Select Committee on Foreign Affairs Written Evidence


Written evidence submitted by Professor Barbara Harriss-White, Queen Elizabeth House, Oxford

DEVELOPMENTS IN INDIA'S INFORMAL ECONOMY

  1.  India has been successfully branded and twinned with China as the emergent knowledge-services and manufacturing hubs respectively of the 21st century world. But, although growing rapidly, knowledge services are a very small fraction of India's economy and an even smaller fraction of world trade in software services. An estimated two thirds of India's GDP is in the informal economy and out of the direct control of the State. I have been studying it through primary field research since 1969.

  2.  The informal economy includes agriculture. India's agricultural sector has well performed the necessary role of providing food, basic wage-goods (such as cotton textiles), labour and financial resources for the development of the non-agricultural economy. While more than doubling its foodgrains production, it has fallen from being about 70% of GDP at Independence to about 25% now. It has done this however in very unusual circumstances: despite the fact that the Green Revolution technologies were capital-biased, it has not shed labour. The proportion of the Indian workforce in agriculture was approximately 70% at Independence and is at about two thirds now. The paradox is explained both by the persistence of underemployment in agriculture and by the net effect of labour intensive versus labour displacing agricultural change (the key labour-generating factor being the increase in land cultivated in more than one season rather than the increase in the real land area cultivated). Now, while the technologies of the green revolution are facing diminishing marginal returns, rising input prices and declining real product prices, the production of many crops is gripped in a cost-price scissor. Over the last 15 years agricultural growth rates have been mediocre; increasing returns to scale rather than the long-celebrated inverse returns put small producers at a disadvantage. In the recent past, the labour elasticities of agriculture with respect to growth have been declining everywhere and have now turned negative in two kinds of region—the most agriculturally advanced and the most agriculturally backwards. Clearly quite different economic processes are involved but we known too little about both of them. What this means is that further agricultural growth will shed jobs. Livelihoods will have to be sought in the non-agricultural, informal sector because, since liberalisation in 1991, the formal (registered, tax paying) third of the economy has been growing in a jobless way.

  3.  The "service sector" is highly differentiated between—crudely—high-end IT and very low-end domestic and sanitary work. It is likely that demand for low end work from the high end of the service sector fuels its statistical growth. But because the data for services is not disaggregated we cannot be certain. Jobs in the informal economy are the most important key to poverty reduction in India. They will also contribute importantly to growth.

  4.  Yet there is no vision or "plan" for India's informal economy. This is an extremely challenging state of affairs confirmed not only by a long reading of the literature and by discussion with many scholars but also very recently and in public in the UK by two people in crucial positions: Dr Y Thorat, the Chairman of India's National Bank for Agriculture and Rural Development (NABARD, at a conference in Reading University in September 2006) and Dr Montek Singh Ahluwalia (the Deputy Chairman of India's Planning Commission—in questions after his public lecture in Oxford University in October 2006). My submission will therefore be concerned with India's informal economy and the committee may deliberate about how "Britain" might engage with it. I will describe some of its important features using the literature based upon field research. I have deliberately decided not to use statistics because, although India is blessed with a relatively compendious statistical base, those referring to the informal economy are well accepted as being approximate and are continually being questioned. For the themes developed here there is no systematic data.

  5.  In India's informal economy, a range of different technologies, forms of finance and ways of organising economic activity co-exist. Diversity is at its heart. The condition of being "informal" is not at all clear-cut. Commonly a firm may be locally registered, possibly have a series of local licences, reimburse a state electricity board for its power, draw credit from a registered bank but it may have its own water supply, lend money "onwards" on unregulated terms and conditions, subcontract all but the finishing processes of production, fail to pay tax or to apply the factories act regulations to its labour force. A registered factory may exist in name and building alone while most of the production it controls is carried out in workshops in the alleys nearby. Thriving industrial clusters producing significant proportions of India's exports operate under these conditions.

