APPENDIX 25
Memorandum submitted by the Forum of Private
Business
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
Governments around the world procure $5.3 trillion
worth of goods per year. In the UK, only 22% of government procurement
contracts go to small and medium-sized businesses. Research shows
that the larger the business, the more chance it has of obtaining
contracts from public authorities.
Why should this be so? Do large businesses necessarily
produce better products and services at cheaper prices than their
smaller counterparts? No. If that were the case, the smaller businesses
would not survive in private markets either.
The key issue is that governments are not commercial
organisations. They do not have a profit motive or a competition
motive, and therefore no incentive to behave in a way that economists
would necessarily define as rational when they procure inputs
to the services they produce. Their behaviour excludes a potentially
large source of bids for tender. Firstly, this means that governments
pay more than they need to, and taxpayer value is not maximised.
Secondly, small businesses, the vehicle for the innovations that
guarantee future increases in prosperity and the target for much
of the investment for innovation that facilitates them, do not
have access to a potentially lucrative market. Thirdly, resources
are not allocated efficiently in the economy. Many stakeholders
worry about the distortions that could be created if deliberate
efforts are made to improve the procurement process for small
businesses. In reality, large distortions already exist.
This paper lists a number of corrective actions
that could be undertaken by government. However, it also points
out that, without the profit motive that drives private organisations
to make economically efficient decisions, there is no incentive
for government departments and local authorities to unilaterally
take these actions. This paper therefore recommends radical reform
of procurement policies so that advocates for fair competition
can work within government departments to instruct them on how
to make their procurement processes fairer. A target should also
be introduced, for the percentage of government contracts that
go to small and medium-sized businesses. Not a ring-fenced quota
that leads to contracts being given unfairly to small businesses
which could not win them competitively, but a benchmark against
which the success of competitive procurement policies can be measured.
Furthermore, we outline the specific circumstances under which
setting certain government contracts aside for small businesses
actually results in greater competition and efficiency than allowing
dominant large businesses to compete with them.
Finally, we recommend support for a revision
of the WTO Agreement on Government Procurement. Revision, not
so that we can protect our own market and unfairly favour domestic
producers, but so that we can take the necessary measures to institute
fair competition, and so that we can work to revise the Agreement
such that small business programmes are allowed, but that national
protectionism is not, for a far greater percentage of the whole
global procurement space than is currently covered by the Agreement.
INTRODUCTION
Governments are not commercial organisations.
They do not seek to deliver profits for their shareholders or
owner-managers. Their revenue is derived from taxes. Profits are
budget surpluses that are simply offset against deficits from
previous or subsequent years, diverted around departments, or
used to pay off government debt. Nevertheless, when they deliver
their services, they inevitably buy goods or services from private
organisations during the delivery process. As William G Poeton
wrote in 1986, government purchases range "...from complex
space vehicles to paper clips, janitorial services to cancer research.
In short, the (US) Government buys just about every category of
commodities and services available."[50]
However, governments cannot be compared with
other commercial purchasers of goods and services.
Private companies purchasing other companies'
products do so with a specific objective that the procured product
be used in their own production processes in a way that will increase
the price: quality ratio of their own products and give them an
advantage over their competitors in a highly contested marketplace.
Governments, however, are not subjected to the
same constraints.
There is no such thing as competitive government.
People cannot choose to receive public services from a range of
different governments in the marketplace. The only choice is at
election time, yet the politicians who have to be re-elected are
not the ones who make the day-to-day purchasing decisions. These
are civil servants. The only other avenue of choice is residence:
yet most people cannot, for practical, personal reasons, emigrate
if they are dissatisfied with their government's services. Furthermore,
while value for money in procurement is important, it is not likely
to influence an intention to vote or emigrate.
Because of the widespread proliferation of government
activity and the ever-increasing role government plays in our
lives, the Government has assumed the role of dominant buyer in
many industries. As a dominant buyer, while not entirely in a
monopolist position, its actions significantly affect the structure
of the markets in which it purchases.
The lack of competitive constraint and incentive
causes Governments to make decisions that would be economically
irrational from the point of view of an economic agent operating
in input and output markets which were perfectly competitive both
from the suppliers' and purchasers' side. As a dominant buyer,
the Government's actions have the power to create significant
distortions.
By far the greatest economic folly committed
by government is single-sourcing. It is simply not economic not
to seek as many tenders as possible for each and every contract,
and yet, in many cases, preferred suppliers are used without the
necessary competitive tendering process. Firstly, this discriminates
against smaller businesses, and causes misallocation of resources
in the economy. Secondly, a lack of or limited competition in
the tendering process causes prices to be inefficiently high and
wastes taxpayers' money.
These irrational actions have resulted in poor
access to government contracts for small businesses. Small businesses
currently receive less than 20% of UK Government procurement contracts.
Including medium-sized businesses, this rises to 22%[51],
but this is still insignificant compared to the 99.8% of businesses
which are small or medium-sized. The situation for small businesses
is similar in many other EU countries. In France, for example,
the figure is 21%.[52]
It is official government policy in the UK that
procurement tenders should be opened up to small businesses. The
Supply2.gov.uk website states that "Government policy is
now encouraging Public Sector bodies to open up public sector
procurement to small business."[53]
The creation of the Supply2.gov.uk website is the main ingredient
of this policy. However, further measures are needed in order
to address the imbalance.
