Select Committee on Environmental Audit Minutes of Evidence


Memorandum submitted by Jennifer L Morgan, E3G

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

  The Bali Roadmap outlines the essential elements that will need to be negotiated within the next two years in order to achieve an ambitious post-2012 agreement. It does not, however, provide sufficient guidance on what warming levels must be avoided, and thus what exact emissions reductions are required to meet such a target. This will be the main core of the negotiations moving forward to be completed by 2009 in Copenhagen. If the goal is to avoid the worst impacts and keep global average temperature below 2 degrees in comparison to pre-industrial levels, the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change finds that global emissions will have to peak and reduce in the next 10 to 15 years along the pathway to reduce global emissions well below half of the levels in 2000 by the middle of the century. In order to keep both these goals in sight, and demonstrate that transitioning to a low carbon economy is possible, developed countries must commit to reduce emissions by 25 to 40% below 1990 by 2020.

  Developed countries will now negotiate their level of effort to reduce emissions both under the Kyoto Protocol, for those ratified Parties, and under the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) where the United States is a Party. This leaves an open space for the next U.S. Administration to engage constructively and hopefully ambitiously in the post-2012 negotiations. It also includes negotiations on mitigation for developing countries to conclude in new and enhanced verifiable, measurable and reportable commitments, very closely linked to the provision of scaled up technology transfer and finance for the transition to a low carbon economy. In addition, the Bali conference made significant progress on putting deforestation and forest degradation on the Bali Action Plan. However, the issue remains a politically highly complex one and many challenges still need to be overcome before any reduce emissions from deforestation and degradation framework can be effectively implemented. Finally, adaptation provisions took a small step forward in Bali, but much more is needed.

  In order to ensure that the principle of common but differentiated responsibilities is fulfilled, any meaningful post-2012 international climate regime will have to ensure that different national conditions are reflected in a country's CO2 reduction commitments. As agreed under the UNFCCC framework, developed countries will have to take the lead by continuing with absolute mandatory caps on emissions. Based on a country's historical responsibility, capability and potential to mitigate, developing countries should take on different kinds of commitments reflecting their differentiated commitments (eg sectoral commitments, policies and measures etc). Developed countries must lead the process to a global low-carbon future by providing clear leadership and allowing the low-carbon technology development and deployment processes to become more ambitious in developing countries. Here the EU should pursue these objectives on both a bi-lateral and a multilateral level, bringing new innovative financing ideas to the table internationally and testing them in a bi-lateral framework, for example by working with China on low-carbon economic zones.

  The current revenue streams for financing adaptation and technology transfer to developing countries are neither of a sufficient scale, nor of an adequate form to meet the growing challenge of tackling climate change. While a range of estimates exist on the costs of adaptation and mitigation, it is essential to ensure that international resources are additional to currently committed ODA and that private sector finance is leveraged. A carbon price alone will not ensure that innovation in every sector occurs. Different technologies are at different stages on the innovation chain and their R&D, deployment and diffusion needs will therefore also vary. Only a balanced combination of market push and market pull incentives for low-carbon trade and investments can play a significant role in creating win-win options for achieving mitigation targets and economic gains across the globe.

  As such, a range of funding options exist which could include auctioning revenue from the carbon market such as is proposed by the European Commission in its updated Emissions Trading System. The financing of mitigation and adaptation technologies in developing countries must be in line with national sustainable development goals of that particular country. Purely donor driven approaches will not build confidence nor will they provide the incentives needed to interest developing countries in agreeing to a new commitment in an international treaty.

1.  Question 1: Is the Kyoto Protocol still a relevant and effective mechanism? How successful was the Bali conference? Does the roadmap contain all that is needed to lead to a post-Kyoto agreement that adequately addresses the climate change challenge? Will the roadmap focus on implementation issues or will it come to an agreement on a stabilisation level? How do we ensure that no key parties are left out of the process?

  1.1  The Bali outcome is step in the right direction. Due to the very strong opposition by the Bush Administration on a range of crucial issues, it was the most that could have been achieved at Bali. The Bali Roadmap outlines the essential elements that will have to be negotiated within the next two years in order to achieve an ambitious post-2012 agreement. It does not, however, provide sufficient guidance on what warming levels must be avoided, and thus what exact emissions reductions are required to meet such a target. These issues will lie at the heart of the negotiation process leading up to Copenhagen in 2009.

  1.2  The Kyoto Protocol is still very relevant in this roadmap and effective on a series of levels. The core of the Kyoto Protocol is its cap and trade approach, requiring binding absolute caps on industrialized country emissions from the period 2008 to 2012. Emissions trading and the other "flexibility mechanisms" such as the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) were first initiated by Kyoto and now serve as the basis for the carbon market. Secondly, negotiations have been underway since late 2005 on the second commitment period of the Kyoto Protocol. This was strengthened in Bali. The Bali decisions set a deadline of 2009 to complete the negotiations and offered some guidance on the level of effort for the next set of targets for Kyoto industrialized countries. This includes the need to peak and reduce global emissions in 10 to 15 years; the need to reduce global emissions well below half of levels in 2000 by the middle of the century; and the recognition that the lowest IPCC scenario would require Annex I Parties as a group to reduce emissions in a range of 25 to 40% below 1990 by 2020. The noting of this single scenario should provide guidance for the second commitment period targets for Kyoto Parties.

  1.3  The process to agree targets for each industrialized Kyoto country for the Protocol's second commitment period is also now very clear, set out by the work plan of the AWG in great detail. Through a series of submissions, workshops, inputs from external experts, roundtables and extra negotiating sessions, countries will negotiate a new set of targets for the second commitment period to be delivered for adoption to the Copenhagen COP in 2009.

