Select Committee on Environmental Audit Minutes of Evidence


Memorandum submitted by the Chemical Industries Association

  The Chemical Industries Association (CIA) Climate Change Agreement (CCA) covers around 300 sites in a sector which, in total, has 190,000 employees across every region of the UK. The sector is one of the UK's most important industrial sectors, accounting for 11% of manufacturing gross value added and is the only major sector to maintain a significant positive trade balance, typically registering a surplus of £5 billion annually. The chemical industry faces global competition with UK assets predominantly owned by companies that are headquartered overseas.

  The industry converts both mineral and plant based raw materials into key intermediates for use by other manufacturing sectors as well as its own final products for households, ranging from paints to detergents, fragrances to pharmaceuticals. We buy our raw materials and sell our bulk products at global prices with energy representing a high proportion of the conversion cost. As well as being major consumers of both gas and electricity for heating and power, our members use gas and oil as feedstocks—for some companies energy represents 30% or more of their total costs.

  As we are both energy intensive and exposed to international competition, the impact of the Climate Change Levy (CCL) on our business could have been significant, had the CCA commitments not provided a means for securing relief. Under the CCAs we have a good track record for improving our performance while the use of relative targets has ensured there is no disadvantage to production growth it is on an energy efficient basis. Unfortunately, overlaps and duplication have arisen with other instruments eg: the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS).

  After the current CCAs run their course, we see a continuing role for a CCA-type instrument suited to energy intensive sites which fall below EU ETS coverage which, unlike the proposed Carbon Reduction Commitment (CRC), qualifies them for relief from the energy tax (currently the CCL) as provided for by the Energy Products Directive. While effectively targeting continued improvements in performance, it is important that this instrument:

    —  Minimizes competitive impacts;

    —  Does not incentivize displacement of activity to countries which are not carbon constrained;

    —  Avoids administrative complexity arising from overlaps or coexistence with other instruments on the same site;

    —  Ensures that operators receive a single and predictable carbon price signal.

OVERALL COMMENTS ON THE CONTRIBUTION OF THE CLIMATE CHANGE LEVY AND AGREEMENTS TO EFFICIENCY IMPROVEMENTS

  There should be greater recognition that the CCAs are a success story. In the chemical industry the CCAs have further built on our already good record for energy efficiency improvement. Over 1990-98, the sector's voluntary energy efficiency agreement with DETR produced an 18% efficiency improvement and, since then the sector's CCA has contributed 20%: in total this is a 34% improvement from 1990 to the 2006.

  We firmly believe that the CCAs that have raised awareness and generated beyond business as usual improvements both through the challenging but achievable targets that have been negotiated but also through instilling a greater ethos of measurement to manage to improve. Top level involvement has been stimulated through the requirement to implement the qualitative requirements (an energy policy and plan) and the need, in many companies, for board level sanction for emissions trading decisions. We believe that increased awareness is being sustained because:

    —  Companies are required to maintain their CCAs and report progress: this includes continuing to meeting the qualitative requirements and an obligation to review targets every 4 years—in the 2004 review chemical sector 2010 targets were tightened by an average of 4%.

    —  Our large companies and many of our SMEs include the price UK Emissions Trading Scheme (UKETS) allowances in their investment and other business decisions.

  There are a number of findings in the National Audit Office (NAO) report on the CCL and CCAs which we would like to comment on:

    —  Business is divided over the effectiveness of the CCAs—this is credible in the context of many targets being imposed "top-down". Whereas CCA targets in the most intensive sectors, like chemicals, are developed on a "bottom-up" basis according to what is challenging and achievable at site level, many of the less intensive sector's targets have been set on a "top-down" basis in which all sites commit to an average sector improvement. Clearly, a top-down approach will be tough on some and easier for others and will therefore appear less meaningful.

    —  DEFRA's latest modelling suggests that CCAs have contributed less emissions reductions than originally estimated. This is on the basis that business as usual improvements have increased over original quantifications, although NAO recognises that the results of such econometric modelling are subject to a high degree of uncertainty. While there is no doubt that the more competitive global environment together with energy price rises have helped to drive increased efficiency, it would be counterproductive to vary climate change commitments with every change in business as usual as this would create administrative burdens and uncertainty. What matters is that targets are met and that any unexpected sustainable overachievements are factored into the next CCA target review, planned for 2008. It should be noted that high energy prices also have a negative impact and, at the 2006 milestone, led to lower throughput, and reduced contributions from combined heat and power—symptoms which, together with increased requirements for environmental abatement, were anticipated to act as a drag on our efficiency in the 2004 review.

