and contrails and cirrus cloud are different in kind and call for different technical and different regulatory or legislative measures.  Our work suggests that the impact of non-CO2 emissions can best be reduced by regulatory action, ultimately at ICAO level but possibly at EU level in the first instance (on the basis that regulatory action by an important destination such as Europe will lead to the introduction of the appropriate technologies and operational practices that can be expected, in due course, to be adopted globally). Progress in this area must await further advance in the atmospheric science relating to these impacts. The main incentive to reduce fuel burn, and thus CO2 emission, is likely to be financial.

  6.  Bearing in mind that it requires a global reduction in aviation emissions to reduce the climate impact of aviation significantly, that almost half the world fuel burn by aircraft is on flights originating in the USA and that the Far East is expected to be the region of most rapid growth in air travel over the coming decades, we must ask what UK or European measures can be expected to have a significant impact on the bullet points above. In particular, what influence can we expect green taxes to have?

THE OBSERVED AND LIKELY IMPACT OF GREEN TAXES

  7.  To date, no evidence has been produced by Governmental, parliamentary committee, NGO or even expert body (Royal Commission on Environmental Pollution, Sustainable Development Commission, Commission for Integrated Transport, Stern) advocates of green taxes or charges that the imposition of a financial penalty would make a material difference to aviation's climate change impacts. Air Passenger Duty, categorised as a green tax by the Treasury, may have reduced the rate of growth in air travel but there is no way to prove it; and we note that while the Pre Budget Report claimed that the doubling of APD would reduce air transport emissions by 0.2-0.5mtc by 2010-11 (PBR Chapter 7, p.179), no methodology was published to support this claim and the National Audit Office's Audit of Assumptions did not examine APD. There is no evidence, as far as we are aware, that it has achieved or encouraged (i)-(v) above. It is a deficiency of the Regulatory Impact Assessment process that tax announcements are excluded from the requirement to publish an assessment of impacts and to undertake a proportionality test. It is questionable as to whether the PBR's APD increase would have satisfied such an assessment.

  8.  It was suggested by the Liberal Democrat Environment spokesman in a recent letter to The Independent (2 November 2006) that "On flights, there is well-established evidence on responsiveness of air travel to price changes. This suggests a 1% change in price leads to a little more than 1% change in travel, assuming other factors—such as incomes—do not change." It could be claimed by advocates of green taxation that this would support an assumption that Air Passenger Duty or other aviation-related taxes and charges would beneficially influence behaviour and satisfy the Miliband test. In fact, although elasticity assumptions ranging from 0.5 for business passengers to up to 2.5 or even 3 for leisure travellers have at different times been advanced by the industry, the Department for Transport and the Treasury, there is little practical evidence to support them. On the contrary, recent market experience suggests that aviation is highly unresponsive to external drivers akin to taxes and charges and that such instruments would be unlikely to pass the Secretary of State's test. If taxes or other cost increases are to influence performance they must either

    —  reduce demand to a level at which load factors would fall to a point at which airlines would either abandon or consolidate services or, if available in their fleet, switch to smaller aircraft. At current average load factors, it may require a fall of 8-10% in passenger numbers for a service to be considered marginal;

    —  stimulate replacement of existing aircraft with more efficient types; or

    —  encourage fuel saving.

Would taxes or charges cut demand?

  9.  At this stage, it is important to understand that it is not passengers who pollute but flights. The critical indicators of performance are not therefore passenger numbers but the number of movements and emissions per movement. The Institute for Fiscal Studies recently endorsed this distinction in relation to the claimed impact of APD:

    "The IFS said there was a risk the doubling of air passenger duty to between £10 for European economy class and £80 for long-haul business class flights would be ineffective in reducing emissions from aircraft.

    Mr Leicester cited evidence that people responded to higher fares by flying less. But if that resulted in planes flying with fewer passengers rather than fewer flights, the environmental benefits would be minimal".[85]

  Because, as load factors increase, demand is rising significantly faster than the number of flights, it is misleading to seek—as have several NGOs and research bodies—to match passenger growth forecasts pari passu to projected emissions.

  10.  The Air Transport White Paper modeled the impact of a fuel tax. It assumed a 10% tax in 2006, increasing by 10 percentage points every year until it reached 100% in 2015.  It also assumed that the tax would be introduced globally and entirely passed through to passengers. Fuel was assumed to account for 10% of total costs. The result of this, DfT projected, would be a reduction in 2015 demand of 10%, or a cut in growth of 0.7% a year (Source: The Future of Air Transport, 2003, p.150).

  11.  What has actually happened? Between June 2004 and June 2006, the price of aviation fuel rose by 94.5% (Source: IATA), a much steeper rise over time than modeled by DfT and which, unlike a steady annual increment, gave the industry no time to adapt. Fuel comprised not 10% but 12 to 20% (IATA) of operating costs before this rapid increase. The industry imposed surcharges but much of the fuel price rise was absorbed for competitive reasons.

  12.  Standard economic analysis would assume that the upshot of the fuel price movement—essentially a 94.5% fuel tax (reduced by price hedging to an average of 50%)—and accompanying surcharges of recent years would be a reduction in demand and therefore in movements. In fact, over the two years global movements rose 5.1% (IATA). Furthermore, if we look at the most financially sensitive global market, the United States, data released last November show that over 2000-2005, total US passenger airline costs rose by 80%. A quarter of that was fuel, the cost of which increased by 266% to account for 25.5% of costs as at November 2006.  Landing charges also increased by 145% (Source: US Air Transport Association [s1]). Between 2000 and 2005, IATA reported that US carrier movements rose 27.5%. So this suggests that a tax imposing a burden at even the high level experienced by the market would not be sufficient to cap or reverse emission growth, still less in the more robust European sector.