  1.4  As the United States is not a Party to the Kyoto Protocol and therefore is not included in the Kyoto target negotiations, a different space had to be found to negotiate U.S. mitigation in the future. Indeed, a major challenge in Bali arose when it became time to discuss what the non-Kyoto industrialized countries would be negotiating for their mitigation for the next two years. While that group includes Kazakhstan, Belarus and Lichtenstein, the main interest is to ensure that the United States is negotiating mitigation of its emissions. Countries were not prepared to launch a new round of negotiations in Bali without a clear and ambitious negotiating process for the USA itself.

  1.5  The Bali Action Plan includes negotiations on mitigation commitments for industrialized countries that are measurable, reportable and verifiable and should be comparable with other developed country negotiations, providing the link to the Kyoto Protocol track of negotiations. The text also specifically notes quantified emission limitation and reduction objectives, the same type of commitments that the AWG is negotiating for other developed countries.

  1.5.1  The Bali Action Plan also includes a negotiation over mitigation for developing countries. Developing countries, along with the United States had been part of the Dialogue on Long-term Cooperative Action on Climate Change under the UNFCCC, but as this Dialogue comes to an end, and in light of growing CO2 emissions from developing countries, it is clear that these negotiations must be more serious and ambitious than before. At Bali countries agreed to negotiate enhanced national mitigation actions that are "measurable, reportable and verifiable." The next two years will focus on negotiating new actions and approaches for developing countries to curb their emissions, linked with support in the fields of technology, financing and capacity building. While formal conditionality is not the case, it is very clear that the level of ambition of developing country mitigation will go hand-in-hand with the level of support from industrialised countries.

  1.5.2  The Bali Action plan also includes a separate, but linked, negotiation framework on deforestation and forest degradation measures in developing countries. For the first time, deforestation will get the attention it requires. A separate subsidiary body decision outlines much of the work plan on this issue, with a programme of work on methodological issues that should identify the range of policy approaches and positive incentives. There is also room for demonstration activities and a focus on increasing resources. In fact, Norway made a major announcement in Bali, committing $500 million/year over the next five years to fund deforestation reduction efforts, independent of any reduction commitments by North or South or any link to the carbon market.

  1.5.3  Technology development and transfer will also play a large part in the negotiation process setting standards on transferring the technologies that are needed for both the mitigation and adaptation of climate change. The increased realization of the need for a functioning set of measures to facilitate technology transfer from developed to developing countries will play a vital role in these negotiations. A much more robust set of commitments and actions around technology transfer and assisting developing countries to create favourable national conditions must be put in place if global emissions are to peak and decline in the next 10 to 15 years. Here the Experts Group on Technology Transfer (EGTT) has a very comprehensive work programme including assessing the gaps and barriers to technology transfer, developing a set of performance indicators to monitor and evaluate the effectiveness of the technology transfer framework and bringing forth a strategy paper on how to move forward.

  1.5.4  In the area of adaptation, the Kyoto Protocol's Adaptation Fund was finally made operational so that it can begin to distribute funds generated from the level on the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM). Under the UNFCCC, the Bali Action Plan decided that there should be enhanced action in the areas of risk management and risk sharing, disaster reduction strategies, and international cooperation to support the urgent implementation of adaptation actions.

  1.5.5  The final element of negotiation of the Bali Action Plan is that of finance, "enhanced action on provision of financial resources and investment to support mitigation and adaptation actions". Tied closely with the three other elements, the negotiation will focus on creating innovative means of funding adaptation, positive incentives for action, provision of new and additional resources and mobilization of public and private sector funding. Investment and finance will require inputs from a range of new actors to the UNFCCC process.

  1.6  The negotiation process will be organized in two different ad hoc working groups. The existing Ad Hoc Working Group of Article 3.9 of the Kyoto Protocol will continue and conclude its work in 2009. A second group, the Ad Hoc Group on Long-term Cooperative Action under the UN Convention, will also conclude its work in 2009. It shall meet as often as necessary, initially four meetings in 2008 with its first meeting taking place in March/April 2008. Chairs for the two years have already been identified and confirmed.

2.  Question 2: What needs to be done between now and Poznan? Emissions from international aviation and shipping were not included in the Bali roadmap. Why did this happen and what can be done to address these emissions?

  2.1  Poznan serves as a verification point between Bali and Copenhagen in December 2009. It will evaluate the international progress made since Bali and outline those measures still necessary to achieve a successful post-2012 agreement. It will be an important conference, although it will serve more as evaluation rather than one which sets out its own agenda. In particular, Poznan will "take stock" to assess whether there are enough meetings scheduled, what progress has been made and optimally to engage a representative of the new US Administration on how it will participate in the negotiations.

  2.2  Aviation needs to be included in any post-2012 climate deal. Although it is not specifically mentioned in the Bali Action Plan, its inclusion will be part of the negotiations due to both a review of the Kyoto Protocol and the inclusion of internationally competitive sectors in the negotiations. Although it is still very disputed on how this will be done, the European Commission, for example, adopted a proposal for legislation to include aviation in the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS) in December 2006. The proposal provides for aviation to be brought into the EU ETS in two steps. From the start of 2011, emissions from all domestic and international flights between EU airports will be covered. In January 2012, the scope will be expanded to cover emissions from all international flights—from or to anywhere in the world—that arrive at or depart from any EU airport. The intention is for the EU ETS to serve as a model for other countries considering similar national or regional schemes, and to link these to the EU scheme over time. The EU ETS could thus form the basis for wider international action to include CO2 reducing measures on aviation.

EMISSION REDUCTION FRAMEWORKS

3.  Question 3: How can "common but differentiated responsibilities" be decided in such a way that ensures the engagement of all parties? How can equity concerns regarding the allocation of mitigation targets and historical responsibility for climate change emissions be reconciled?