In recommending further measures, we are always
mindful of the fact that small businesses, while they do not enjoy
the same economies of scale as their larger counterparts, are
the vehicle for much of the innovation that guarantees future
increases in our living standards. In the United States, they
produce 13 to 14 times as many patents per employee as larger
businesses.[54]
They are the companies at which venture capital and other sources
of high-risk equity for innovation are directed, and, without
the ability to tap into a market that can reach up to a sixth
of GDP, they are less attractive investments than they could be.
Furthermore, we do take into account the fact
that mention of improving access for small businesses to government
contracts invokes preconceptions of "positive discrimination"
or some kind of undue favour. In fact, we are looking for procurement
to be more competitive, not less. Currently, a huge field
of potential supplierssmaller businessesis shut
out from the process, meaning that Government does not always
take into account all possible suppliers of goods and services
and is, therefore, procuring less competitively and with less
taxpayer value than it could.
GOVERNMENT BEHAVIOUR
AND THE
INHERENT DISCRIMINATION
AGAINST SMALL
BUSINESSES
As highlighted above, governments are not subject
to competitive constraints in the same way that commercial purchasers
of goods and services are. Therefore, their actions are not always
entirely rational, or, if they are, are driven by motives other
than economic ones.
Here are some examples of how government practices
shut small businesses out of the procurement process:
Single sourcing means that many contracts
are not even advertised, but are simply awarded to the preferred
supplier.
Many procuring authorities require
three years' worth of audited accounts from a tendering business
in order to consider them, even though this is of questionable
relevance to their ability to complete the job.[55]
Some of the most innovative businesses with much to offer may
be venture-backed start-ups who have existed for less than three
years.
Most small businesses do not know
where to find public contracts.
Public authorities, like other dominant
buyers such as New Look and Matalan[56],
have a poor track record on payment practice[57],
which discourages small businesses. They are safe in the knowledge
that, as they are a dominant buyer, the firm from which they are
purchasing will be unlikely to exercise its statutory right to
interest under the Late Payment of Commercial Debts Act 1998an
Act inspired by the FPB's workfor fear of losing business.
The bureaucracy needed to complete
a tender often takes one person three working days, which is a
huge cost commitment for smaller businesses, indeed probably a
larger commitment in terms of average avoidable cost than for
large businesses.
Public authorities tend to bundle
tenders together for convenience when they could get better value
for money by breaking them up and putting them out to tender individually.
For example, the contract to build the interrogation centres for
the new identity card scheme was given as a whole to a large company
called Mapeley. However, there is more than one centre to be built,
and the contract was given for all centres. This is called bundling.
If the construction of each centre had been put out to tender
individually, small businesses in each locality could have competed
for the building of individual centres, and, in some instances,
their bids may have been cheaper or more advantageous.
There is also inherent risk-aversity
in government departments, both at a personal and collective level:
"Nobody ever got sacked for hiring IBM", is a common
phrase. As departments are not businesses acting under competitive
constraints, they do not have to think about potential return
on their investment. They simply go for the most convenient and
safest option. For innovative start-ups and specialist smaller
businesses, there are obviously unique problems with such behaviour.
Private firms that procure products and services have to make
complex value judgments when deciding between tenders. One may
have the potential to deliver stunning returns, but these returns
may not be certain. Does the purchaser select the riskier offer
with the higher potential, or play it safe? The level of risk-aversity
in the business drives the decision, a level that is itself driven
by the competitive dynamics of the marketplace that the purchaser
eventually supplies. However, private purchasers have the ability
to make provisions for riskbad debt provisions are used
in their accounts; risky investments are hedged, and they are
financed by a variety of means provided by investors: leverage
finance, acquisition finance, equity finance for specific ventures.
Investors vary in their risk-aversity, but risk-seeking ones may
be found to finance specific, promising but risky, ventures. Governments
do not have the same financial facilities; their funding is simply
decided on three-year cycles by the Treasury.
Where it would be rational to seek as many bidders
as possible for each tender and evaluate them on the basis of
return on investment in a risk-neutral mindset, the Government,
sometimes intentionally, through single-sourcing, and sometimes
unintentionally, through the practices outlined above, restricts
competition for its tenders, and then evaluates them in a risk-averse
manner.
The reasons for this can be:
(a) Convenience. A tendering process takes
up time. The interests of the individual working in the procuring
authority are not always aligned with those of the organisation
for which they are working, or those of the taxpayer. This is
known in economics as the principal-agent problem[58].
If the interest of the procuring authority or the taxpayer is
return on investment, or even simply cost, but the interest of
the individual (or the procuring authority, in contrast to the
taxpayer) administering the procurement is convenience and speed,
there is a propensity for the individual to use single-sourcing.
(b) Financial goals. Public sector organisations
do not work to the same financial goals as private organisations.
