Select Committee on European Scrutiny Thirty-Fourth Report


20  VALUE ADDED TAXATION

(a)
(28778)
11635/07 
+ ADD 1
COM(07) 381

(b)
(28782)
11695/07
 + ADD 1
COM(07) 380

Draft Directive amending Directive 2006/112/EEC with regard to certain
temporary provisions concerning rates of value added tax




Commission Communication: VAT rates other than standard VAT rates


Legal base(a) Article 93 EC; consultation; unanimity
(b) —
Documents originated5 July 2007
Deposited in Parliament (a) 11 July 2007
(b) 12 July 2007
DepartmentHM Treasury
Basis of consideration EM of 23 July 2007
Previous Committee Report None
To be discussed in Council 13 November 2007
Committee's assessmentPolitically important
Committee's decisionCleared, but further information requested

Background

20.1 The Community has a common system of value added taxation (VAT) which includes rules about permissible rates of VAT and under which:

  • supplies of goods and services are normally subject to a standard rate of at least 15%;
  • Member States may apply one or two reduced rates of not less than 5% to a limited number of goods and services;
  • Member States may, under certain conditions, apply a reduced rate to certain labour intensive services; and
  • individual Member States have a variety of temporary derogations from the general rates rules allowing them to apply additional reduced rates.

20.2 These derogations were granted during the negotiations preceding adoption of the VAT rates Directive of 1992 and in the Acts of Accession since then. The duration of these derogations varies according to when a Member State joined the Community. Those which joined before 1 January 1995 are allowed to maintain their derogations until the entry into force of a "definitive system". However, those Member States which joined after 1 January 1995 received precise deadlines for their derogations to expire, if the introduction of the definitive system did not occur first.

The documents

20.3 The draft Directive, document (a), would extend until 31 December 2010 some of the temporary derogations of Member States which joined the Community after 1 January 1995. The Commission proposes this because the definitive system is unlikely to be adopted in the foreseeable future and the first of the post-1994 temporary derogations are due to expire in 2007, thus creating an imbalance of treatment between newer and older Member States. It has chosen the date of 31 December 2010 on the basis that a new political agreement on VAT reduced rates will be necessary before that date, as the minimum 15% standard rate of VAT and the experiment on the application of reduced VAT rates to labour-intensive services are due to expire then. This issue could therefore be reconsidered at the time of these broader discussions.

20.4 The draft Directive would prolong derogations for:

  • reduced rates applied in the Czech Republic, Cyprus, Poland and Slovenia relating to the restaurant and housing sector; and
  • zero or super reduced rates (of less than 5%) in Cyprus, Malta and Poland for food, books and pharmaceuticals.

20.5 The draft Directive would allow some derogations to lapse. This is largely an administrative exercise removing those which are either not necessary because the reduced rates in question can be applied under the general rules or are no longer used by the Member State. Czech and Estonian derogations allowing a reduced rate for natural gas, electricity, district heating and firewood are examples of the former; a Hungarian derogation for restaurant services and energy supplies and a Slovakian derogation for construction and heat energy supplied to private homes are examples of the latter. But two derogations are allowed to lapse on the basis that they conflict with the proper functioning of the internal market or other Community policies. These concern terminating Estonia's derogation regarding coal, coke, fuel and oil, which is considered to be in conflict with Community energy and environment policies, and Poland's derogation allowing a super reduced rate for agricultural inputs, on the basis that this is in conflict with the internal market. However, Poland could continue to apply a regular reduced rate (of no less than 5%) to such supplies under the general rules.

20.6 In its Communication, document (b), the Commission summarises briefly the findings of a study into the economic impacts of reduced VAT rates undertaken for it by Copenhagen Economics[85] and sets out some possible ways to apply these to reforming the VAT rules. The Commission's intention is to foster a "fundamental debate" on VAT rates and it seeks initial views from Member States, the European Parliament and the European Economic and Social Committee by the end of 2007, with a view to presenting a broad legislative proposal on VAT rates in late 2008 or early 2009, for agreement before the end of 2010.

20.7 In the Communication the Commission focuses on how in its view the current system might be simplified and rationalised and highlights the business compliance costs associated with different levels and scopes of VAT reduced rates. It does not make any formal proposals but it does identify possible overarching objectives for future changes to the VAT rates structure:

  • ensuring equal treatment of all Member States, which the Commission argues would require terminating country specific derogations;
  • recognising that there is a strong political will in most Member States to apply very low reduced rates including zero rates, particularly for social purposes;
  • recognising the increased economic and budgetary difficulties in moving a product from one rate to another, because of the often very huge difference between the standard rate and a reduced rate;
  • establishing a clear and logical purpose for reduced rates; and
  • balancing any increase in the flexibility allowed to Member States against compliance costs.