  3.1  The principle of "common but differentiated responsibilities" is the core underlying principle to the UNFCCC, particularly for developing countries. How do we forge a common response to the threat of climate change that respects the different starting points of varying countries? The current framework includes only two annexes—one for developed countries and one for developing with no long-term perspective of what the overarching goal of the climate regime shall be. The post-2012 negotiations will rotate around these issues and should be based upon the latest scientific data.

  Any meaningful post-2012 international climate regime will have to include countries at very different economic stages. It is therefore vital to the success of any post-2012 agreement that these different conditions are reflected in their national CO2 reduction commitments.

  3.2  As agreed in the UNFCCC, developed countries will have to take the lead by continuing with absolute mandatory caps on emissions. In order to demonstrate leadership and have a higher probability of staying below 2 degrees C, the level of ambition for developed countries should match the IPCC's lowest scenario equally to 25 to 40% emissions reductions below 1990 by 2020. It is clear, however, that some developing countries must also take on ambitious, specific mitigation commitments. CO2 emissions from fuel combustion in non-Annex I countries have increased by 38.9% over the 1990-2000 period, resulting in a 40% of annual global emissions in 2000 according to the World Resources Institute. Some non-Annex I countries have seen a rapid economic development in recent years.

  3.3  While it is important for non-Annex I countries to take on CO2 limitation and/or reduction commitments it is also vital to the political success of any such agreement that there is clear differentiation amongst non-Annex I countries as their responsibility, capacity and potential to mitigate vary greatly. The current grouping of developing countries does not reflect the different national circumstances of that block (eg from Saudi Arabia to Togo). The post-2012 regime should base the level of effort for commitments on a set of core principles that can be quantified so as to ensure a transparent process in setting commitments. Three criteria are particularly mentioned in the literature on this subject and include:

    —  Historical Responsibility which can be analysed in various ways but the most cities approach is to assess the cumulative per capita emissions of fossil CO2 in the period 1990-2000 ("Brazilian proposal"). Other approaches focus on longer time periods.

    —  Capability of a country to reduce emissions. This might be quite different to its historical responsibility. Here two criteria need to be taken into consideration: the Human Development Index (HDI) and the GDP on the basis of purchasing power parity. This would result in countries with higher levels of national income and higher HDI ranking having to carry a higher burden of mitigation.

    —  Potential which can be derived by a country's emissions intensity and its emissions per capita. Thus a high value for a country's CO2/GDP ratio would imply a high potential to mitigate emissions. The more efficient an economy already the less efficiency potential exists to mitigate further. High per capita emissions, on the other hand, could be altered by changes in lifestyles.

  These criteria can then guide negotiations both on the type and level of ambition of the commitments and the level of financing a country will require to meet those commitments. This mixture is highlighted below.

    Potential to mitigate[1]
High potential Reductions of domestic emissions
Medium potentialLimitation of domestic emissions
Low potential commitmentsNo quantitative but qualitative mitigation


    Capability to mitigate
High capability Financial transfers for mitigation activities to "low/medium capability" countries
Medium capabilityCo-sharing: mitigation partly funded by "high capability" countries
Low capabilityAll mitigation activities funded by "high capability" countries


    Responsibility to mitigate
High responsibility Binding absolute reduction target
Medium responsibilityQuantitative commitments only binding if all "high responsibility" countries take on commitments and conditional on transfer of adequate financial and technological resources
Low responsibilityOptional/voluntary mitigation commitments


  After evaluating the above criteria one arrives at a set of country groups similar to the following:

    —  Poorest countries, including a large part of African LDCs, will initially be excluded from any new commitments until they have reached a certain level of economic and institutional development in order for national CO2 emission reductions to make economic sense.

    —  Advanced developing countries, for example large parts of northern Africa, will begin to reduce their CO2 emissions by measures of sustainable development.

    —  Newly industrialising countries, such as China, South Korea, Mexico, Brazil and most OPEC states, will set no-lose targets to limit their carbon emissions.

    —  Developed industrialised countries will take on commitments of absolute emissions reducing measures according to the Kyoto Protocol model. Here those countries with higher CO2 emissions per capita will have to reduce more than others.

Table 1

COMMITMENTS ACCORDING TO COUNTRIES' PARTICIPATION FOR A 450 PPMV STABILISATION GOAL[2]


  A re-evaluation of the groups must take place every 5-10 years so as to remain effective and take account of the progress made by individual countries. Step by step this will allow for a greater number of countries to actively contribute to avoiding dangerous climate change by taking on more ambitious CO2 emissions reducing targets over time.

  The final agreement may look slightly different than that above. There may, for example, only be two or three groupings within the developing country block. The point is to ensure that there is an equitable process to determine the level of effort and type of commitment developing countries must take.

4.  Question 4: How might an agreement be reached with emerging economies to ensure that their emissions trajectories move into line with the need to reduce global emissions? How might developing countries' need to expand their economies be reconciled with controls on emissions?

  4.1  The developed world holds great responsibility in leading the way to a low-carbon future. Only if their economies show clear and determined signs towards a low carbon economy can developing countries be assured that their emerging economies will not lose out by taking on ambitious actions or commitments to curb their emissions. The Western economies of Europe, the United States and Japan must therefore set clear emissions reduction targets if emerging economies are to follow suit. There are different ways to shift together to ensure a lower emissions trajectory:

  4.1.1  Provide leadership: Ensure that Europe meets its 30% energy reduction target agreed by the Council in March 2007. Not only will this serve as a process by which to show emerging economies that industrialised countries are serious about climate change, but it will also present less advanced economies with the political know-how of how low-carbon economies can be achieved. Germany, which sees itself as a frontrunner in setting ambitious national CO2 reducing targets, is seeing clear signs that its economic growth may be decoupling from its total greenhouse gas emissions. As such, not only can Europe be a leader on showing the rest of the world how to put adequate regulatory measures into place and make them work, but its companies will also have clear competitive advantage in developing low-carbon technologies.