    —  The announcement of CCL resulted in businesses making energy efficiency improvements—we believe that most of the improvements have taken place in the CCAs. This is because we do not believe that CCL has been at sufficient levels to drive improvements outside the CCAs of most non-intensive organisations whereas energy costs are relatively insignificant to the cost base. The study by Cambridge Econometrics NAO cite, which attempts to quantify the CCL announcement effect, appears to place a heavy caveat on its findings when it records that how far the observed fall in energy consumption is attributable to an announcement effect or a rise in temperatures is a matter of "econometric judgement". In relation to the Ineos Chlor case study cited as evidence of the CCL announcement effect it should be noted that the intention to negotiate agreements for energy intensive sectors was also part of this announcement and that Ineos Chlor are CCA participants whose improvements have also been attributed to the chemical sector CCA. Other anecdotal evidence, including that from the Carbon Trust's experience, CBI surveys, and the NAO's survey, support the view that most improvements have taken place in the energy intensive sectors covered by the CCAs.

  Please find below our comments on the issues set out in the EAC's call for evidence.

1.  Is it right for the Levy and Agreements to target energy use, or should they be reformed to target carbon emissions directly? If so, how should they be changed?

  It is important that any future CCL changes take care to ensure that there is continuity in regulatory incentives which have driven long term investments. CCL is the foundation on which several Government incentivisation programmes are built, eg: exemptions for Combined Heat and Power Quality Assurance (CHPQA) and renewable source electricity. While we do not therefore support radical change, we believe that the efficacy of the CCL would be enhanced if it were developed to reflect carbon emissions rather than calorific value. This would then be consistent with the need to make a transition to a low carbon economy. However, if this change is made, it is imperative that equivalent incentivisation programmes be put in place to replace those founded upon CCL.

  The continuation of access to CCL relief is essential to sustaining the international competitiveness of intensive businesses in the chemicals sector—for some of our most intensive sites, energy accounts for more than 30% of total costs. We therefore see a continuing role for CCAs. While CCAs already provide incentives to use low carbon fuels through their link to the UKETS, we agree it would be sensible to make a full move to carbon based targets. However, we see a continuing role for relative targets as this approach directly incentivises reductions in the carbon footprint of products—until industry elsewhere becomes carbon constrained, absolute targets at site level risk driving carbon intensive production to potentially less efficient locations.

  We support the Government's decision to let the current CCAs run their full course, ie: to the 2010 target, and that CCL continues until March 2013 as this gives time to plan their successor. However, we are concerned that formal consultation on the future of the CCAs is being delayed until 2008. Energy intensive sectors like chemicals have long asset life cycles so it is important to have certainty to inform on long term planning decisions. We would therefore welcome an early indication from Government on the future of CCL and CCAs.

2.  With the advent of UK-wide carbon budgets from 2008 (proposed under the draft Climate Change Bill), how valuable is the focus of the CCL and CCA on the efficiency with which business consumes energy? Would it be better to have an instrument which enforced absolute caps in energy use (or CO2 emissions)?

  Part of the success of the CCAs has been due to their use of relative targets which ensure that improved energy efficiency is achieved without imposing a growth penalty. We see a continuing role for relative targets as this approach directly incentivises reductions in the carbon footprint of products—until industry elsewhere becomes carbon constrained, absolute targets risk displacing carbon intensive production to potentially less efficient locations. Indeed, carbon efficiency is becoming more prominent in the Commission's review of the ETS post-2012. EU ETS review discussions are currently signalling that benchmarks will be used to maintain free allocations and minimise competitive impacts—this interest is allied to a recognition that this approach has the added benefit of giving a performance (energy efficiency) signal.

3.  How well do the Levy and Agreements fit together with other existing and proposed climate change policies, and what can be done to ensure maximum impact from complementary policies with minimum administrative burden and overlap?

  There are too many economic instruments and carbon price signals per company.

  We estimate that in combination, CCL, the Renewables Obligation and the EU ETS have added around 20% to the cost of electricity in our sector as this includes the full CO2 cost pass through of the EU ETS (this estimate is relates to the period before the fall in the price of Phase 1 EU allowances which will be shortly be reversed with the start of Phase 2). This means that electricity users are paying for the related carbon emissions more than once—this is particularly impacting our competitiveness with non-EU producing regions.

  The introduction of EU ETS has also added to complexities and administrative burdens as sites now have to participate in two emissions trading schemes and overlaps in scheme coverage produce the need for a double counting mechanism. To minimise overlap, Government should consider extending exemption from CCL to EU ETS participants to reduce the need to participate in both EU ETS and CCAs. Now that EU ETS is in place we believe that the pass through of full CO2 costs to electricity prices provides sufficient incentive for sites in energy intensive sectors to improve their use of this energy source. Government should resist any drive for a CCA successor to target improvements in the end-use of electricity on intensive EU ETS sites. Small emitters should be excluded from the EU ETS because their participation is not cost effective; they would be better covered by equivalent schemes with lower administrative burdens like the CCAs.

