Select Committee on Business and Enterprise Written Evidence


Supplementary evidence submitted by energywatch

PAPER FOR ENERGYWATCH BY DR PHILIP MARSDEN,[199] BRITISH INSTITUTE OF INTERNATIONAL AND COMPARATIVE LAW

IT IS TIME FOR AN ENERGY MARKET INVESTIGATION BY THE COMPETITION COMMISSION

  In recent years, governments and the European Commission have become increasingly concerned about anti-competitive activity in the energy sector. Several inquiries have made clear that it is a "market that is not working fairly for consumers or many providers. The European Commission's sector inquiry identified five core problems of market concentration; vertical foreclosure; lack of market integration; lack of transparency; and price formation.[200] To try to address some of these problems, Ofgem and other national regulators keep the sector subject to regulatory review; while national competition authorities and the European Commission's DG-Competition have increased use of their competition law enforcement powers, including:

    —  reviewing mergers more strictly[201];

    —  reviewing state aid and other government support; and

    —  launching dawn raids that have uncovered further evidence of price-fixing and abusive foreclosure of competitors.[202]

  These newly discovered anticompetitive practices are particularly troubling, as one would not expect further anti-competitive arrangements to keep arising in a sector under regulatory scrutiny. This strongly suggests the need for more work in this sector. It is energywatch's view that apart from the recently announced probe into the energy supply markets,[203] Ofgem have not held serious investigations into these markets since 2004 and have made very little intervention at both wholesale and retail levels of the markets.[204] In particular, due to its limited resources and primary focus on monopoly infrastructure, Ofgem has paid limited attention to the relation between the retail and wholesale markets. Our current regulatory and competition law review of the energy sector in the UK need to be supplemented if they are to be effective. Fortunately, help is close at hand. In the UK we are in the unique position of being able to benefit from the added scrutiny and remedies available through a Competition Commission market investigation.

  We will identify the key benefits of such an investigation, and submit that the Secretary of State should call for such an investigation without delay.

  Only a market investigation by the Competition Commission can ensure that OFGEM and the other authorities are assisted in their crucial role of making this market work fairly for consumers in the UK.

Background to the regime

  The Enterprise Act created the UK market investigation reference regime, whereby the OFT has the power to refer markets to the Competition Commission for further investigation where it has reasonable grounds for suspecting that any feature, or combination of features, of a market is preventing, restricting, or distorting competition.[205] Under this system the Competition Commission will decide whether competition is indeed prevented, restricted or distorted, and if so what, if any, action should be taken to remedy the adverse effect on competition or any detrimental effect on customers arising from the adverse effect. According to the legislation "detrimental effect" can take two forms: (a) higher prices, lower quality or less choice of goods or services in any market in the United Kingdom (whether or not the market to which the feature or features concerned relate); or (b) less innovation in relation to such goods or services.[206]

Examples of Market Investigation References: in the energy sector, comprehensive review and remedial powers

  In 2002-03, the Competition Commission reviewed the acquisition by Centrica plc from Dynegy Inc of two companies that owned and operated the Rough gas storage facility.[207] A major issue for the inquiry was whether, as a result of the merger, Centrica would be likely to withhold sources of flexible gas in order to force up wholesale gas prices. The Competition Commission found that Centrica could be expected: (a) to discriminate between customers in giving access to capacity at Rough; (b) to use to its advantage sensitive information gained from the operation of Rough; (c) to withhold information about the operation of Rough; (d) to be less innovative in marketing Rough products than another owner; and (e) to invest less in expanding Rough's capacity than another owner. As a result, the Competition Commission determined that competition in the markets for flexible gas and domestic gas supply would be weakened, with the likely consequence of price increases will be higher than in the absence of the merger. To prevent these adverse effects, the Competition Commission required that Centrica give statutory undertakings regarding its behaviour as owner of Rough. The major elements of the undertakings were that Centrica would: sell Rough's full capacity on non-discriminatory terms; auction all capacity remaining unsold no less than 30 days before the start of each storage year, with no reserve price; maintain legal, financial and physical separation between its storage business and all other parts of the group; ensure that no commercially sensitive information arising from the operation of Rough is passed to other parts of Centrica; and make any disclosure of information relating to the storage operations to all market participants simultaneously; facilitate the efficient operation and development of the secondary market in Rough capacity; offer at least 20% of Rough's capacity on annual contracts. The Competition Commission maintained the power to divest assets if Centrica did not comply with these commitments.

