4 Kyoto instruments
Adaptation and mitigation funding
52. Given the likely impacts of climate change,
substantial funding will be required to help developing countries
to lower their emissions and adapt to the change that the world
is already committed to. As described earlier, such funding will
make or break a global deal. Adaptation costs alone will run to
some $86 billion by 2015. With mitigation costs as well a total
of $155 billion will be needed per year. [56]
Although these are vast sums of money, they should be put into
perspective. $155 billion is less than 0.5% of developed countries'
GDP.[57] Existing adaptation
funding mechanisms have only delivered $26 million so farthis
is around the same amount that the UK spends on flood defence
each week.[58]
53. The difficulties involved with ensuring the
delivery of such sums are made apparent when they are considered
alongside Official Development Assistance (ODA). A commitment
to give 0.7% developed country GNI as aid to developing countries
has been in place since the 1970s. It has not been delivered.
The UK provided 0.56% in 2007,[59]
up from 0.26% in 1997.[60]
At Gleneagles the G8 committed itself to increase aid by $50bn
by 2010, but this only translated into 0.36% of the GNI of the
G8approximately half of the 1970 target.[61]
The UN recently commented that the signs regarding the delivery
of aid commitments are 'not encouraging' and that aid has actually
decreased since 2006.[62]
It should also be remembered that the levels of climate change
funding described above would have to be in addition to currently
committed ODA.
54. Under the UNFCCC and Kyoto Protocol, $26
million is currently available each year for adaptation work in
developing countries. Dr Huq told us that these would not deliver
the scale of action required.[63]
He argued that it will be important to agree new and innovative
funding mechanisms able to generate regular and large sources
of capital. He pointed to the Adaptation Fund of the Kyoto Protocol
as an example of such an innovative funding mechanism. As it draws
money from a 2% levy placed upon CDM credits it is essentially
a global tax on an international transaction, and the tax is held
by an international fund rather than going into national treasuries.
This fund might generate US$160-950 million by 2012, depending
of the degree of trade and the costs of transactions. Jennifer
Morgan told us that deeper emissions cuts in developed countries
could mobilise increased CDM credits. She pointed out that an
advantage of using the international carbon market is that much
of this investment comes from the private sector. However, she
also made it clear that the international carbon market alone
will not provide the necessary funding.[64]
55. Given the size of the shortfall, there is
a need for further funding sources. One potential source could
be the partial auctioning of international emissions credits rather
than their free allocation as at present. Jennifer Morgan told
us that $150 billion per year could be generated if 40% of emissions
credits were auctioned at 30 to 40 $/ton, thereby generating enough
money for both adaptation and mitigation in developing countries.
An alternative to auctioning at an international level could be
the use of revenues raised from auctioning within emissions trading
schemes. The UN Human Development Report calculated that an adaptation
levy set at US$3/tonne CO2 on the EU ETS to 2012 would
raise US$570 million.[65]
Another source could be through direct taxation. It is claimed
that an international aviation levy of 5 euros per ticket could
generate 10 billion euros per year.[66]
Another source of funding could be from the potential border adjustment
taxes that might be introduced to protect domestic industries
at risk of carbon leakage. The hypothecation of such revenues
might make the introduction of such a tax more politically acceptable.
56. The Minister thought that 85% of the money
required would have to come from the private sector. He also thought
'funding should be multilateral; that recipient countries should
have a major say; that the World Bank should be a major conduit,
if not the major conduit'.[67]
Chris Dodwell told us that the Office of Climate Change had been
charged to undertake a project looking at 'ways of meeting this
gap[
] looking at the costs and benefits of auctioning,
versus ODA, versus other forms of finance'.[68]
He said that through the Strategic Climate Fund they would work
with the World Bank and others to pilot some different approaches
and 'actually try to work out how you can best get the right blend
of public and private finance into solving the problem'.[69]
57. The scale of funds required
for adaptation and mitigation in developing countries might run
to some US $150 billion each year by 2015. Given past failures
to meet commitments on Official Development Assistance it is unlikely
that conventional funding sources will deliver the funds required.
Existing mechanisms such as the international carbon market are
also unlikely to be able to mobilise the scale of funds required.
The Government has commissioned work to identify appropriate funding
mechanisms. We welcome this and urge that the work should be published
at the Government's earliest opportunity.
Technology transfer
58. As we found during our visit to China, technology
transfer is a top priority for developing countries. An agreement
on this will be required if we are to secure a successful conclusion
to the negotiations However, there appears to be confusion about
what technology transfer means. Dr Müller described it as
a 'euphemism which can be used by both sides to talk to each other
thinking that they
agree', but in actual fact 'in the north
we mean exports and in the south we mean gifts'.[70]
He said that given the significance placed upon this issue by
developing countries it would be best to let them decide what
they would like in this regard.