  4.1.2  Low-carbon technology deployment needs to become more ambitious in developing countries. Strengthened intellectual property protection is a necessary but insufficient condition for speeding up technology development in developing countries. Here it is vital to give every country a stake in the necessary transition, especially large emerging economies like China and India. There is a clear need for a pragmatic approach in addressing intellectual property rights (IPR) issues. Here the rights governing the technology itself are often less important, rather it is vital that the receiving country has the absorptive capacity to use them, to enable their widespread diffusion and to innovate independently on the basis of the new knowledge. Negotiations in multilateral institutions between host countries and rich investing countries should include the issue of diffusion, and address the fact that genuine transfer of technology involves providing the host country with the capacity to develop and produce technology of its own, rather than merely selling a piece of equipment or blueprint. Despite risk of retaliation by trading partners, compulsory licensing can be a useful tool when environmental protection or public health is at stake. Governments can play a key role in stimulating the innovation and diffusion of climate technologies. Strategies including public provision of adequate infrastructure, subsidised research and priority public procurement are major tools to encourage such low-carbon technologies. A mix of push and pull mechanisms must be used to facilitate the transition to a low-carbon future.

  Europe should be pursuing these objectives on both a bi-lateral and a multi-lateral level, bringing new and innovative financing ideas to the table internationally and testing them out in bi-lateral relations.

  4.1.3  Establishing "Low-Carbon Economic Zones" (LCEZs) between China and the EU could be a bold initiative for European and Chinese policy-makers to consider. These LCEZs could be the testing grounds for policies promoting the economic transformation necessary for a low-carbon future. Their focus on attracting investment in research and high-end manufacturing would be consistent with the Chinese leadership's desire to shift away from simple processing and assembly. The EU could focus its energy and climate cooperation with China around these zones to demonstrate the real possibility of large-scale transformations to other regions and countries, from which the EU would greatly benefit. Such LCEZs could also pioneer sectoral approaches to climate change since competitiveness concerns about climate change policies have generated significant interests in global sectoral standards agreements for energy intensive sectors.

  The creation of such LCEZs could also allow the EU and China to set world-class standards for energy-efficient goods and services as well as making coal more sustainable, through CCS financing mechanisms for example. The coal issue is central to both regions as future dependence on coal is expected to increase significantly in China and the EU. Both could enhance existing cooperation to deliver an agreed set of benchmarks and practices for improving efficiency and reducing the sustainability impacts across the coal fuel chain; including enhancing cooperation on development of carbon capture and storage as a potential future energy option.

  4.2  In short, there needs to be a clear move from a competition to a cooperative framework if developing countries are to ensure that their emissions trajectories move into line with the need to reduce global emissions. With climate change posing new security threats to all countries, finding technological solutions is a shared dilemma and must be met by strengthened cooperation between national governments and corporations.

ADAPTATION AND TECHNOLOGY

5.  Question 5:   Is there adequate support for developing countries to adapt to climate change? How will funding for climate change mitigation or adaptation interact with existing aid budgets? Will such funding contribute to wider sustainable development goals?

  5.1  Increased adaptation financing in developing countries is needed in part to respond the incremental risks climate change pose to the achievement of the Millenium Development Goals (MDGs). The 2006 UK DfID White Paper recognised that climate change poses the most serious long-term threat to development and the achievement of the MDGs. Climate change is driving near term increases in climate variability and extremes. This will increase humanitarian costs from drought, floods and extreme storms. UN Security Council debate on climate change in April 2007 showed strong developing country views that climate impacts were increasing risks of crisis and conflict. Ministry of Defense and Foreign Commonwealth Office analysis supports this view.[3]

  5.1.1  Climate change will impact the poorest people in the poorest countries first; all poverty reduction efforts will be affected. OECD (2005)[4] estimates 15-60% of aid spending is vulnerable to climate change. 350 million people could be displaced by climate change by 2050. By 2015, the share of DFID's budget devoted to humanitarian costs could almost double, from 12% to 23%. Increased risks of instability and conflict driven by climate change will add additional costs.

  5.1.2  Financial costs to industrialized country governments to "climate proof" current investments in both middle and low income countries, assuming private sector leveraging occurs, would be $1.3 to $7.7 billion per annum (Table 2). The World Bank estimates costs of adaptation as 5-20% of development investment sensitive to climate. For 2005 ODA, this amounts to US$4.5 billion as the midrange value.

Table 2

COST OF CLIMATE PROOFING IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES
Cost Scenario $ billion per year) Total Developing Country CostTotal LICs Share Total MICs Share
Low estimate1.30.2 1.1
Middle estimate4.51.1 3.5
High estimate7.71.9 5.8
Adapted from WorldBank, 2006[5]


  5.1.3  If one wishes to estimate the total costs, including Foreign Direct Investment and Gross Domestic Investment then the total numbers are much higher eg in the range of $4 to $37 billion per year for developing country "climate proofing". Cost estimates for OECD countries, according to Stern are in the range of $15-150bn cost per year for adaptation in OECD countries. This brings the total range to $19 to $187 billion per year for the globe.

  5.1.4  This, however, does not include the costs related to disaster relief; climate-proofing people has been neglected at the expense of climate-proofing investment. If climate change is left unchecked, global humanitarian costs would skyrocket.

  5.1.5  In addition to finding more innovative and additional ways of financing adaptation as well as mitigation, adaptation should also take complementary actions by:

    —  Building adaptive capacity by investing in basic human development eg the MDGs.