THE COMPETITION COMMISSION WAS THE ONLY GOVERNMENT BODY ABLE TO RECOMMEND THE INTRODUCTION OF COMPETITION INTO THE ENERGY SECTOR IN THE EARLY 1990'S

  In 1992 the then Director General of Gas Supply asked the then Monopolies and Mergers Commission (MMC) to investigate whether the operation by British Gas plc of its pipeline system and other facilities for the transportation, and storage of gas, operates against the public interest.[208] Related references were sent to the MMC at the time by the Secretary of State into the supply of gas to tariff customers and to non-tariff customers, and into the conveyance or storage of gas by public gas suppliers. reports. The MMC found that because BG was both a seller of gas, and owner of the transportation system which its competitors have no alternative but to use, this dual role gave rise to an inherent conflict of interest which makes it impossible to provide the necessary conditions for self-sustaining competition. The MMC recommended modification of BG's Authorisation so as to establish its businesses as separate units. The Secretary of State (whose final decision it was) chose not to implement the MMC's recommendation, but British Gas decided to establish "Transco" as a separate unit in 1994 and the formal demerger that led to the creation of Centrica took place in February 1997. It was only after this MMC report, that competition actually became possible in the gas sector in the UK.

OTHER MARKET INVESTIGATIONS: NO FEAR TO ACT

Excessive prices

  In Store Cards the OFT referred the supply of store card services to the Competition Commission following its conclusion that there are features of the sector, both in the supply of store card credit to consumers and in the supply of store card services to retailers, that appear to prevent, restrict or distort competition.[209] In paragraph 1.13 of its report the OFT stated that "there is insufficient competition to ensure that consumers get good value from store cards and that such lack of competition may lead to increased profits for retailers and store card providers".[210] For the OFT then, the possible harm to consumers resulting from the perceived lack of competition in this sector revolved around the concept of value for money. The idea of "good value" brings to mind the definition of an "unfair price" in the case United Brands Co. v Commission; it concerns a price that is "excessive in relation to the economic value of the product supplied".[211] In other words the OFT is formulating the possible consumer detriment in this sector in terms of unfair or excessive prices for consumers.[212] In its investigation the Competition Commission tried to quantify this consumer detriment by comparing the prices actually paid by cardholders who pay interest and insurance charges on store cards with the prices they would have paid had these reflected costs, including the cost of capital.[213]

  Subsequent market investigation references submitted to the Competition Commission have also concerned the impact of (weak) competition on prices paid by consumers; see for example Supply of Liquefied Petroleum Gas[214] or Northern Ireland Banking[215] In the former case the OFT suspected that "the high switching costs [between different gas companies in the market for the supply of domestic bulk liquefied petroleum gas] may form a barrier to entry, so that competition is restricted and many consumers face higher prices overall than they would in a similar market without switching costs".[216] In the latter case, the OFT held that the conditions for a referral were met as high levels of concentration, significant entry barriers, price parallelism and consumer inertia appear together to result in limited price competition and weak switching competition between the big four banks in Northern Ireland.[217] Both investigations are ongoing.

  In Home Collected Credit[218] the Competition Commission actually attempted to quantify the overcharge suffered by customers in the relevant market; according to the CC customers suffered from "substantial overcharging":

    [overcharging] may have amounted to as much as £100 million a year over the last five years across the whole market, which would imply that a home credit customer pays over £25 too much for an average loan, or £9 per £100 borrowed, and that home credit lenders have been able to earn more than £500 million in profits in excess of the cost of capital in the last five years.[219]

  This case thus highlights that the Competition Commission: (i) considers overcharging as a form of consumer detriment; and (ii) is willing to quantify the extent of the overcharge when possible. Home Collected Credit also demonstrates that the CC will consider the effects of weak competition on particular categories of consumers as well as consumers in general. Indeed, on the facts before it the Competition Commission expressed its belief that the overcharge may have more of an effect on single mothers under 35:

    Home credit customers were more likely than the population as a whole to be female, to be under 35, to have young families, to fall into socio-economic groups D and E, to live in a low-income household and to live in housing rented from a local council or housing association.[220]

It is not just about price . . .