59. Some developing countries have argued that
intellectual property rights (IPR) are a barrier to the diffusion
and transfer of low-carbon technology. However, Mr David Hone,
Group Climate Change Adviser for Shell International, described
such concerns as a 'red herring'.[71]
He argued that technology is already successfully deployed around
the worldfrom computers to mobile phones, and that companies
will develop links with developing countries, especially those
where they wish to produce their goods. He could not think of
concrete examples of technology that needed to be transferred.[72]
Professor Burke agreed, and pointed out that wind technology was
being deployed quickly in developing countries and that it was
likely that other renewable energy technologies, such as photovoltaics,
were going to be built in China and India for the same reasons
that other goods were produced there. He cautioned that there
might be demands for certain technologies, such as nuclear, or
even technologies that might not necessarily have anything to
do with climate change.[73]
Dr Müller pointed out that CDM projects involve the transfer
of technology and that other mechanisms do the same, such as bilateral
agreements.
60. We asked a number of Chinese officials about
technology transfer. There was a general view that more advanced
technology is required to reduce emissions. Yu Qungtai, Chinese
Ambassador and Special Representative on Climate Change Talks,
told us that they do not possess the most efficient technologies
and urged western governments not to turn climate change into
a money-making exercise. He told us that China was not looking
for charity or gifts, but was instead looking for companies to
make technologies more affordable and available. Yu Qungtai said
he was encouraged by the UK Government's stance on technology
transfer. He welcomed the agreement made between the Prime Minister
and the Chinese Premier in January 2008. Chinese officials were
hopeful that this would lead to closer working on clean coal technology,
carbon capture and storage, capacity building, environmental technologies,
wider research and development, and also public awareness strategies.
However, a note of caution was raised by Xu Huaqing, Director
of the Centre for Energy, Environment and Climate Change, who
told us that in the past there had been a failure to ensure that
bilateral agreements resulted in the diffusion of technologies
across the country.
61. E3G also stressed the importance of technology
diffusion.[74] It said
that the establishment of Low-Carbon Economic Zones between the
EU and China could facilitate the required technological diffusion
and also provide 'testing grounds' for low-carbon policies.[75]
This option was also put forward by Chatham House in a recent
report, which concluded that the common interest of the EU and
China in a low carbon future could mean that, working together,
these countries could become the 'global powerhouse' of low-carbon
innovation.[76] It recommended
the creation of Low-Carbon Economic Zones as a way to focus EU
energy and climate cooperation with China 'to demonstrate the
real possibility of large-scale transformations to other regions
and countries'.[77] Chatham
House also recommended trade reforms involving joint agreements
on the energy efficiency of goods and also an agreement on free
trade in low-carbon products. In our Eleventh Report of Session
2005-06 we recommended action on the removal of trade barriers
to environmental goods and services. Bilateral agreements would
seem to be a way to take this forward.
62. There appears to be a widespread
perception in developing countries that they are missing out on
certain key technologies due to the expense of intellectual property
rights. This view has not been supported by the evidence that
we received. However, given the significance of this issue for
developing countries the Government is right to allow them to
develop their own proposals.
63. Low carbon technologies
will have to be deployed in developing countries. To facilitate
this, technology transfer will need to include the direct funding
of projects through mechanisms like the Clean Development Mechanism,
as well as bilateral work on research and development. We welcome
UK-China and EU-China commitments to closer working in relation
to climate change, environmental technologies and research and
development. It is critically important that these lead to advances
in the deployment and diffusion of low-carbon technologies. Parties
should explore the concept of Low-Carbon Economic Zones as a way
to focus joint-working opportunities. In addition the Government
and EU must seek to establish bilateral, low-carbon, free trade
agreements, and also to define stringent joint standards for energy
efficient goods. In order to aid the diffusion of low-carbon technology
globally, trade barriers to low-carbon goods and services must
be removed; efforts must continue on this issue in the Doha trade
round.
International credits
64. The Kyoto Protocol created three 'flexibility
mechanisms' in order to lower the overall cost of reducing greenhouse
gas emissions: the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM); Joint Implementation;
and emissions trading. These mechanisms enable countries to access
opportunities to reduce emissions in other countries where it
might be cheaper to do so.[78]
Damien Meadows explained that a significant benefit of the CDM
has been that it has engaged some 150 developing countries in
the international carbon trade.[79]
Dr Müller said that the CDM might have helped to pave the
way for action in developing countries. He thought that as the
CDM was now trusted by developing countries it might be used to
encourage them to take further action.[80]
Flexible mechanisms lower the incentive for developing countries
to free-ride as non-participants would not have access to the
funding that they provide.