As highlighted above, return on investment is a key criterion
for private organisations. Government departments, however, do
not have an incentive to look for return on investment. Their
funding is decided in three-year cycles between Comprehensive
Spending Reviews, decided by the Treasury. They cannot set their
own budgets, nor raise external financing for an investment project
which may be costly in the short term but pays for itself in the
long term, subject to risk. Therefore, short-run cost and reliability,
rather than contribution to long-term productivity and competitiveness,
are often the criteria used, and this weighs heavily against small,
innovative businesses.
CORRECTIVE ACTIONS
The following corrective measures should be
taken:
(a) The removal of the requirement for three
years of accounts to be provided before a tender is granted. This
requirement obviously excludes innovative start-ups which may
not have existed for three years, as well as certain small businesses
that have no reason to keep accounts that are audited according
to the standards used by listed companies.
(b) A reduction in the paperwork and bureaucracy
needed to submit a tender.
(c) A reduction in the propensity of government
departments to bundle and aggregate tenders.
(d) An improvement in the late payment records
of government departments. They act as a large disincentive. Research
could also be commissioned to determine whether payment practices
could be changed for small businesses. For example, the justification
for the requirement for three years of accounts is that government
departments must know that the tendering business has the financial
capacity to deliver the project. This is often needed if the project
is of long duration with payment on completion. However, if payment
practices were changed such that payment could be made incrementally
for work in progress, more small businesses would be able to compete.
(e) Greater transparency and abolition of
single-sourcing: every government contract should be advertised
publicly, not given to a preferred supplier, and tendering businesses
should have access to information as to why their bid was successful
or unsuccessful.
(f) A decision management process, either
through decision-management software or through recognised procedures,
should be implemented in order to take into account other factors
than short-term cost, which might make a tender attractive to
a government department.
(g) All local authorities should sign the
small business concordat.
(h) The use of "smart procurement"
could be examined. One example of smart procurement is a process
whereby procuring authorities are less rigid in their requirements
from a tender, allowing a tendering business to creatively apply
whichever solutions they feel will increase the operational efficiency
of the customer's business. This allows tenders to be judged against
more criteria than just the one-off cost of producing specific
defined services. Innovative small businesses, especially start-ups,
would be better able to compete if such methods were used.
Of course, ideally these measures would be actioned
by government departments unilaterally. Unfortunately, unless
government is subjected to competitive constraints (which is,
of course, impossible, as a country can only have one government),
this is unlikely to filter through the whole government machine.
Without competitive constraint or the motive
of profit, there is little incentive to act in an economically
rational way. Therefore, an "artificial" incentive,
and a mechanism to ensure the corrective actions outlined above,
need to be inserted in order to change the behaviour of the procuring
authorities and individuals.
STIMULANT FOR
CORRECTIVE ACTIONS
One such incentive would be a target for the
percentage of government contracts that should go to small businesses.
Of course, introduction of this target should not be the sole
measure put in place. In the absence of corrective measures to
address the problems highlighted, it would be impossible to implement,
as small businesses still could not compete fairly. Small businesses
can only compete fairly if the measures above are taken. However,
a target would be the incentive to implement those measures. If
an individual, be it a Minister or a relevant senior civil servant,
could be held accountable to the target, then annual reviews of
performance against the target would provide indicators as to
whether the measures were being implemented and having the desired
effect.
Furthermore, if the target were set above the
current level, but just below the level which small businesses
would receive from an economically rational buyer, the target
could, along with the corrective measures, be guaranteed to correct,
rather than create, distortion, and to enhance competition by
including more small bidders, rather than unfairly favouring small
businesses.
Targets distort the market when they are introduced
into already perfectly functioning and competitive markets. However,
such a description is not apt for the UK public procurement space.
We have listed above several examples of market failure, such
as imperfect information, and irrational behaviour and non-optimisation
on the side of the consumer (government). This results from the
dominant position of government as a buyer and its lack of competitive
constraint in its output markets. The proliferation of government
activity and the ever-expanding size of the state have created
a dominant buyer, whose actions have the power to distort the
market because of its dominance. Furthermore, this is a buyer
that does not operate in any competitive market as a supplier.
It is not subject to competitive constraints that would rationalise
its economic behaviour. Therefore, its economically irrational
behaviour creates market failure and misallocation of resourcesor
what we would commonly call distortion.
A target would not correct this. Corrective
measures as outlined above would. A target would force government
departments to implement those measures.
The target that we advocate should not be a
ring-fenced quota. It should not, under any circumstances, lead
to small businesses being granted contracts that they could not
obtain competitively. Indeed, if a quota did lead to this situation,
the UK would be in breach of EU law.[59]
The target should be a benchmark target against which actual performance
can be measured and relevant individuals and authorities held
accountable.
A second means of enforcement of the necessary
changes would be a system of advocates, which may or may not be
modelled on those working under the auspices of the Small Business
Administration (SBA) in the United States, working with government
departments to force them to put out tenders for competition and
make them more accessible for small businesses.