  In Home Collected Credit signalled how the Competition Commission will also consider different forms of consumer detriment where relevant:

    We shall determine whether any effect on advertisers or users [ie consumers] in the form of higher prices, lower quality or less choice of goods and services, or less innovation has resulted from, or may be expected to result from, any adverse effects on competition in the relevant market or markets.[221]

  Indeed, if the Competition Commission decides that there is an adverse effect on competition it must "take action to `remedy, mitigate or prevent' the adverse effect on competition and to `remedy, mitigate or prevent any detrimental effects on customers' so far as those effects have resulted from the adverse effect".[222] By definition "any detrimental effects" must also include those detrimental effects that cannot be classed solely as effects on the prices paid by consumers.

  In the ongoing Groceries Market Investigation, the Competition Commission has recently published its Provisional Remedies notice, which recommends a number of competition policy solutions, including the introduction of a "competition test" when local planning authorities are assessing planning applications for new large grocery stores, and A requirement on grocery retailers to lift existing exclusivity arrangements that have been in place for more than five years, where these have been identified as a barrier to entry by a competing retailer in areas of high concentration. In addition, however, the Competition Commission has recommended remedies that go beyond what competition law itself could do: namely that the Department for Business, Enterprise and Regulatory Reform amend the Land Agreements Exclusion Order so that agreements which restrict grocery retailing should no longer benefit from exclusion from the Competition Act.[223]

What can the authorities do?

Ofgem

  Of course, Ofgem is the port of first resort in examining the energy sector. It is energywatch's view that apart from the recently announced probe into the energy supply markets, Ofgem has not held serious investigations into these markets since 2004 and has made very little intervention at both wholesale and retail levels of the markets. It has also only paid limited attention to the relation between the retail and wholesale markets.

The Competition Commission

  Although all of the UK authorities have considered consumer detriment in its many different forms, it appears that the OFT, at least, seems to concentrate primarily on price related consumer detriment. The Competition Commission, by contrast, will consider more readily the other aspects of consumer harm (viz the negative impact of conduct on innovation, quality and choice for consumers) especially when considering a particular market in the context of a market investigation reference. The Competition Appeal Tribunal also takes a more dynamic approach to the market. For the CAT consumers may be harmed through the higher long-run price levels, reduction in choice and decreases in quality, which, in general, significant distortion of competition brings.

Greater powers than DG-Competition

  In contrast, the type of sectoral inquiry employed at EC level can only be used to enforce the competition law rules enshrined in Articles 81 and 82 EC. In other words the EC Commission is not empowered to adopt any remedies that would aim to resolve the particular market failure in question; rather, it must bring competition law based cases against undertakings if it wishes to use its administrative powers to solve the problem identified. It is obvious then that the above arguments concerning potential benefits are more relevant for the UK market investigation regime

  The Competition Commission, in contrast to its counterpart in Brussels, has a wide discretion, and the necessary power to adopt a wide range of measures designed to remedy an identified defect in the market. Such remedies available under Competition Commission guidelines can:

    —  make a significant and direct change to the structure of a market (eg, through divestment and unbundling);

    —  change the structure of a market less indirectly (eg, by reducing entry barriers or switching costs, by requiring the licensing of know-how or intellectual property rights, or by extending the compatibility of products through industry-wide technical standards);

    —  direct firms to discontinue certain behaviour (eg, giving advance notice of price changes) or to adopt certain behaviour (eg, more prominently displaying prices and other terms and conditions of sale);

    —  restrain the way in which firms would otherwise behave (eg, the imposition of a price cap); and

    —  monitor (eg, a requirement to provide the OFT with information on prices or profits).

  This is an impressive array of potential remedies. The European Commission, in contrast, can only pursue formal competition law cases using its powers to enforce Articles 81 and 82.