  Coverage of sites by IPPC, CCAs and EU ETS leads to multiple CO2 emissions reporting requirements and frustrations arise from each scheme using different CO2 conversion factors. This needs to be rationalised as part of the review of the EU ETS and CCAs post-2012; change prior to that would bring a burden as systems are now established for the current CCAs.

4.  Businesses are able to use carbon trading to meet their targets under the Climate Change Agreements. What have been the impacts of trading so far? Should trading be allowed in this way, or how should it be controlled?

  UKETS has provided significant early learning benefits and has made some contribution to CCA overachievements. We believe trading to meet CCA targets should be allowed because UKETS is integral to the scheme.

  Through the CCAs, UKETS is the first cross manufacturing sector emissions trading scheme in the world. CCA participants in UKETS have benefited from early learning and in coming to the EU ETS many already understood how to trade, how to use a registry, and had established relations with various brokers. Due to this early experience, chemical companies have included the price of UKETS allowances in their business decisions and this has also lead them to include the price of EU ETS allowances when the scheme started. Participation in UKETS has helped to incentivise overachievements against CCA targets although, owing to the oversupply of allowances, these incentives have been relatively weak. A third of chemical sector participants have also traded to meet compliance at each milestone: despite low allowance prices, trading costs have added to awareness effects at top level within companies where trading decisions are sanctioned. Low prices have arisen in the context of UKETS being the original learning by doing scheme; we note there have been similar problems in Phase 1 of EU ETS—it is only from experience that these issues can be improved.

  By definition, emissions trading mechanisms work by trading to meet compliance. Trading provides a flexible mechanism which allows emissions across businesses to be secured at least cost while ensuring that overall environmental objectives are met. UKETS is integral to the CCAs and they were signed on the basis that there was provision for such trading. It is therefore entirely legitimate for a business to secure continued CCL relief by trading to meet CCA. Indeed, the EU Energy Products Directive provides for relief from such energy taxes to be provided to intensive businesses participating in trading schemes.

5.  What have been the economic impacts of the CCL and CCA on the organisations subject to them, and the wider UK economy?

  The cost impacts of CCL on our members have generally been muted as most pay after CCA relief at 80%. However, depending on the fuel and its current price, unrelieved CCL represents 10% to 20% of energy costs. Because our most intensive companies' energy costs can exceed 30% of their total costs, the loss of relief therefore represents a significant sanction.

  Because of set-up costs and ongoing administrative requirements, CCA companies tend not to find CCA participation worth management time if annual CCL savings are below £10,000 p.a. The administrative requirements are therefore not insignificant and can be complex as they comprise:

    —  CCA performance monitoring and reporting;

    —  annual checks on PP4 eligibility form including the 90/10 rule;

    —  maintaining claims for CCL on each account from each energy supplier with reviews at minimum on an annual frequency;

    —  participating in UKETS including the registry, dealing with trader/brokers and trading agreements, and any third party verification of overachievements.

  To understand resource requirements we undertook a case study of a chemical sector SME. The CCA facility in question is a speciality chemicals company engaged in manufacture by batch process. The company estimates that it spends 16 man-days p.a. on administrative requirements for CCAs at a cost of £7,000 p.a

  These figures demonstrate that CCA costs are not insignificant. However, they are below the burdens imposed by the EU ETS which the SME is also subject to although its annual emissions are below 25kCO2 p.a. The company estimates that, of the 16 man-day spent on its CCA, 13 man-days are on monitoring and reporting that is also used for EU ETS. But there are an additional 9.5 man-days (cost £3,500) which are EU ETS only and relate to permitting. In addition, the fees for the permit, permit variations and verification total £1,800 p.a. It is clear that coverage by EU ETS adds significantly to administrative burdens and that, in this respect, the lighter touch of CCAs is a more appropriate instrument for small emitters in intensive sectors.

6.  Should the Climate Change Agreements be reformed in any way? For instance, should the Agreements be simplified, or the sectoral targets made more stringent?

  It would be sensible to make a full move to carbon based targets, reduce overlaps with other instruments and make CCAs and other instruments in the policy mix more consistent (see also answers to questions 1, 2 and 3).

  Simplifications should include the removal of requirements for third party verification to generate emissions allowances from CCA overachievements. This requirement makes individual verification of small overachievements, eg: by SMEs, uneconomic. Instead, allocations should be made based on self-certified data, though this should be backed by an increased number of sample audits. This would be consistent with the self-certification principle included in the Government's CRC proposals. We would also favour some relaxation in the 90/10 rule as this bars a number of our sites from including all their activities under a CCA and thereby taking a holistic approach to targeting efficiency improvements.