    —  Capacity building—eg projecting impacts, planning etc.

    —  Institutional strengthening to plan and manage impacts.

    —  Technology transfer—eg building standards, drought-resilient seeds, dyke building, early warning systems.

  5.1.6  The current revenue streams for financing adaptation are neither of a sufficient scale, nor of an adequate form to meet the growing challenge of tackling climate change. The scaling-up of existing mechanisms alone would not be sufficient to cover for climate adaptation. Existing instruments include two UNFCCC funds (ie Least Developed Countries Fund, LDCF and Special Climate Change Fund, SCCF), which were set up under the auspices of GEF (Global Environment Facility) to finance adaptation efforts in developing countries. Another fund, Strategic Priority on Adaptation (SAP), is financed separately by GEF's own resources. The delivery of these funds has been very limited (Table 3). Total committed finance for adaptation through multilateral funds was US $279 million. By mid-2007, actual multilateral financing delivered under the broad umbrella of initiatives set up under the UNFCCC had reached a total of US$26 million. This is equivalent to one week's worth of spending on flood defence in the United Kingdom (HDR, 2007).

Table 3
Adaptation FundsOperational since Total Pledged (US $ million)Total received (US $ million) by 2007 Total disbursed (US $ million) by 2007
LDCF2001156.7 52.19.8
SCCF200567.3 (56.7[6]) 53.31.4
Adaptation200X5 5
FundBy 2012[7] 160-950
Sub-total229 110.411.2
SPA200450 5014.8
Total279 160.426
Source: Adapted from HDR 2007


  In Bali, there was agreement regarding the governance of the Adaptation Fund of UNFCCC. It will receive a constant flux of revenues by a 2% levy on credits generated through CDM projects. If implemented, it is estimated that the levy could generate a total income in the range of US$160-950 million by 2012.

  5.1.7  HDR Report 2007-08 drawing from various methodologies, sets out its rough "lower bound ballpark" estimate of overall additional adaptation investment required as US $86 billion per year by 2015. Table 4 outlines different components of this additional funding. Updating WorldBank's figures for 2005, their cost estimate for climate proofing development investments and infrastructure is suggested to be at least US$44 billion annually by 2015 (This figure is based on the assumption that adaptation financing requirements in developing countries will represent around 0.1% of developed country GDP). Since most adaptation cost estimates are solely focusing on the cost of climate-proofing, they include other types of costs adaptation will entail. Adapting poverty reduction programmes is suggested to require a commitment of at least US$40 billion per year (This figure represents around 0.5% of GDP for low income and lower-middle income countries). Finally, increase in climate-related disaster response of US$2 billion a year in bilateral and multilateral assistance by 2015 is estimated to prevent the diversion of development aid. The existence of different estimates shows the wide range of methodologies, which themselves reflect various uncertainties over calculating the exact cost of climate risks.

Table 4
Estimated Cost
Estimated donor country cost% of OECD GDP by 2015 US $ billion by 2015
Climate-proofing development investment 0.144
Adapting poverty reduction to climate change 0.140
Strengthening disaster response(.) 2
Total0.2 86

Source: Estimates based on GDP projections from World Bank 2007d quoted in HDR 2007


  5.1.8  Institutional aspects of funding adaptation mechanisms could include:[8]

    —  expanding ODA infrastructure to accommodate the required adaptation—internalize adaptation in the existing bilateral and multilateral ODA infrastructure;

    —  creating or extending a globally centralized fund—extend the Protocol's Adaptation Fund;

    —  creating locally-focused funds such as Autonomous Adaptation Funds—establish funds at national/sub-national levels to respond to local adaptation needs; and

    —  an insurance mechanism for adaptation—range of ideas here from compensation for the suffering from impacts to innovative market-based insurance instruments.

  5.2  It is important to ensure in the medium term that international resources for climate change mitigation and adaptation are additional to currently committed ODA. Financing adaptation by multilateral development assistance has been so far characterised by underfinancing, fragmentation and weak leadership as also shown above (HDR, 2007). HDR (2007) also notes that in addition to this, "international cooperation on adaptation has not been developed as part of the wider international aid partnership on poverty reduction. The end result is that multilateral financing mechanisms are delivering small flows of finance with high transaction costs, yielding very limited results".

  5.2.1  In the area of mitigation, it is very clear that existing ODA will not be enough to address the huge challenge climate change will impose. The role of the carbon market, additional ODA funding and other possible means and sources need to be further explored.

  The underlying documents to Stern try to calculate the scale of additional costs that will need to be made in developing countries by 2015 in order to stabilize concentrations (Table 5).

Table 5[9]
Costs in non OECD
countries, per year in 2015
Costs in non OECD countries,
per year in 2025
Mitigation$69 billion $294 billion


  In order to cover these additional costs, a range of approaches exist starting with:

    —  Developing countries themselves fund part of the additional investment costs. How much will depend on the level of development of each country and their technology needs. See case studies below.

    —  Deeper cuts in developed countries and a transformed CDM to sectoral and policy approaches in developing countries thus allowing more carbon finance to flow south. The rapid development of an international carbon price, in particular, would mean that much of this investment could be made "off-balance sheet" from the point of view of the public sector.

  5.2.2  Financing options can include expanding the carbon market by deeper industrialized country targets, and transformed CDM. Stern documents include the following calculations in regard to the potential role of the carbon market in assisting in closing the gap of additional cost (Table 6):

Table 6[10]
Costs in non OECD countries, per year in 2015 Costs in non OECD countries, per year in 2025
Funding through carbon market$24 billion (of the $69 billion total) $173 billion (of the $294 billion total)


  These results are generally consistent with those done by Baker & Mackenzie for Vattenfall (2007), which find that there are a range of mitigation options for a marginal abatement cost of 40 euros/ton in 2030, again consistent with the overall Stern economic estimates. The striking thing to note is that Stern focused on 550ppmve and Vattenfall on 450ppmve, thus showing the large ranges in the estimates.