Competition Commission Plus

  In most cases action to impose the remedies can be taken by the Competition Commission. In other cases (such as changes to industry regulations), the Commission can only recommend such action to government departments or other bodies. The government has committed that it will respond publicly to any such recommendation within 90 days of the publication of the Competition Commission's report.

THE COMPETITION COMMISSION HAS AN EXPERT ENERGY PANEL ON-HAND

  The Competition Commission also has a special utilities panel, made up of CC members expert in the energy and related sectors. Most usually the panel deals with water, electricity, gas and energy code modification appeals but these members would clearly be involved in any market investigation into the energy sector, thus ensuring an expert and thorough review.

THE COMPETITION COMMISSION EXISTS TO FILL THE EXISTING GAP BETWEEN REGULATION (OFGEM) AND COMPETITION LAW ENFORCEMENT (OFT)

  In the words of the Chairman of the Competition Commission, Peter Freeman:

    "Not only are market investigations a very useful way of investigating industry-wide issues but, in terms of fairness of process, thoroughness of investigation and practicality of remedies, they can have important advantages over the so-called `prohibition' system. And with a maximum of two years they are comparatively quick for what they can deliver. So, in conclusion, I do not know what chemical is concocted from mixing regulatory "chalk" with competition "cheese"; but . . . the distinction between them is not as clear cut as some would argue and that, in particular, market investigations can act as a bridge over whatever gap divides the two".[224]

So what is needed?

  Even before a market investigation is called, it is obvious what is needed to address the problems identified by the European Commission alone:

  The most obvious candidate is improved transparency. The recent price spikes in the UK gas market and the difficulties in determining why more gas was not flowing from the Continent to the UK are a clear indication of this. If the authorities have difficulties getting the information that they need, competitors of the vertically integrated incumbents must be operating completely in the dark. So regulation here may well be needed. The Competition Commission is ideally suited to identify further informational remedies to promote transparency in this sector.

  However, transparency alone will not suffice. The greatest problems with the sector stem purely from oligopoly, and indeed collective dominance. In such cases, as the European Commission has identified in this and other sectors,[225] the primary problem is one of a forcing out, or keeping out, of rival providers, and thereby allowing incumbents to charge consumers what they wish. Other problems may arise as well, simply out of coordinated effects and tacit collusion that can stem from oligopoly. One of the most common problems in such a closely held market, however, is the fact that two to three players can effectively sew up the market through long-term agreements with downstream distributors. This is precisely the problem identified by the European Commission in the energy sector. In its final report on its sector inquiry, the EC reported that "the prevalence of long-term supply contracts between gas producers and incumbent importers makes it very difficult for new entrants to access gas on the upstream markets. Similarly, electricity generation assets are in the hand of a few incumbent suppliers or are indirectly controlled by them on the basis of long-term power purchase agreements . . . giving the incumbents control over the essential inputs into the wholesale markets".[226] "The Sector Inquiry has also confirmed the vertical tying of markets by long-term downstream contracts as a priority for review of case situations under competition law and of providing guidance where required".[227]

  These problems of vertical foreclosure and long-term contracts, and the linking through de facto integration between the wholesale and retail levels, is precisely the problem that energywatch has identified as prevailing in the UK energy sector.[228] It needs to be addressed as a matter of high priority by Her Majesty's Government, and it is submitted that the Competition Commission has the analytical tools, the remedial powers and the expertise to do the job.

1 April 2008





199   Senior Research Fellow and Director, Competition Law Forum-http://www.biicl.org/philipmarsden/ Back

200   European Commission, Energy Sector Inquiry, Final Report, January 2007. Back

201   R Owen-Howes and C Thomas, "Freeing Energy" finding that stricter merger control is a major policy tool of the European Commission, when its usual competition law enforcement powers under Article 81 and 82 are found wanting: reviewing the E.On/MOL, GDP/EDP/ENI, Endesa/Gas Natural and Endesa/E.On transactions. Competition Law Insight, 6 June 2006. Back