  6.  Undeclared rents, profits and factor payments constitute the black economy. Using the most recent official data derived from the mid 80s, it was estimated to be on an upward trend at 35% and most scholars believe there is no reason to assume it has not continued to rise. India's black economy is thought to be concentrated in the retail sector, inventory, the film industry, real estate and unregistered money export (and import). (The black economy is implicated in the electoral process.)

  7.  The informal sector is clearly larger than the black economy and consists legitimately of agriculture and firms operating below a size threshold for commercial tax eligibility (until recently Rs 3 lakhs—now Rs 10 lakhsi). The informal sector also consists of socially legitimate activities which make complex private and public organisations work smoothly; together with socially illegitimate and illegal rent seeking and fraudulent activity. The Indian economy is regulated not only by the state but also by a significant informal "shadow state" of more or less party-politicised brokers, rent seekers, fixers and protectors of private property which exists entirely because of the way the state regulates the economy.

  8.  Of the workforce of nearly 400 million, over half its livelihoods consist of family businesses run without wage labour, engaged in production or trade and usually depending for their survival on loans from commercial-cum-moneylending firms which derive their own credit from banks or from ethnicised financial networks. Job working, subcontracting and outsourcing are common ways in which registered or unregistered firms ensure operational flexibility and scale. 93% of the workforce has no rights to work, at work or to social security; 7% has social security rights and about half of this latter proportion are members of trades unions. There is no evidence that this rightless proportion of the workforce is contracting. India's labour laws, considered an impediment to investment, are simply irrelevant to the vast bulk of the workforce. The Indian state regulates the lives of labouring families outside their work through their (lack of) water supply, drainage, electricity, housing, education and their use of space and leisure— arguably more thoroughly than it regulates their work.

  9.  Between and quarter and a third of India's population (the precise fraction is deeply debated) remains below an exiguous poverty line (an income sufficient to buy 2,200 calories per person per day). All of India's poor operate in the informal economy but the reverse is not true. Concepts of poverty have expanded from inadequacy of income to include wellbeing (and deprivation in health, education, nutrition, shelter, water and sanitation). These non-income forms of deprivation remain more widespread than income poverty and they do not map congruently across society: their alleviation is a necessary development objective both in itself and as an instrument to improvements in the terms of economic participation. But there is a fundamental idiosyncracy in the anti-poverty policy mixes at the levels of states: to take Southern examples, significant budgetary outlays on subsidised staple food (AP), subsidised school meals (TN), employment guarantees (Maharashtra, going national in late 2005), ubiquitous subsidised health and education (Kerala). The Indian state has implemented national enabling law for a social security system for those under the poverty line but few states have made more than a token attempt to implement it.

  10.  The informal economy is far from being chaotic; it is well ordered and "socially regulated". Business associations (operating by product sector and by town, some federated at higher levels) and chambers of commerce are of growing importance not only as representatives of occupational sectors but also as regulators of the economy.

  11.  Forms of social identity regarded as antiquated—and long predicted to disappear—are reworking their roles and strengthening their regulative activity in the market economy. The following paragraphs will give examples and the development problems that arise from them.

  11.1  Gender screens half the population from all but wage work. There tends to be a non-linear relationship between wealth and income and women's economic participation in which women are progressively secluded from work outside the domestic arena to a kink point above which they participate in the economy. By and large the female workforce is in agriculture, in casual labour and at poverty wages. Relatively few women possess productive assets. Dowry is unlawful but widely required. A scholarly literature has revealed the consequences of women being non-earners and economically burdensome. The child sex ratio reveals deteriorating life chances in the post-liberalisation period. Although the relationship with poverty is complex, one of India's development scandals is that the child sex ratio is most adverse to girls among the upper deciles of the income distribution and in the most developed regions of the NW.