The experience from the US shows that, in just
the two years after President Reagan signed into force the Small
Business and Federal Procurement Competition Enhancement Act
of 30 October 1984, savings of $201m[60]
had been achieved, just in the Department of Defence, through
releasing to open tender defence contracts that would previously
have been secretively given to large, established, reputable companies
for convenience. This reflects the increased competition for each
tender, which was only made possible through the SBA's work in
forcing departments to break the contracts out so that they were
competitively tendered and accessible for smaller businesses.
The $201 million can be taken as the quantification
of the reduction in market distortion achieved by the SBA's
Breakout for Competition Programme. Indeed, one might add that
President Reagan, given his record, would not have passed such
an Act unless it acted to reduce market distortions and enhance
competition, as is implied in the name of the Act. It is proof
that deliberately improving access for smaller businesses opens
a new field of potential bidders, therefore creating greater competition
for tenders, reducing distortion and saving taxpayers' money.
A further measure in use was the system of set-asides.
Set-asides do not mean unfair advantages, as Poeton points out:
"The use of the phrase `set-asides' immediately creates a
feeling of privilege to the UK mind. It took the team some time
to fully understand that in reality it is a `set aside for competition'
programme."[61]
Set-asides are used for certain classes of procurement
and they dictate that only small businesses may bid for them.
This does seem, at face value, to restrict competition. However,
such set-asides are only implemented where the presence of a large
business as a bidder deters small businesses from submitting a
tender themselves, when, for example, the small business may be
economically dependent on the larger business. Where such discouragement
occurs, there is market failure, as the large business is obviously
dominant enough to bring about exclusionary abuse against the
small business. Therefore, the set-aside is a measure to reduce
market failure. The evidence of the United States' experience
shows that cost savings to the taxpayer of 40% can be achieved[62]
because the number of bids received for each tender is greater
under small business set-asides than when competition is open
to large businesses as well.[63]
Whilst we would not recommend wholesale copying
of this policy into the United Kingdom, we do believe that its
use should be permitted, under specific circumstances which
can be identified through appropriate economic research procedures:
namely, where the market failure, in the form of exclusionary
abuse outlined above, can be proven.
LEARNING FROM
BEST PRACTICEPROCUREMENT
FROM SMALL
BUSINESSES IN
THE UNITED
STATES
It is fair to say that the system in the United
States is imperfect and has worked, at many points in history,
far better than it does now. For this reason, any recommendation
to model our own policies on the American experience is often
treated with trepidation. Whilst we would not advocate simply
lifting and copying the system from the United States, we do believe
there are significant advantages to the American system that could
form the basis of a British model. However, it is worth explaining
in depth which points to take on board and which features have
caused the current imperfections in the American system.
The genesis of efforts to improve small businesses'
access to public procurement contracts in the United States came
during World War Two, when Congress was concerned that taxpayer
dollars used for defence procurement may not be being spent effectively.
The concern was that the federal Government was not maximising
its use of funds and that the war effort may, therefore, be being
compromised. A programme was initiated to grant Certificates of
Competency (COCs) to small businesses to enable them to bid for
tenders from the Department of Defence (DOD). As Clark and Moutray
point out: "The Certificate of Competency (COC) had its beginning
during World War Two as part of the Small Business Mobilization
Act of 1942. This legislation established, among other things,
the War Production Board, with authority to review and certify
the competency of a small business to perform a specific Government
contract."[64]
The dual utility of the programme is effectively
summed up by the same authors. "The purpose of the program
is to ensure that small businesses, especially those newly entering
the federal marketplace, receive a fair share of government contracts.
This, in turn, helps the Government to supplement and diversify
its sources of supplies and services."[65]
Small businesses benefit because they receive
fair access to a significant market. The Government, and taxpayers,
benefit because there is greater competition, as a whole new source
of tenders is opened up. The economy benefits through greater
efficiency and allocation of resources.
The Small Business Act was created in 1953,
to ensure fair treatment of small businesses as well as ensuring
that they received a fair proportion of government contracts.
Again, the focus was on maximising small business interests in
order to enhance competition, as Congress stated:
"The essence of the American enterprise
system of private enterprise is free competition. Only through
full and free competition can free markets, free entry into business,
and opportunities for the expression and growth of personal initiative
and individual judgment be assured. The preservation and expansion
of such competition is basic not only to the economic well being
but to the security of this Nation. Such security and well being
cannot be realized unless the actual and potential capacity of
small business is encouraged and developed. It is the declared
policy of the Congress that the Government should aid, counsel,
assist, and protect, insofar as is possible, the interests of
small business concerns in order to preserve free competitive
enterprise, to insure that a fair proportion of the total purchases
and contracts or subcontracts for property and services for the
Government... be placed with small business enterprises..."[66]
The Small Business Act was enhanced through
the Small Business Federal Procurement Competition Enhancement
of 1984, after a pilot project of 1980 that had pointed to the
efficacy of breakouts, saving $7.3 million through 294 breakouts
at four Air Force Logistics Centres.[67]
The Act assigned a Small Business Administration (SBA) Breakout
Procurement Centre Representative to all major procurement centres
and required federal procurement regulations to be subject to
public consultation.[68]
In the same year, the Competition in Contracting Act limited non-competitive
procurement methods and instituted an advocate for competition
in each executive agency.[69]
In 1985, the Department of Defence Authorization Act designated
an advocate for competition to the Department, and established
guidelines on the use of qualified bidder lists, which small businesses
believed had been used to discourage new firm participation in
the tendering process.[70]
Following the signing into law of these Acts
by President Reagan, significant cost savings were achieved as
outlined above, as new sources of bids were opened up.