  5.2.3  It is therefore clear that a carbon price alone will not ensure that innovation in every sector occurs, or that the essential research and development occurs. Indeed, there is additional financing needed for emerging technologies along the following lines:

Table 7[11]
Costs in non OECD countries, per year in 2015 Costs in non OECD countries, per year in 2025
Emerging technologies where further funding needed $45 billion (of the $69 billion total) $121 billion (of the $294 billion total)


  Financing needs to be tailored according to the country and its specific needs. As far as where the funding is most needed, there are a range of graphs which show the different costs for the different technologies in various years. Financing mechanisms must be tailored to recipient developing countries, since they vary widely. For example, in Middle Income Countries (MIC), there should be clear funding for the transition to a low-carbon economy, while in Least Income Countries (LIC) the focus should be on adaptation and access to climate change proofed energy.

  5.2.4  Additional finance can be generated through a mixture of regulatory and market mechanisms:

    —  Auctioning of permits:

    —  on the international level, part of the national level commitments, the so-called assigned amount, would not be allocated for free to countries but rather taken out and put in a separate global fund to be monetized and allocated to technology development (and adaptation); or

    —  on the national level, permits would be auctioned and part of that revenue would be placed in a national fund coordinated with other national funds or an international fund for technology development and adaptation.

    This could be a significant funding source. For example, 150 $bn/year could be generated if 40% of the emissions permits from developed countries were auctioned at a price of 30 to 40$/ton. From 2012-20 auctioning developed country carbon permits could provide sufficient funds to deliver adaptation and MIC mitigation.

    —  Placing a levy on the other financial mechanisms of the Kyoto Protocol; currently there is a 2% levy on the CDM revenues to finance Adaptation Fund. This could be spread to emissions trading and joint implementation in the future. The total amount available depends on the size of the market.

    —  Carbon tax.

    —  Taxing air travel.

    —  Doubling public support for RD&D to around $50bn/yr to reduce costs and accelerate deployment in both developed and developing countries.

    —  World Bank and Regional Development Banks' efforts to create a global Investment Framework for scaling up public and private investment:

    —  potential to overcome obstacles to investment in developing countries; and

    —  facilitate the transfer of finance and technology; and allow financing for different sources to be combined effectively, to catalyse the private sector investment needed to fund low carbon technology, including energy efficiency. Policy mechanisms that can assist in driving down costs and driving private sector investment to stimulate technology development and diffusion will be detailed further in Section 6.

  5.3  The approaches taken in financing mitigation and adaptation in developing countries must be in line with national sustainable development goals of that country. Purely donor driven approaches will not build confidence nor will it provide the incentives needed to interest developing countries in agreeing to a new commitment in an international treaty.

  5.3.1  Avoided climate change is a global public good that has strong poverty reduction benefits in developing countries. As mentioned earlier, lack of adaptation will undermine all development efforts, particularly in climate sensitive sectors (ie agriculture, forestry) which the poorest in the developing countries are most dependent on for their livelihoods, while lack of mitigation efforts would lock advanced developing countries in carbon intensive economies.

  5.3.2  Adaptation and mitigation needs and opportunities differ according to the country. In MICs, adaptation funding would support the transition to a low-carbon economy while achieving MDGs. On the other hand, in LICs, reducing the vulnerability of the agriculture to climatic extremes would support food security of the poor. In addition to that, it would enable them to access energy through climate change ready energy structure.

  5.3.3  A comprehensive approach to climate change adaptation (including enhanced humanitarian and disaster relief), including additional investment and improved governance/conflict prevention needs to be developed. Adaptation discussions have mainly focused on technical and investment measures, linked to international funds. This assumes governments will act to reduce climate impacts on their citizens. But in states with low governance records, climate change will magnify social stresses increasing the risk of conflict and instability. In many areas in Africa and Asia the only form of adaptation will be migration, with 200-400 million people at risk by 2050. Managing the stresses of migration between and within states will require strengthened humanitarian and political action.

6.  Question 6:   Is there effective international coordination on technology R&D? How might technology transfer to developed countries be improved? How does technology transfer interact with international trade rules? How effectively do Government technology programmes, such as the Energy Technologies Institute, lead to technology development and transfer to developing countries? How effective are UK Government measures to assist developing countries to reduce emissions?

  6.1  There has been only slow progress on developing the practical and effective innovation incentives needed to drive a global transition to low-carbon economy. There are considerable economic, political, regulatory barriers to overcome.

  6.2  As noted above in question 5, large ranges of marginal abatement cost estimates, suggest that a carbon price alone will not ensure that innovation in every sector occurs, nor that the essential research and development occurs.

  6.2.1  Different technologies sit at different stages on the innovation chain; therefore their R&D, deployment and diffusion needs will also vary. For example, one can see below that perhaps onshore wind could be funded through carbon market expansion but solar thermal would need additional funding. This will vary, however, from country to country.

Figure 1

INCREMENTAL CoSTS OF LOW CARBON OPTIONS AS % COSTS OF FOSSIL FUELS


  6.3  In addition to technology push through increased resources for R&D, "market pull" with regulatory reforms is equally important for low-carbon technology deployment and diffusion. Policy mechanisms that can assist in driving down costs and driving private sector investment include:

    —  A Multi-lateral Technology Acquisition Fund to buy-out intellectual property rights with public funds and distribute them to developing countries.

    —  Energy Efficiency or Carbon Intensity Related Technology Agreements.

    —  Benchmarking/standard setting for technologies to drive private sector investment in more efficient and/or lower carbon intensive products such as vehicles, household appliances etc. so leading to phasing out of most carbon intensive products.