  11.2  The phenomenon of caste remains of foundational importance in the economy. Approximately mapped onto class, it structures the socialisation to work and still operates to screen occupations the more rigorously the lower down the collapsed (or fictitious) "system". It is especially fierce a regulator at its base, where 25-30% of the population that is "dalit" (oppressed, ex-untouchables) is, despite positive discrimination, extremely poorly educated, still fighting contemptuous treatment and generally confined to sanitary work, agricultural labour and construction sites. Political assertion is taking caste rather than class forms. Caste politics has a dual role in the economy. On the one hand castes aim for upward mobility through absorbing the customs of higher castes and shunning low caste occupations. At the same time they queue for official recognition as backward in order to qualify for positive discrimination by the state. Over the last 10-15 years, middle caste organisations have been transformed into trade associations which regulate entry to, and the terms and condition of participation in, the market economy. Through these institutions the informal economy takes a corporatist form. Labour may be represented inside such lobbies but the agendas of these self-regulating institutions do not prioritise their needs. Trade associations play a very active role in the non-party politics of marketplaces, negotiating and representing, and redistributing resources. But as regulators and redistributors they are incomplete, local, arbitrary and exclusive. Pervasive and persistent, they present challenges to both economic participation and democracy. International codes of conduct and sector-wide voluntary labour codes have little purchase as yet on this economy.

  11.3  Religions—and India has a notable plurality of them—supply collective identities that in turn supply indispensable conditions for capital accumulation. In India religious affiliation can be found to govern the acquisition of skills and contacts, the circulation of finance, the establishment and defence of collective business reputation, the circulation of information, the norms that regulate the inheritance and management of property, the creation and protection of rent and the subordination of women. In addition religious groups are often found regulating and distributing livelihoods, providing insurance and last-resort "social security". As a result, the distinction between the private and the public sphere is blurred. Public protest and riots have been triggered by religious events—the damage that results not only affects people but also is mapped onto commercial property and living quarters.

  11.4  Ethnicity: in the late 1980s, an extremely small proportion of the population (0.4%) controlled the major part of India's industrial assets (60%). Although now being diluted, this ethnicised control is still remarkably concentrated. While ethnicity is generally understood as a phenomenon of tribal identity and some of the most under-developed regions of India's economy are populated by tribal societies; a more widespread economic expression of ethnicity is the control over rural money markets, agricultural processing, pawnbroking and the jewellery trade of ethnic diasporas which spread slowly from North West India to those regions of the east and south which did not have local business castes. These highly entrepreneurial communities are development "problems" when lending to poor smallholders at monopolistic interest rates. State attempts to compete are sometimes captured.

  11.5  It is due to these kinds of social regulation that the rising tide does not lift all boats. These forms of "social regulation" do not only structure the economy, they also pervade the "care economy" and structure the "help in times of need" which compensates for the lack of a welfare state for a labour force whose workplaces are often dangerous and unsanitary. They also pervade the state and compromise its Weberian organisational principles. Any policy change has to square with them, yet development policy discourse (where it is not directly addressed to them) is couched in terms rendering them invisible.

  12.  India punches well above its weight in military and scientific affairs and diplomacy. It is now flexing its muscles as a foreign investor. The UK's biggest aid receiver, it has always been an aid donor too. It must be concluded that the Indian state has taken the choice to regulate much of its economy through its social institutions. A novel vision is urgently needed for exactly that part of the economy that is out of state control - in particular the informal, rural, non-farm economy. The conditions under which labour-intensive utilities, infrastructure, production, services and trade may be developed are not necessarily ones mediated by untrammelled markets. Production and delivery systems for the creation of the capabilities which would transform the workforce's well-being and security are also urgently needed. Ironically, strong state institutions will be needed to support a flourishing informal economy able to absorb excess agrarian labour.

  Barbara Harriss-White, Professor of Development Studies and Director of Queen Elizabeth House, Oxford University. See Barbara Harriss-White, 2003, India Working Cambridge University Press; 2004, Rural India facing the 21st Century, Anthem, London (with S. Janakarajan and others); 2006, Trade Liberalisation and India's Informal Economy Oxford University Press, New Delhi (ed. with A Sinha).

REFERENCE  i  A lakh is Rs 100,000 or £1,175. £1 = Rs 85 in late 2006

Professor Barbara Harriss-White

Director, Queen Elizabeth House, Oxford

November 2006





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2007
Prepared 4 May 2007