  The current CCAs already include provision to review targets every four years to take account of changes in circumstances, eg: new technological developments. The review conducted in 2004 strengthened the chemical sector relative energy target for 2010 by 4% and this greatly reduced the overachievement at the 2006 milestone. The Government has confirmed that next review set in the agreements, for 2008, will go ahead as planned. With reference to the final bullet in paragraph 3.32 of the NAO report, it is clearly correct that emissions allowances built up from overachievements in previous milestones should not be factored into the review. This is because, under the principles of emissions trading, these form part of the payback for the improvement measures in question. It is also entirely correct, of course, that any unexpected, but sustainable overachievements are factored into the next CCA target review.

  We would support the new, independent Climate Change Committee advising Government on the review to ensure the right balance is struck between contributions from early starters in CCA sectors and other sectors of the UK economy, where there may be more cost effective potential.

7.  What are the main barriers to accelerating energy efficiency in the business sector? How can these be overcome?

  In the chemical sector, an acceleration in energy efficiency will require significant process change/plant replacement or the development and innovation of step change technologies. This is because the sector is an early starter in improving the energy efficiency of its existing assets and much of the "low hanging fruit" has been addressed. Over 1990-98, the sector's voluntary energy efficiency agreement with DETR produced an 18% efficiency improvement and, since then the sector's CCA has contributed 20%: in total this is a 34% improvement from 1990 to 2006.

  Economic barriers therefore include availability of cost effective energy efficiency projects, capital to fund them, and asset life cycles. Plant supporting our most energy intensive activities tends to have long life cycles (eg: ethylene crackers, where equipment can be continuously upgraded and refurbished within a framework laid down 20 or more years ago). While market based instruments like emissions trading can help to improve the payback on complete replacement, it would need an unsustainably high carbon price to provide sufficient incentive to replace plant mid-way through its life. What's more, a multilateral approach to emissions trading is a pre-requisite for a high carbon price as, until industry elsewhere becomes carbon constrained, this would risk displacing carbon intensive production to potentially less efficient locations.

  There are also barriers to innovation. In the above context, as Nick Stern recognizes, additional sources of coordination and support are needed to work alongside carbon markets to ensure the development and innovation of the step-change technologies that will be needed to move us towards our ambitious long term climate change goals. In this respect we feel more needs to be done to support commercialisation and demonstration of step change technologies.

  Finally, uncertainty about the future climate change policy mix also represents a barrier to improving energy efficiency. In the longer term it is difficult to anticipate additional changes as a result of climate change policy. There is considerable uncertainty about the future shape of EU ETS and CCAs post-2012 and whether these systems will be part of a multilateral or unilateral framework for addressing climate change. This uncertainty is inhibiting investment decisions

8.  Products which can increase energy efficiency (such as insulating glass for windows) can be energy-intensive to manufacture. Policies such as the CCL and CCA can penalise manufacturers for making such products. How big an issue is this, and what, if anything, should be done about it?

  Chemical sector products also provide some of the solutions to climate change, eg: materials for wind turbine blades, silicon for photovoltaic cells, fuel cells, insulation materials for housing, low weight materials for cars and other applications, synthetic rubber for low rolling resistance tyres and low temperature detergents.

  It would be very complex to recognise the contributions of these innovations in schemes aimed at improving plant efficiency. A key thing that can be done is to avoid penalising these technologies by providing for their coverage by relative targets which are consistent with their realistic carbon intensity—until industry elsewhere becomes carbon constrained, absolute targets risk displacing such production to potentially less efficient locations.

9.  Alongside the CCL, the Government introduced the Enhanced Capital Allowances, to further encourage firms to make energy saving investments. How well is this scheme working? How well does it fit with other existing or proposed climate change instruments?

  The ECA scheme provides information benefits because it helpfully identifies energy efficient equipment. Whether the 100% depreciation allowance in the first year is significant to an energy project depends on the extent to which it comprises eligible technologies. The Budget 2007 decision to extend equivalent financial benefits to companies that have not generated a profit will help to increase the take-up of the scheme and is very much welcomed.

10.  The Levy exempts electricity from renewables, though so far this appears to have had little impact. Should it play a greater role in incentivising the growth of renewable electricity, and, if so, how?

  Renewable electricity enjoys sufficient incentives from the combination of Renewables Obligation Certificates (ROCs) and Levy Exemption Certificates awarded to relevant schemes. Indeed, the banding proposal in the Energy White paper will increase the ROCs allocated to technologies which need higher levels of support to be economic. There is also an incentive from the full pass-through of EU ETS CO2 costs to electricity prices. There is therefore no need to increase the incentive from CCL.

2 October 2007





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2008
Prepared 10 March 2008