202   Spiegel Online reported as late as November 2007 that the German BundesKartellamt and European Commission have found evidence of price-fixing after raids in Germany yielded thousands of documents in dawn raids. "German Energy Giants Accused of Collusion", Spiegel Online, 5 November 2007. The European Commission is also investigating Distrigas, the dominant gas supplier in Belgium-for suspected violations of Article 82 from its long term gas supply contracts with many of its industrial customers. Back

203   http://www.ofgem.gov.uk/Media/PressRel/Documents1/ProbeFINAL.pdf Back

204   Allan Asher, Chief Executive of energywatch, "Consumer welfare-a casualty of `light touch' regulation-The End of Regulation as we know it? . . . so where next?" SBGI 2008 Seminar London, 6 March 2008, Back

205   See Part IV of the Enterprise Act 2002. Back

206   Ibid at Section 134(5). It should be obvious that these two "effects" are the opposite of those defined as benefits under Section 1(a) of the same act; see supra. Section 134(8) also defines customer benefit as (i) lower prices, higher quality or greater choice of goods or services in any market in the United Kingdom; or (ii) greater innovation in relation to such goods or services. Back

207   http://www.competition-commission.org.uk/rep-pub/reports/2003/480centrica.htmfull Back

208   http://www.competition-commission.org.uk/rep_pub/reports/1993/335britishgas.htmsummary Back

209   Store Cards, OFT Reference to the Competition Commission, 18 March 2004. Back

210   Emphasis added. Back

211   United Brands Co. v Commission [1978] 1 CMLR 429, at paragraph 235. Back

212   At paragraph 6.1 of the reference, the OFT underlined its suspicions that excess prices were being paid by some consumers for certain store cards: "the provision of store card credit may not be working well for consumers. It is possible . . . that the difference between the interest charged on store cards and other credit cards is not fully explained by the offsetting benefits and the differences in the cost of providing these services". Back

213   See Paragraph 1 of Annex 9.1 of the Competition Commission Report, available at: http://www.competition-commission.org.uk/rep_pub/reports/2006/509storecards.htm. Back

214   Supply of Liquefied Petroleum Gas, Market Investigation Reference, 5 July 2004. Back

215   Northern Ireland Banking, Market Investigation Reference, 26 May 2005. See also: Home Collected Credit, Market Investigation Reference, 20 December 2004. Back

216   At paragraph 3 of the OFT Reference (emphasis added). Back

217   See paragraph 75 of the OFT Report. Back

218   Home Collected Credit, Market Investigation Reference, 20 December 2004. Back

219   Ibid, Competition Commission News Release, 27 April 2006, available at: http://www.competition-commission.org.uk/inquiries/current/homecredit/index.htm, at p 1. It should be noted that these findings are only provisional and that the Competition Commission intends to discuss them further with home credit companies before making its final conclusions on the matter: ibidBack

220   Ibid, at p 2. Back

221   Classified Directory Advertising Services, Market Investigation Reference, 5 April 2005, Competition Commission, Issues Statement, Paragraph 17 (emphasis added). Back

222   Northern Ireland Banking, Market Investigation Reference, 26 May 2005, at paragraph 83 of the OFT Report (emphasis added). See also Section 138 of the Enterprise Act 2002. Back

223   Competition Commission, Provisional Decision on Remedies. http://www.competition-commission.org.uk/inquiries/ref2006/grocery/provisional_decision_remedies.htm Back

224   P Freeman, "Regulation and Competition-Chalk and Cheese? The Role of the Competition Commission", CRI Frontiers of Regulation Conference, Keynote Speech University of Bath 7 September 2006Back

225   Case T-342/99 Airtours/First Choice [2002] ECR II-2585; Case T-464/04, IMPALA vs Commission of the European Communities, 13 July 2006. Back

226   European Commission, Energy Sector Inquiry, Final Report, January 2007 at 8. Back

227   European Commission, Energy Sector Inquiry, Final Report, January 2007 at 13. Back

228   energywatch, Efficiency Review of the GB Wholesale Gas and Electricity Markets; Business and Enterprise Committee: Inquiry into possible anti-competitive behaviour in the energy markets. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2008
Prepared 28 July 2008