  13.  The above cost:movement ratio could misleadingly be interpreted as a "movement elasticity" of -2.9: misleading because, as we have noted, although it is impossible to assess accurately, cost increases may have reduced the rate of passenger and movement growth. Nonetheless, the observed responsiveness of aviation emissions to price signals appears to be very low and the Committee should note the Air Transport White Paper progress report's (DfT, 2006, Table C1) acknowledgement that the Department's passenger growth forecasts were considered more or less robust regardless of whether DfT's assumed £70/tonne cost of aviation carbon was doubled or halved.

  14.  The industry's response to cost pressures has in fact been to seek to increase load factor while driving down other operating costs, and while those pressures might under conventional models be expected to lead to increased fares and possibly to reduced demand, despite marginal trading conditions highly competitive market dynamics forced overall US fares down by 12% between 2000-2005 (Source: ATA). This has had its parallel in the influence of no frills carriers in the UK, although the European market, with a greater passenger emphasis on service quality, has allowed network operators to maintain a wider pricing and cost premium over no frills operators than has been possible in the US. While some US domestic services were scrapped following the start of the sharp fuel price rise, their operators merely transferred capacity to more profitable international flights and within a few days even the shelved domestic services were restored. US load factors have risen markedly, and while emissions per passenger have reduced, the number of emitting flights has increased.

  15.  It appears clear on the basis of the above evidence that a green tax would have to be levied at a very high rate—perhaps upwards of 150% on fuel—in order to prompt a demand reduction sufficient to cut load factors to a level where flights become uneconomic and are consolidated or cancelled. It is possible, however, that where substitution between transport modes is relatively convenient[s3]—for example, journeys of under 400km—increasing the cost of air travel would be more effective in encouraging a shift to less polluting modes, although any tax or charge would have to be sensitively applied in order not to prejudice communities (such as the Highlands and Islands) which may be highly dependent on the availability of air services.

Would taxes or charges stimulate fleet replacement?

  16.  If even steep increases in costs have not reversed movement growth, would they encourage airlines to move to higher-efficiency aircraft?

  17.  Leaving aside the high opportunity costs of accelerating planned fleet replacement, the evidence is that UK airlines are extending their fleet life, not because they want to continue using out of date aircraft but because the UK (and indeed the European) fleet is pretty much state of the art and more efficient models to replace the key short-medium haul workhorses of most UK carriers (the A320 and B737 and B757 families) are unlikely to be launched for several years. While the efficiency of an engine falls slightly over time, dependent on maintenance standards, there is little environmental benefit in replacing an eight year old 757 with a new one if lower-impact types are not yet available. The known potential for near to medium term advances in engine and airframe technologies could, in our assessment, radically mitigate climate change impacts (cf GBD's 2006 Annual Report: http://www.greenerbydesign.org.uk). However, manufacturers do not believe the incentive yet exists to commercialise them or to invest in higher risk research. That incentive—whether by market dynamics, incentives or regulatory standards—must be created if a substantial improvement in environmental performance is to be achieved by 2030.

Would taxes and charges encourage fuel saving?

  18.  At such a significant share of operating costs, airlines currently need no incentive to save fuel and they all have fuel saving schemes. The November 2006 DfT review of Continuous Descent (so-called "clean flying) and the introduction of the EU Single Sky system will, in our assessment, do more than any tax to reduce fuel burn.

CONCLUSION

  19.  It is important to assess the likely effectiveness of green taxes sector by sector, not on the basis of broad economic theory. Those who advocate green taxes or charges as a mechanism for improving aviation's environmental performance have not to date adduced any evidence based on market performance that supports their contention.

  20.  Ahead of next generation technologies coming on stream, if green taxes were to stimulate an improvement in environmental performance they would have to prompt a reduction in demand to the extent that load factors would fall to a level at which services would be consolidated or cut. The reverse has occurred. While this may be an inconvenient truth to advocates of green taxes on aviation, market evidence suggests that the sector has been highly resistant to classical economic signals in the face of significant cost increases.

  21.  Government's elasticity assumptions have been over-optimistic. The likely "movement elasticity" of air travel in response to tax and charge-like signals is very low. We would be happy to assess evidence to the contrary.

  22.  It is however possible that for journeys of under 400km where rail and bus alternatives are available, increasing the cost of air travel might be effective in encouraging a shift to lower-emission transport modes.

  23.  The funding of offsets[s4], while not influencing aviation's performance, is an example of beneficial green taxation provided the efficiency of the funded projects is properly assessed. Standards are being developed that will lead to a more uniform market and it is possible that such schemes could complement emissions trading. While it is likely that transaction costs will rise, offsets offer a way of achieving environmental benefit at a low cost. Moreover they can be taken up immediately and could carry a strong message to consumers not of simply assuaging any guilt associated with air travel but to encourage careful consideration of the reasons for flying.

  24.  There may be a role for hypothecated charges in order to accelerate improved efficiency through, for example, air traffic control improvements or support for technology research programmes; but taxes and charges, unless hypothecated (and possibly not even then) are unlikely to persuade manufacturers to accelerate development of step-change technologies because the opportunity costs of not optimising revenues from current and planned aircraft models are so high. An approach focusing on regulation (for example, the International Civil Aviation Organisation's NOx standard has significantly influenced Rolls-Royce's engine design programme) and incentives is needed.

Air Travel—Greener By Design Group,

Royal Aeronautical Society

January 2007





85   The IFS' own report on green taxes (The UK Tax System and the Environment, October 2006) cites a Canadian study claiming that a 10% tax cuts leisure demand by 10% and short haul demand by 15% but it is uncertain on reading the study whether it was based on economic assumption or on market observation. (Source: Financial Times, 8 December 2006) Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2007
Prepared 13 September 2007