Even before the 1984 Act and the savings identified
in 1986, the Small Business Act of 1953 had been effective in
increasing small business' share of the federal market to 30%.[71]
These policies, which are both competitive and
SME-friendly, and produced visible results both for SMEs and for
the taxpayer, are those on which we would like to see a UK reform
modelled.
However, there are also downsides to the American
system. The Buy American Act of 1933, which "mandates preference
for the purchase of domestically produced goods over foreign goods
in US Government procurement"[72],
is not a policy that we advocate replicating, as it is protectionist
and anti-competitive.
Furthermore, the access of smaller businesses
to federal contracts appears to have gone into decline from the
1990s, as Clark and Moutray point out that 22.6% and 23.6% of
government contracts went to small businesses in fiscal years
2002 and 2003 respectively.[73]
However, the explanations for this are offered
quite clearly by Clark and Moutray, and their figures are a clear
vindication of the theories highlighted above regarding competitive
procurement.
As Clark and Moutray point out[74],
the Federal Acquisition Streamlining Act of 1994 authorised multiple-award
contractsleading to a 19% jump in the number of bundled
contractsand allowed for purchases of items below $2,500
without competitive quotations. The National Defence Authorisation
Act of 1994 created a new category of transactions authorised
for the Department of Defence other than those that had to be
competitively tendered. The Clinger-Cohen Act of 1996 authorised
credit card use for purchases up to $2,500, and the Administrative
Dispute Resolution Act of 1996 limited the number of places where
small businesses could file a claim.
All of these Acts impacted negatively on the
ability of small businesses to fairly compete for government contracts,
as evidenced by the low proportion of government contracts won
by small businesses in 2002 and 2003 compared with, for example,
1984. In short, bundling and less competitive tendering had unfavourable
effects on small businesses. This corroborates our view that the
less competitive the tendering, the more difficult life is for
small businesses. This was predicted, at the time of these reforms,
by Donald L. Campbell.[75]
Conversely, however, the Small Business Reauthorization
Act of 1997 actually increased the target for the percentage of
Government contracts that should be awarded to small businesses,
from 20% to 23%. The target was increased at the same time as
the ability of small businesses to compete fairly was compromised.
There is anecdotal evidence that the target has, during recent
years, caused market distortions, as federal authorities have
tried to award small businesses a fair share that they cannot
fairly obtain. However, the reforms of the 1990s are the reason
that they cannot fairly obtain that proportion. If the effect
of those reforms were neutralised, small businesses could compete
fairly and the target would not be causing any distortion, but
acting as a regulator of fair behaviour.
Therefore, it can be fairly calculated that
any distortions that have occurred in recent years as a result
of the 23% target have in fact been due to the fact that the target
was acting alone. When the procurement system was altered it became
unfavourabe to small businesses and to competition, attempts to
enforce small businesses' fair share through the use of a target
alone resulted in limited success, success that was achieved at
the price of distorting the market.
However, the fact that federal authorities have,
in recent years, missed or only narrowly met the percentage target
for procurement from small businesses has forced a review of the
1990s reforms and a new round of initiatives to allow small businesses
to compete: Clark and Moutray point out:
"...final bundling regulations went into
effect in October 2003. In 2002, Congress instructed DOD contracting
officers to solicit offers from all contractors offering the required
services under the multiple-award contracts. The intent was to
improve the process of making awards under multiple-award schedule
contracts. Also, regulations now have finally eliminated duplicative
database systems that take precious time away from small businesses....
All of these new procurement developments are designed to find
better ways to make the procurement process more open and fair
for small businesses."[76]
The failure to meet or to significantly exceed
the target acted as an indicator to policymakers that procurement
policies were not as competitiveas open to small businesses
as well as largeas they should be. This has led to corrective
actions such as tightening up on bundling and reduction of bureaucracy,
the results of which cannot yet be judged due to economic and
data collection time lags, but which should result in more competitive
procurement and greater access for small businesses. If there
were no target against which small businesses' share could be
benchmarked, there would have been no signal that the reforms
of the 1990s had been harmful.
We believe that the American experiences of
the 1980s through to the present corroborate our view that specific
measures to maximise openness and competition are needed to improve
the access of small businesses to government contracts, but that
these can only be policed through benchmarking against a target,
where the failure to reach the target acts as an alarm bell to
sensible policymakers that such policies may not be being pursued
or implemented in the best possible way.