65. Nevertheless, CDM credits can cause problems.
To begin with, credits have to be proven to be 'additional' i.e.
that a project would not have gone ahead without flexible mechanism
funding. There have been concerns about the true additionality
and sustainability of certain projects[81]although
witnesses to this inquiry thought that the robustness of CDM rules
lowered this risk. There is also a fear that permitting the use
of too many international credits in the EU might mean that the
necessary action and investment does not take place domestically.
For example, it could undermine investment in renewables making
it more expensive to deliver the renewables targets.[82]
66. Recent European Commission proposals have
sought to limit CDM credit use within the EU ETS. In order to
balance the risk that use of CDM credits would undermine domestic
efforts, and to ensure that the cost of compliance was not too
high, it proposed that no new credits should be permitted in the
third emissions trading period. Instead, credits can be carried
over from the second period. As the second period allocation was
so generous this equates to more than a third of the total reduction
effort by 2020 within the EU ETS.[83]
A Commission official told us that there had been pressure to
both increase the proportion of credits that could be used in
the scheme, [84]
and also pressure from NGOs to ban the use of these credits.[85]
67. The Minister indicated to us that the Government
might be happy for a greater proportion of international credits
to be used than has been proposed by the European Commission.
He argued that it makes little difference where emissions are
reduced and that credits generate useful investment in developing
countries. He would be happy for a significant proportion of Britain's
commitment to be met internationally, although he accepted the
need for 'balance'.
68. We are concerned by this view. As we noted
in our Second Report of Session 2006-07, the Government's 'endorsement
of and reliance on making up shortfalls in
national targets
by buying carbon credits from other countries' is not consistent
with the fact that substantial emissions cuts in developed countries
are required alongside challenging caps on emission growth in
developing countries.[86]
We argued that developed country reliance on overseas credits
could mean that global emissions will not actually be reduced.
We felt also that the Government must face up to the fact that
'ultimately neither the UK, nor any country, nor any industry,
can simply buy its way out of meeting its carbon commitments'.
Further to this, in our Seventh Report of Session 2006-07, we
said that we had concerns about 'the practical feasibility of
relying
on finding significant volumes of surplus carbon
credits to buy from other countries, when all nations will surely
find it very challenging to meet their domestic emissions targets
for 2050 under any post-2012 regime'.[87]
69. We urge caution about the
use of international carbon credits. The argument that a tonne
of carbon reduced abroad is the same as a tonne of carbon reduced
at home is an over-simplification of a complex issue. Permitting
the use of too many international credits will drive down the
cost of carbon, but this will also make renewables and air pollution
targets more expensive to reach and potentially slow down the
long-term shift to a low-carbon economy in the UK.
70. The Minister argued that
the market in flexible mechanisms will help to provide investment
in developing countries. We accept this but we caution that current
flexible mechanisms will only provide a proportion of the funds
required for mitigation and adaptation in developing countries.
The post-2012 negotiations will have to identify additional sources
of money to supply the tens of billions of pounds that will be
required.
71. Nevertheless, we feel that
there is still a role for flexible mechanisms in transferring
funds and technology to developing countries. They will also provide
a 'carrot' to developing countries to play their part in a post-2012
agreement. We agree with the European Commission that the current
level of credits proposed to be permitted in the EU ETS should
not be expanded further under current emission reduction targets.
Only when the EU adopts a target of at least 30% by 2020 could
their use be increased, and only to a level that does not undermine
the carbon price in the EU.
CDM REFORM
72. Benito Müller argued that developing
countries should be rewarded through the CDM for implementing
policies that reduce emissions below business as usual.[88]
Jennifer Morgan agreed with this proposal and said that the CDM
could also be reformed to deliver sectoral emission reductions.[89]
The aim of such reforms would be to encourage wider action in
developing countries through the creation of no-lose mechanisms.
The Government said that it was exploring how the CDM might be
applied to sectors. It pointed out that a potential benefit of
a sectoral CDM approach could be that it reduces the risk that
a project might have gone ahead anyway (in other words, additionality
concerns). It was hopeful that CDM improvements would be possible
in the negotiations.[90]
Eric Bettelheim thought that the safeguards applied to the CDM
process were so stringent that they were preventing business investment.[91]
Benito Müller recognised that business had found it difficult
to get approval for projects, but asserted that the rules were
required to prevent inappropriate projects from receiving credits.