    —  Sectoral agreements where sectors agree to certain carbon-intensity technology standards—could be a G8+5/G20 agreement on key sectors.

    —  Technology Related Targets—Specific targets whether national, regional or global for key low carbon technologies, such as renewable energy; number of fossil fuel plants fitted with carbon capture and storage; percentage of biofuels within the transportation sector etc would be combined with Technology Cooperation Agreements with developing countries and financing for incremental costs provided.

    —  Removing trade and investment barriers to climate change technology transfer, eg common market in low carbon technologies between the EU and China.

    —  Setting technology standards: Innovation and diffusion in buildings and transport will be driven by technical standards not price. Trade and investment driven deals with dynamic developing countries can lower costs and drive diffusion. Therefore, there is a need to link tariff barrier reduction, investment policy, mutual standards recognition and joint efficiency standard policies.

  6.4  The financial resources generated for technology innovation and diffusion could be used to set up a common pool of IPRs (depending on the technology). But most importantly they should encourage and make substantial steps in making the underlying knowledge available through joint R&D and demonstration collaborations. The leading companies in global power plant industry have provided licenses to developing country firms for the manufacture of equipment such as gas turbines. However, these licenses exclude the manufacture of the most "high tech" components such as the first row of turbine blades which incorporate advanced materials, cooling technologies and manufacturing techniques.[12] Although having patents to manufacture high tech is building up the capacity and skills-base, access to the underlying knowledge is a key component for innovation in those countries through knowledge transfer. Capacity building is also another important component of technology transfer.

  6.5  Win-win options of achieving mitigation targets and economic gains are possible through creating new market incentives for low-carbon trade and investment. In the case of EU and China, a recent Chatham House and E3G study[13] suggests that "the sheer size of the two markets means that an EU-China trade agenda will influence the global marketplace and further stimulate trading opportunities, both with each other and elsewhere. This could also help offset competitiveness concerns of EU and Chinese entrepreneurs about moving quickly towards low-carbon alternatives". To achieve this, barriers to trade and investment in low-carbon trade in goods and services would need to be removed.

  6.6  The newly established Energy Technologies Institute (ETI) (operational from 2008),outlines its objectives as follows:

    —  increasing the level of funding devoted to R&D to meet the UK's energy policy goals;

    —  delivering R&D that facilitates the rapid commercial deployment of cost effective, low carbon energy technologies;

    —  providing better strategic focus for commercially applicable energy related R&D projects;

    —  connecting and managing networks of the best scientists and engineers to deliver focused energy R&D projects to accelerated eventual deployment; and

    —  building R&D capacity in the UK in the relevant technical disciplines to deliver the UK's energy policy goals.

  None of its objectives specifically address technology transfer from the UK to developing countries. On the other hand, it does not have a UK remit, ie investments do not have to be made in the UK or into UK companies.

  Given ETI's early development stage it is difficult to argue whether it can play a significant role in technology development and transfer. We believe technology transfer to developing countries has a significant role to play in mitigation and adaptation; therefore needs to be a part of the UK government technology programme.

7.  Question 8:   How might mechanisms to tackle emissions from deforestation be developed? How can we ensure that such mechanisms contribute to wider sustainable development aims? Will such mechanisms deal with the need to ensure the protection of indigenous people, land use rights and governance? How might forest degradation be dealt with? Are additional mechanisms required to enable the creation of carbon sinks?

  7.1  Deforestation emissions are estimated to contribute 20% of all anthropogenic CO2 emissions.[14] This makes deforestation the second largest cause of greenhouse gas emissions after fossil fuel burning. Therefore, we think the suggested Reduced Emissions from Deforestation and Degradation (REDD) mechanism can play an important role in addressing GHG mitigation.

  7.2  At the last COP meeting in Bali, significant progress was made by putting deforestation and forest degradation on the Bali Action Plan, and a work programme for further methodological work was adopted. The so-called Bali Roadmap also included possible financial support to tackle deforestation and forest degradation, which contributed to climate change. However, given the complexity of forest governance issues and, the uncertainties about the post-2012 market and political architecture, there are considerable challenges in the design and implementation of any REDD framework.

  7.3  The basic principle of a REDD mechanism is that following a baseline for emissions from deforestation and degradation for a country is agreed the emissions reductions below the agreed baseline will be rewarded ex-post. Options of financing this by a dedicated fund or by selling emission reduction in the carbon market, or some combination of the two are still being discussed.

  7.4  Including credits accrued from REDD in the international trading system on a fully fungible basis has large risks. It has the potential of flooding the global carbon market with cheap compliance credits. This would have serious negative implications on the price of carbon, and in turn would undermine urgent need for transition to a low-carbon economy. A potential solution can be setting up a hybrid market-linked fund proposed by Greenpeace International. This so-called "Tropical Deforestation Emission Reduction Mechanism (TDERM)" could provide funding for forest protection that is driven by a mandatory minimum contribution from Annex I Parties to meet a certain percentage of their emission reduction targets. Compliance with national emissions reducing targets could be secured by a "Tropical Deforestation Emissions Reduction Unit", and its price could be determined by auctioning. These proceeds would go into the TDERM to fund and reward reductions of emissions. In addition to a mandatory minimum contribution, the supply of these credit units would also be limited to an agreed level, while it would be necessary to ensure sufficient funds.