While the 1990s and 2000s provide a valuable
lesson in the usefulness of the target as an enforcer of procurement
policies which are both friendly to small businesses and pro-competitive,
the actual policies enacted in the United States through the Acts
of 1942, 1953, 1984 and 1985 that we believe could form the basis
of a reform in the UK are:
Break-out for competition programmes
Set-aside for small business competition
programmes, where appropriate on grounds of fair competition
Limiting of non-competitive tendering
Public consultation of procurement
regulations
Guidelines on use of qualified bidder
lists
Appointment of an advocate for competition
in each procuring authority
Advocacy of the above by an equivalent
Small Business Administration, whose advocates should work inside
each procuring authority
INTERNATIONAL FRAMEWORK
There are two major international agreements
governing government procurement practice, to which the UK is
subscribed. At EU level, there is Directive 2004/18/EC. At WTO
level is the Agreement on Government Procurement (AGP), to which
the UK is a party as an EU member state.
EU Directive 2004/18/EC does not need to be,
could not and should not be renegotiated. As mentioned above,
it forbids the granting of any kind of special favours to a tendering
business that could not win a contract competitively. This is
implied to include favours on grounds of home nationalityit
is a piece of internal market legislation[77].
However, as we have extensively pointed out in this paper, we
believe that greater, not lesser, open competition is needed and
do not look for special favours of any kind.
EU Directive 2004/18/EC also contains certain
specific provisions which could be helpful to small businesses,
but have simply yet to be implemented in the UK. For example,
it stipulates that unsuccessful tenderers must be able to know
the reasons why their tender failed[78],
it instructs procuring authorities to act in a transparent way[79],
provides for competition by regulating the use of restricted procedures,[80]
and instructs procuring authorities to advertise the value of
contracts they wish to issue.[81]
The Directive, indeed, provides a certain legal framework that
may be helpful in enforcing some of the measures we outline.
The Directive could probably not be renegotiated
even if this were worthwhile, as the negotiations were extensive
and were only concluded three years ago, as per the date of the
Directive. The Directive does not rule out any of the corrective
measures we outline, nor does it rule out the enforcers of those
corrective measures that we recommend: the advocates or the target.
The AGP was concluded in the General Agreement
on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) in 1979 and re-concluded at the inception
of the World Trade Organisation in 1994. It was one of four agreements
annexed to the agreement establishing the WTO, and came into effect
in 1996.
The AGP is a plurilateral agreement for which
signatories must designate which procuring entities and types
of procurement are covered.[82]
Specific signatories have made specific classes of procurement
or procurement policies exempt from their participation in the
agreement. As the Canadian Department for Foreign Affairs and
International Trade sets out, the USA has exempted its small business
set-asides and Canada has exempted procurement by sub-federal
governmental authorities.[83]
Japan and South Korea also enjoy specific opt-outs.
The main purpose of the agreement is summarised
by the WTO as follows:
"The AGP establishes an agreed framework
of rights and obligations among its Parties with respect to their
national laws, regulations, procedures and practices in the area
of Government procurement. The cornerstone of the rules in the
Agreement is non-discrimination. In respect of the procurement
covered by the Agreement, Governments Parties to the Agreement
are required to give the products, services and suppliers of any
other Party to the Agreement treatment "no less favourable"
than that they give to their domestic products, services and suppliers
and not to discriminate among goods, services and suppliers of
other Parties (Article III:1). Furthermore, each Party is required
to ensure that its entities do not treat a locally-established
supplier less favourably than another locally-established supplier
on the basis of degree of foreign affiliation or ownership and
do not discriminate against a locally-established supplier on
the basis of country of production of the good or service being
supplied (Article III:2). In order to ensure that the basic principle
of non-discrimination is followed and that access to procurement
is available to foreign products, services and suppliers, the
Agreement lays heavy emphasis on procedures for providing transparency
of laws, regulations, procedures and practices regarding government
procurement."[84]
It essentially rules out national protectionism
from the selection of contractors on a global level, in the same
way as Directive 2004/18/EC does so on an intra-EU level. This
goal is one with which we fundamentally agree.
However, in the laudable aim of seeking to encourage
international competition, the Agreement has also possibly ruled
out certain of the specific measures that we have outlined that
could improve small businesses' access to government contracts.
Article 7 states: "Each Party shall ensure
that the tendering procedures of its entities are applied in a
non-discriminatory manner."[85]
Again, while we agree with the noble aim of this clause, we anticipate
a degree of legal uncertainty with regard to the use of small
business set-asides. In the cases where small business set-asides
are needed, it is because the presence of a large business in
the tendering process discriminates against a disproportionate
number of small businesses, as described above. Therefore, a small
business set-aside is a measure to reduce discrimination, as we
outlined.
However, is this the interpretation the WTO
would use, when large businesses are excluded from certain contracts?
We believe that this article should be redrafted simply to say
"in a manner that ensures that tenders are competed for in
the most competitive way possible", as this would allow set-asides
when they are necessary to improve competition. The same legal
uncertainty does not apply to EU Directive 2004/18/EC, as its
non-discrimination applies to the "Awarding of Contracts',
which implies the selection of a tender from the bids received,
not the actual conditions for participation in the tendering process.
It is also doubtful whether a target for the
percentage of government contracts to be given to SMEs, would
be in accordance with the Article 7.