He thought that due to these rules most approved projects were
authentic.[92]
73. We believe that there is
a good case for sectoral and policy-focused CDM. We recommend
that the government explores the desirability and feasibility
of its introduction. The government should also explore whether
CDM project approval rules need to be reformed.
INTERNATIONAL REGULATORY BODY FOR CARBON MARKETS
74. The Market Mechanisms Working Group of the
Global Legislators Organisation for a Balanced Environment (GLOBE)
recommended in February 2008 that a new international independent
regulatory body for carbon markets be established. It said that
this would be required to 'oversee all carbon transactions, develop
clear guidelines for transactions, [and] provide technical advice
to countries that operates under standards associated with commercial
law and operations'.[93]
It indicated that this would be needed to create a stable and
predictable regulatory framework. Eric Bettelheim thought that
the creation of such a body was 'absolutely essential' and that
it was unrealistic to expect the UN to serve as a regulator of
'what is essentially a financial market'.[94]
The Scientific and Business Congress on Protecting the Climate
agreed with the above, and suggested that this body would be needed
to encourage private companies to invest in solutions to climate
change.[95]
75. We recommend that the Government
explores with existing market participants and other interested
parties the creation of a new independent regulatory body to manage
and develop the international carbon market.
Deforestation
76. Emissions from deforestation are immense.
It currently contributes more than 18% of annual man-made greenhouse
gas emissions.[96] Without
prompt action deforestation emissions between 2008 to 2012 will
be more than the total emissions from aviation since its invention
until at least 2025. The Stern Review concluded that 'curbing
deforestation is a highly cost-effective way to reduce emissions;
large-scale international pilot programmes to explore the best
ways to do this could get underway very quickly'.[97]
77. We received written evidence from Sustainable
Forestry Management (SFM), which stressed the critical need to
address emissions from deforestation. SFM argued that flexible
mechanisms have failed to take advantage of the potential for
land use, land use change and forestry (LULUCF) projects in mitigating
climate change. It concluded that this has had a negative impact
on deforestation rates. In particular, SFM argued that the EU
ETS ban on the use of forestry credits, and EU policy on biofuels,
have combined to create market signals that promote deforestation.[98]
It also stressed that limiting the use of LULUCF credits is not
economically sound as it unnecessarily increases the carbon price
in the EU. Eric Bettelheim made the point that mitigation actions
are focusing on technological change rather than taking advantage
of the natural biological mechanism that LULUCF projects represent.[99]
These strong, market-centred, views went further than other witnesses
to this inquiry, who stressed the need to restrict the use of
these credits to prevent carbon prices from being too low.[100]
78. We received conflicting evidence about how
deforestation should be tackled in the negotiations. Proposals
included:
- a fund-based mechanism in which developed countries
pay agreed amounts to developing countries not to deforest land;
- a standalone market-based system rewarding avoided
deforestation; and
- the full integration of LULUCF credits into existing
market mechanisms.
79. Eric Bettelheim called for improved regulation
in the sector and for LULUCF credits to be integrated into existing
carbon markets.[101]
The European Commission rejected this in its recent EU ETS proposals,
arguing that deforestation should be addressed through other instruments.
It suggested that part of the proceeds from auctioning allowances
in the EU ETS could generate additional means to invest in LULUCF
activities both inside and outside the EU.[102]
A number NGOs agreed that LULUCF activities should not be permitted
in the EU ETS because: there is uncertainty about permanence and
additionality; they are simply a cheap way to avoid reducing emissions
from industry; allowing such credits would flood the market with
cheap credits.[103]
There are also questions about the use of such credits in the
absence of appropriate data to make them verifiable. These concerns
led one European Commission official to describe such credits
as being 'sub-prime'.[104]
A recent OECD report appeared to confirm this view, but also indicated
that there might be ways to address forestry credit data and verification
concerns in the future.[105]
80. The Minister told us that if the technical
issues surrounding data, monitoring, sustainability and additionality
can be dealt with, he thought LULUCF projects should be part of
the carbon market.[106]
Allowing their use in the EU ETS would, he believed, destabilise
it at this stage, but he stressed that the Government's policy
is to work towards their eventual inclusion.[107]
Ms Jan Thompson, Head of Negotiations on International Climate
Change at Defra, pointed out that if these credits were permitted
to be used in the EU ETS in future, there would have to be deeper
emission reduction commitments to balance out their relative cheapness.