  7.5  It is not yet clear whether REDD will have any obligations towards any development outcomes to be met, and how these will be integrated into a REDD design. Experience from community forestry projects emphasised the importance to make explicit any development objectives in the design phase, if any development outcomes will be achieved.[15] We agree that "REDD activities should be coupled with long-term development co-benefits to ensure permanence of avoided emissions".[16]

  7.6  There are significant governance issues which will need to be addressed if emission reductions from deforestation and forest degradation will be achieved and be permanent. Tackling these will require clarity over ownership/tenure of land/trees and carbon benefits, distribution of transaction costs and benefits, clarity over the distribution of benefits, a better understanding of power relations and decision-making processes between different actors (ie central and local governments, local communities, NGOs, logging companies, unions etc), improved accountability and transparency, and increased capacity of institutions in managing the use and benefits accrued.

  7.7  Causes of degradation are multi-faceted, and vary greatly between different countries and regions. There is no one-fits-all options for the design of REDD to tackle deforestation and degradation. They must be developed in the context of wider sectoral reform and institutional strengthening at the national and local levels[17] to avoid creating perverse incentives for changing land use.

8.  Question 10:   What action is the Government taking to prepare for and accelerate the linking of the EU Emissions Trading Scheme with other trading schemes? Is a new institutional or regulatory framework required to enable their development and coordination? How might schemes be linked where they have different emission caps? Might the EU-ETS be undermined by linking with other schemes?

  8.1  UK Government has recently signed (28 January 2008) International Carbon Action Partnership (ICAP), a supportive initiative to UNFCCC framework to develop similar design principles for their national/regional trading schemes and markets in preparation for a global carbon market integration in post-2012.

  8.2  Given the early stage development in GHG emissions trading markets, it is important that their architecture remain flexible and adaptive to learning from experiences. Some amount of innovation should be encouraged regarding their design while bearing in mind that clear rules and some degree of harmonization will be needed for a well-functioning and effective global carbon market.[18]

  8.3  There are various non-exclusive arguments for linking GHG emissions markets in different countries in a post-2012 global carbon market. We believe that the balance of different objectives should be set clearly. In principle, trading systems covering as many sources and gases as possible would be more likely to achieve most economic efficiency, and would provide cheaper abatement options in developing countries. However, linking GHG emissions markets also holds the potential as a new diplomatic tool to bring more stakeholders in to reach a Global Deal, and encouraging domestic change to a low-carbon economy in both developed and developing countries. The end goal must be a global agreement with emissions trading at its heart which then will likely replace any linking agreements undertaken up to that point.

  8.4  We believe that a set of criteria should be satisfied to ensure quality of the various schemes, which would be linked to EU-ETS. This would make sure that the EU- ETS is not undermined. These should include absolute mandatory caps, strong measuring and monitoring, and perhaps even auctioning requirements. A recent OECD study (2006) points out the following design features, which will require special attention if to encourage linking different GHG emissions trading markets and schemes:

    —  "How targets are expressed (eg fixed or indexed). For example, care would be needed to ensure that linking does not change the environmental integrity of either system by allowing more emissions than originally intended.

    —  Price caps. Linking a scheme with a price cap to one without a cap could reduce the incentives to deploy innovative technologies in the system not subject to a cap if the price is set too low.

    —  Non-compliance provisions. These can affect the environmental effectiveness of a particular scheme by encouraging (or not) its targets to be met. Stakeholders in a scheme with rigorous non-compliance provisions may be reluctant to link to a scheme with less stringent provisions, and thus a lower perceived environmental effectiveness.

    —  Banking/borrowing provisions, commitment period lengths and starting points. Care would be needed if linking an ETS that allows borrowing with one that does not. Different commitment periods, lengths and banking provisions might also require more sophisticated emissions accounting processes.

    —  Eligibility of offsets. Credits from CDM projects are accepted in several ETS. Other types of eligible offsets vary widely in terms of project types/host countries.

    —  Permit allocation methods in different countries. These could have competitive implications thereby affecting the political acceptability of linking different national systems".

8 February 2008







1   Winkler et al, "Future mitigation commitments: differentiating among non-Annex I countries", Climate Policy 5 (2006); p 478. Back

2   Ho­hne, Niclas. Phylipsen, Detal. Ecofys. "Options for the second commitment period of the Kyoto Protocol"; p 33. Back

3   MOD/DCDC, Global Strategic Trends 2006; FCO Africa Research Analysts, 2007. Back

4   OECD, 2005 Bridge Over Troubled Waters: Linking Climate Change and Development. Back

5   WorldBank, 2006 Back

6   Amount earmarked for adaptation only. Back

7   This is an estimate therefore it is not included in the calculation; the total amount will depend on trade volumes and prices. Back

8   ECP Report, November 2006. Back

9   D Anderson, "Costs and Finance of Abating Carbon Emissions in the Energy Sector," Imperial College, 2006. Back

10   Ibid. Back

11   Ibid. Back

12   Watson et al, 2007 Technology and carbon mitigation in developing countries: Are cleaner coal technologies a viable option? Background Paper for Human Development Report 2007. Back

13   Bernice, Froggatt et al, 2007 Changing Climates: Interdependencies on Energy and Climate Security for China and Europe. Chatham House. Back

14   IPCC, 2007; Houghton, 2005; Stern Review, 2006. Back

15   Schreckenberg et al, 2007 A way out of poverty? A review of the impacts of PFM on livelihoods. Keynote paper presented under Theme 4 "PFM and Livelihoods: Role of PFM in Poverty Reduction" 1st National Participatory Forest Management Conference, 6-8 June 2007.Kenya Forestry Research Institute (KEFRI) HQ, Muguga, Kenya.

ODI; Luttrell et al 2007 The implications of carbon financing for pro-poor community forestry. ODI. Back

16   Peskett and Harkin, 2007 Risk and responsibility in Reduced Emissions from Deforestation and Degradation. ODI. Back

17   Ibid. Back

18   Ellis and Tirpak, 2006 Linking GHG Emission Trading Schemes and Markets. OECD and IEA. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2008
Prepared 8 July 2008