Article 8 states: "...any conditions for
participating in tendering procedures shall be limited to those
which are essential to ensure the firm's capability to fulfil
the contract in question."[86]
Here, small business set-asides stipulate that a business must
be small in order to compete for a contract, yet this is not related
to the business' ability to fulfil the contract, it is related
only to the need to ensure maximum competition. This clause would
need to be redrafted to say "any conditions for participating
in tendering procedures shall be limited to those which are essential
to ensure the firm's capability to fulfil the contract in question
or to ensure effective competition in the tendering process."
Article 10 states: "entities shall, for
each intended procurement, invite tenders from the maximum number
of domestic suppliers and suppliers of other Parties, consistent
with the efficient operation of the procurement system."[87]
There exists the potential for legal uncertainty here with regard
to the use of set-asides. We believe they should only be used
where they are proven to produce a higher number of bids. However,
would the WTO conclude that the exclusion of larger businesses
is contrary to the invitation of the "maximum number of suppliers"?
We believe that this clause would need redrafting to exclude the
duty to "invite" tenders, saying instead "...entities
shall, for each intended procurement, provide for efficient competition
by ensuring the maximum number of bids is received." Again,
as we believe set-asides should only be used where they increase
the number of bids, this would allow us the legal flexibility.
EU Directive 2004/18/EC[88]
does allow, as we pointed out above, for restricted procedures
under certain regulated conditionsnamely that at least
three bids must be solicited. We do not see this as a problem
because, we repeat, set-asides should only be used where they
increase the number of bids.
Article 13 states: "The entity shall make
the award to the tenderer who has been determined to be fully
capable of undertaking the contract and whose tender... is either
the lowest tender or the tender which in terms of the specific
evaluation criteria set forth in the notices or tender documentation
is determined to be the most advantageous."[89]
While we agree with the aim of this clause, the phrase "in
terms of the specific evaluation criteria set forth in the notices
or tender documentation" makes it more difficult for small
firms to win contracts by producing innovative offers that provide
benefits outside of the specific scope of the contract, and indeed
for procuring authorities to be open-ended in the requirements
they stipulate. Therefore, this clause would need to be redrafted
to remove the words in bold, giving procuring authorities more
flexibility.
There is currently a window open until March
2007 for the tabling of a revised AGP.
The UK cannot negotiate for itself in the WTO,
as trade is an EU competence at "first-pillar", i.e.
supranational, Community level. Therefore, we believe that the
UK should actively engage in the EU to reach an agreement that
a revised AGP proposal should be tabled, encapsulating the above
suggestions, and that the EU should push for these changes in
the WTO. If the changes cannot be made, an opt-out should be sought
to exempt smart procurements, and, if necessary, break-outs and
set-asides, from the agreement, or indeed to exempt certain classes
of procurement from the whole agreement if this is easier to operate.
However, we do not believe that the thrust of
the AGP is wrong. Non-discrimination on grounds of nationality
is imperative to the evolution of comparative advantage through
international trade. We would not want any of our proposed measures
to conflict with this principle, and do not believe that there
is any reason why they should. Even if we were to opt out from
the agreement, we should still award contracts without discrimination
on the grounds of nationality.
Opt-outs would, however, be suitable, because,
as well as providing the flexibility as outlined above, they would
provide a rationale for a new agreement replacing the AGP, because
they would make the AGP virtually obsolete. The AGP already only
covers $240 billion of the $5.3 trillion that public authorities
around the world spend on goods and services in a year. EU opt-outs
would reduce this figure even further.[90]
Currently, the Agreement does not cover large
sections of procurement by the world's largest purchaser, the
United States Government. The rationale for the US opt-out of
small business set-asides from the Agreement is that they are
forbidden by the Agreement. The Buy American Act, as a protectionist
measure, is also forbidden, but is conveniently applied to those
classes of procurement, i.e. set-asides, that are exempted from
the Agreement. If the Agreement were revised to allow small business
set-asides, for the reasons extensively set out above, it would
remove the US' rationale for exempting them from the Agreement,
and the Buy American Act would also not be able to apply, so much
of the extensive national protectionism that surrounds the US
procurement system could be eroded.
A new agreement would, of course, be difficult
and probably take many years of extensive negotiations to reach.
However, an agreement which provides the flexibility to take measures
to ensure SMEs' access to government contracts, while ruling out
national protectionism to a far greater extent than at present,
is desperately needed, and therefore the process should be initiated.
Therefore, the UK Government should support
current moves in the EU for a revised Agreement to be tabled.
As we have made clear, though, we do not support a watered-down
Agreement or opt-out being used for purposes of national protectionism,
and understand the reservations of those who believe that it would
be used as such. Nevertheless, a proposal for a new agreement,
or indeed for an interim opt-out while a new agreement was being
negotiated, would probably be more widely supported if it were
made clear that it would not be used for protectionism, especially
by the relevant EU commissioners.
In negotiating in the EU, we have to be aware
that there are many countries where small businesses do not experience
the same problems as they do in the UK. These countries therefore
see no reason to tackle the problem of small businesses' access
to government contracts. However, their support is needed for
the EU to table a revised WTO agreement. Given the circumstances,
we must explain to them the asymmetry that a measure that can
only be negotiated by the EU is necessary to make improvements
in the UK.