20.8 The Commission suggests one way, but not the only one, that these objectives could be translated into a structure composed of three VAT rates (which might accommodate reduced rates currently allowed by the temporary derogations):

  • a very low rate of 0-5% for products of prime necessity, such as food;
  • an optional second rate of 10-12% for other purposes, which were felt to merit preferential treatment for other reasons, such as cultural, educational, public transport or employment considerations; and
  • a standard rate.

20.9 The draft Directive and the Commission Communication are each accompanied by a copy of a staff working document which more fully describes the findings of the study by Copenhagen Economics and reproduces the consultant's own executive summary. The consultant says:

  • the study argues that there is a strong general argument for having uniform VAT rates — they are a better instrument to maintain a high degree of economic efficiency, to minimise otherwise substantial compliance costs and to smooth the functioning of the single market; but
  • it also argues that there are exceptions — there is a case for extending lower rates to some sectors in Member States characterised by specific economic structures.

20.10 The consultant continues that the study examines the theoretical and empirical merits of four different arguments for reduced rates — reduced VAT can increase efficiency by increasing productivity or by reducing structural unemployment and reduced VAT can enhance equity by improving income distribution or by making particular products more accessible to an entire population. It says there is:

  • a theoretical and empirical argument for extending reduced rates (or other subsidies) to sectors whose services are easily substituted for do-it-yourself or black economy work, for example locally supplied services and some parts of the hospitality sector;
  • a theoretical argument for extending reduced rates to sectors employing many low skill workers in order to boost low skill demand, for example hotels, restaurants and locally supplied services;
  • a limited and contingent argument for extending reduced rates (or other subsidies) to sectors particularly favoured by low income households in order to improve post consumption income distribution; and
  • a limited and contingent argument for extending reduced rates (or other subsidies) to sectors that for some good reason are under-consumed.

20.11 The consultant says also that the study identifies a number of concerns to be carefully evaluated in each case:

    "most arguments in favour of lower VAT are equally valid for other policy instruments, for example targeted subsidy schemes or targeted changes in income tax;

    "all empirical evidence indicates that compliance costs associated with lower VAT rates can be sizeable;

    "the key to an efficient application of lower VAT or any other subsidy is to keep low mechanical revenue losses; and

    "the choice of financing scheme to secure budget neutrality should be carefully considered in the context of the goals to be achieved by reduced VAT rates."

20.12 The executive summary concludes:

    "To summarise, there seems to be a strong argument for making the current VAT structure more simple and uniform, but also an argument for selective cuts in VAT rates primarily in locally supplied services and parts of the hospitality sector. We stress that the current study cannot be seen as a per se endorsement for further reductions in VAT. The devil is in the detail and we stress the need to consider each case on its own merits and to seriously appraise whether alternative non-VAT instruments may be preferable to reduced VAT rates."

The Government's view

20.13 The Financial Secretary to the Treasury (Jane Kennedy) says that:

  • the draft Directive, document (a), has no direct policy implications for the UK;
  • the Government supports extending most of the temporary derogations granted to those Member States that acceded after 1 January 1995, in order to ensure more equality of treatment between Member States;
  • non-prolongation of derogations considered to conflict with a smooth functioning of the single market and with other Community policies does not set a precedent which could be applied to UK derogations, which continue to apply unless and until there is unanimous Council agreement to introduce a definitive system of VAT;
  • any future proposals from the Commission regarding the structure of VAT reduced rates, or which might affect the UK's zero rates, would require the Council to act by unanimity;
  • the Government has always made clear that it will not agree to any proposals that would harm its social objectives or undermine the fairness of the UK VAT system; and
  • the Government has a manifesto commitment not to extend VAT to food, children's clothes, books, newspapers, and public transport fares.

Conclusion

20.14 The draft Directive, document (a), is unexceptionable. But the Communication at document (b) concerns important issues and we note with approval the Minister's robust reiteration of the Government's continued stance on this matter.

20.15 We clear the documents, but wish to see in due course the Government's response to the Commission's call for comment on its suggestions in the Communication.


85   "Copenhagen Economics is an international consulting company dedicated to providing private and public decision makers with economic insight." - see http://www.copenhageneconomics.com/Default.aspx?ID=19 . Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2007
Prepared 12 October 2007