She also highlighted that the Government has provided funding
for the World Bank's forest carbon partnership facility which
might help to reduce deforestation:
In Bali the UK Government announced a contribution
of £15 million to the [facility] which has a couple of funds
in ita readiness fund which looks at building capacity
in developing countries so that they can measure these emissions
properly and try and address issues of leakage and that sort of
thing; and a carbon fund which looks at testing out incentive
mechanisms and how payments are to be made and whether or not
this comes through carbon markets, through public finance and
to whom those payments would go and so on. Those pilots are getting
underway now through this year and next so we can see where we
get to by the time we are looking to include an international
agreement.[108]
- Deforestation
and land use change will have to be tackled as part of the post-2012
negotiations. It provides an effective natural option for mitigating
greenhouse gas emissions. However we have received conflicting
evidence as to how this could be done without undermining the
EU ETS. We intend to return to this issue at the earliest opportunity.
In the meantime we welcome Government contributions to 'avoided
deforestation' pilot studies. These studies will need to report
as soon as possible to be able to inform the negotiations.
56 Ev 36 Back
57
UN Development Programme, Human Development Report 2007-2008
(New York, 2007), hdr.undp.org/en/ Back
58
ibid Back
59
"Keeping promises to the world's poor", Department
for International Development, 9 October 2007, www.dfid.gov.uk Back
60
Department for International Development, Statistics on international
development 1998/99-2002/03, October 2003 Back
61
"Gleneagles: What really happened at the G8 summit?",
Oxfam, July 2005, www.oxfam.org.uk Back
62
UN Development Programme, Human Development Report 2007-2008
(New York, 2007), hdr.undp.org/en/ Back
63
Ev 10 Back
64
Ev 35 Back
65
UN Development Programme, Human Development Report 2007-2008
(New York, 2007), hdr.undp.org/en/ Back
66
Benito Muller & Cameron Hepburn, "IATAL-An outline proposal
for an International Air Travel Adaptation Levy", Oxford
Institute for Energy Studies, October 2006 Back
67
Q190 Back
68
Q194 [Mr Dodwell] Back
69
Q194 [Mr Dodwell] Back
70
Q96 [Dr Müller] Back
71
Q55 [Mr Hone] Back
72
Q56 Back
73
Q96 [Professor Burke] Back
74
Ev 29 Back
75
Q71 Back
76
Bernice Lee, Antony Froggatt et al, "Changing Climates: Interdependencies
on Energy and Climate Security for China and Europe", Chatham
House, November 2007 Back
77
"China and EU could lead the low-carbon economy", chinadialogue.net,
22 November 2007, www.chinadialogue.net Back
78
"The Mechanisms under the Kyoto Protocol: Emissions Trading,
the Clean Development Mechanism and Joint Implementation",
UNFCCC, May 2008, unfccc.int Back
79
Annex 2 Back
80
Q71 [Dr Müller] Back
81
Annex 2 Back
82
Annex 2 Back
83
Annex 2 Back
84
Annex 2 Back
85
NGOs argue that such credits should only be permitted in the ETS
if the overall emissions reduction target increases to 30% Back
86
Environmental Audit Committee, Second Report of Session 2006-07,
The EU Emissions Trading Scheme: Lessons for the Future,
HC 70 Back
87
Environmental Audit Committee, Seventh Report of Session 2006-07,
Beyond Stern: From the Climate Change Programme Review to the
Draft Climate Change Bill, HC 460 Back
88
Q59 Back
89
Q60 Back
90
Q62 [Ms Thompson] Back
91
Ev 88 Back
92
Ev 51 Back
93
Market Mechanisms Working Group, GLOBE International, Submission
to GLOBE Brasilia G8+5 Legislators Forum, February 2008, p4 Back
94
Q106 Back
95
"Climate Protection Congress calls for a World Carbon Authority
and World Joint Strategy", Tyndall Centre for Climate Change
Research press release, 30 March 2008, www.tyndall.ac.uk Back
96
HM Treasury, Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change,
October 2006, p 537 Back
97
HM Treasury, Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change,
October 2006, p 537 Back
98
Ev 56 Back
99
Q106 Back
100
For example, see Ev 40 Back
101
Ev 60 Back
102
"Questions and Answers on the Commission's proposal to revise
the EU Emissions Trading System", Europa, 23 January
2008, europa.eu Back
103
Ev 40 Back
104
Annex 2 Back
105
Katia Karousakis and Jan Corfee-Morlot, Financing mechanisms
to reduce emissions from deforestation: issues in design and implementation
OECD, December 2007, www.oecd.org Back
106
Q200 Back
107
Q201 Back
108
Q202 [Ms Thompson] Back
|