CONCLUSION
Small businesses do undoubtedly need better
access to government contracts in the UK. SMEs make up 99.8% of
the businesses in the UK and yet they receive only 22% of government
contracts. Procurement procedures and policies are uncompetitive
and inefficient, because government is not a commercial organisation
subject to competitive constraints.
A holistic reform of the procurement system
is required, making government act and think more like a commercial
organisation when it procures products, and building incentives
in to the system.
To fully ensure the legal flexibility to implement
the necessary measures, we would need the EU to table a revised
Agreement on Government Procurement. The agreement should permit
the necessary pro-competitive SME-friendly measures, while clamping
down on national protectionism in procurement.
11 January 2007
http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/site/en/oj/2004/l_134/l_13420040430en01140240.pdf
http://www.dau.mil/pubs/pm/pmpdf97/campblnd.pdf
http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/site/en/oj/2004/l_134/l_13420040430en01140240.pdf
50 GRYLLS MP, Michael; POETON, William, and
FORRESTER, Julian, Defence Procurement: A private mission to
discover the efficacy of competitive purchasing methods carried
out by the United States DOD (April 15-20 1985), and an opinion
on its relevance to UK and some European Community Practices,
1986. Back
51
Confédération Générale des Petites
et Moyennes Entreprises, SMEs' access to public procurement,
October 2006. Back
52
Confédération Générale des Petites
et Moyennes Entreprises, SMEs' access to public procurement,
October 2006. Back
53
Supply2Gov, How To Tender, www.supply2.gov.uk/how-tender.shtml Back
54
CLARK, Major and MOUTRAY PhD, Chad, The Future of Small Businesses
in the US Federal Government Marketplace, 2004, page 4. Back
55
Supply2Gov, How to Tender, www.supply2.gov.uk/how-tender.shtml Back
56
For more information on New Look and Matalan see http://www.fpb.org/YVHWzPVo5lMmUA.html Back
57
http://www.warmwell.com/03nov12pq.html Back
58
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Principal-agent_problem Back
59
EU Directive 2004/18/EC, Article 53 (on page 35) Back
60
Grylls, Poeton and Forrester, 1986, page 8. Back
61
Grylls, Poeton and Forrester, 1986, page 12. Back
62
Grylls, Poeton and Forrester, 1986, page 14. Back
63
Grylls, Poeton and Forrester, 1986, page 14. Back
64
Clark and Moutray, 2004, page 7. Back
65
Clark and Moutray, 2004, page 8. Back
66
US Public Law 83-163 paragraph 202, reproduced by Clark and Moutray,
2004. Back
67
Poeton and Forrester, 1986, page 7. Back
68
Poeton and Forrester, 1986, page 4. Back
69
Poeton and Forrester, 1986, page 3. Back
70
Poeton and Forrester, 1986, page 4. Back
71
Poeton and Forrester, 1986, page 2. Back
72
Wikipedia, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Buy_American_Act. Back
73
Clark and Moutray, 2004, page 7. Back
74
Clark and Moutray, 204, page 5-8. Back
75
Campbell, Donald L., Acquisition Reform: A Trojan Horse In
Our Midst? Back
76
Clark and Moutray, 2004, page 8. Back
77
EU Directive 2004/18/EC, http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/site/en/oj/2004/l_134/l_13420040430en01140240.pdf,
page 1 paragraph 1 states "Having regard to the Treaty establishing
the European Community... and Article 95 thereof." Article
95 is the clause establishing the internal market and acts as
the legal base for the Directive. Back
78
EU Directive 2004/18/EC, article 41 (on page 29) Back
79
EU Directive 2004/18/EC, article 2. Back
80
EU Directive 2004/18/EC, article 44 (on page 31). Back
81
EU Directive 2004/18/EC, Article 35-37 (on page 26 and 27). Back
82
WTO, Overview of the Agreement on Government Procurement,
http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/gproc_e/over_e.htm Back
83
Foreign Affairs and International Trade Canada, 2001 WTO Consultations
Doha (Qatar) Ministerial Meeting Government Procurement-Information
Paper, http://www.international.gc.ca/tna-nac/gp-info-en.asp Back
84
WTO, Overview of the Agreement on Government Procurement,
http://www.wto.org/english/tratop-e/gproc_e/over_e.htm Back
85
Agreement on Government Procurement, Article 7, http://www.wto.org/english/docs-e/legal_e/gpr-94_e.pdf Back
86
EU Directive 2004/18/EC, Article 2 (on page 9). Back
87
Agreement on Government Procurement, Article 8, http://www.wto.org/english/docs_e/legal_e/gpr-94_e.pdf Back
88
Agreement on Government Procurement, Article 10, http://www.wto.org/english/docs_e/legal_e/gpr-94_e.pdf Back
89
Agreement on Government Procurement, Article 13 paragraph
4 (b), http://www.wto.org/english/docs_e/legal_e/gpr-94_e.pdf Back
90
Foreign Affairs and International Trade Canada, 2001 WTO Consultations
Doha (Qatar) Ministerial Meeting Government Procurement-Information
Paper, http://www.international.gc.ca/tna-nac/gp-info-en.asp Back
|