Memorandum submitted by Sustainable Forestry
Management Ltd
INTRODUCTION TO
SFM'S COMMENTS
If there was unanimity on one issue in Bali
at COP 13, it is that tropical forests must play a central and
vital role in any realistic effort to mitigate climate change.
Another strong message from Bali is that payments for reductions
of tropical deforestation and degradation are the key to the developing
world's consent to a post-2012 treaty. Bali highlighted that virtually
the only way in which most developing nations, and particularly
the least-developed ones, can meaningfully participate in and
benefit from the carbon markets is through land use change and
forestry (LULUCF).[1]
The promised benefits of the CDM have, however, largely bypassed
almost all tropical and subtropical countries due to its stifling
approach to LULUCF.[2]
Finally, the important co-benefits of encouraging the conservation
and restoration of tropical and sub-tropical forests were recognised,
including protecting biodiversity and fresh water sources, and
providing the best means of adaptation to climate change for many
of the world's most vulnerable people.[3]
After years of controversy, much of it unjustified
in our opinion, the essential ecosystem services provided by forestry
in mitigating climate change were recognised as a result of the
efforts of the Coalition of Rainforest Nations beginning in Montreal
at COP 11,[4]
the cumulative scientific work of the IPCC and the definitive
economics of the Stern Review. Among other things, the Bali decision
highlights the enormous damage imposed on the world's most important
ecosystems and most vulnerable people by the EU ETS ban on forest
carbon credits. The EU ETS is the world's largest operating carbon
market[5]
and thus the most important, near-term, potential source of the
large-scale, long-term investment required to slow and reverse
deforestation. Yet it has been made inaccessible for this purpose
and to the people most dependent on forests for their survival.
This inaccessibility has compounded the market failure caused
by the CDM (as to which see below).
The EU ban on LULUCF credits, like the EU policy
on biofuels, actually incentivises deforestation and the conversion
of rainforest to agricultural use. This generates manifold perverse
environmental consequences which are becoming more apparent by
the day. Viewed objectively and from the point of view of developing
nations, EU environmental policy is clearly designed to encourage
continued tropical deforestation. The European Commission, lead
by DG Environment, has now adopted two policies, the continued
ban of LULUCF credits and its policy on bio-fuels, which not only
fail to reflect the Bali consensus, but directly contradict the
EU's expressed policies on climate, sustainable development, biodiversity
and poverty alleviation. One need not be a cynic to see this as
hypocritical. The Commission's recent proposal to amend the legislation
governing the EU ETS,[6]
in which it proposes a continuing ban on forestry credits beyond
2012, together with a radical curtailment of all other project
credits, is simply unjustifiable and explicable only by European
myopia and a willful disregard of the evidence.[7]
There are repeated references in Commission
documents to the need for Europe to lead the world in emissions
trading; to set an example. This is somewhat reminiscent of the
last French administration's promotion of the French economic
model; a "model" which no other economy sought to imitate.
A continuing EU ETS ban on forestry combined with a phasing out
of other carbon credits from the developing world, will not only
discourage the participation of the developing world in a post
2012 treaty but it will, in fact, jeopardise the leading position
the EU has achieved in the carbon trading markets. All other emerging
carbon markets, both compliance and voluntary, in the US, Australia,
New Zealand, and the post Kyoto arrangements, propose, or already
include, forest carbon credits. The Commission's position therefore
not only runs against the tide of the rest of the world, but will
also render the EU ETS incompatible with all other trading schemes,
directly in contradiction with its expressed desire to link with
other schemes.[8]
The "linking directive" has, in effect, become the "separation
directive."
A further perverse effect of banning forest
carbon credits will be to make European heavy industry uncompetitive
to the point that, as DG Environment admits, there will be "carbon
leakage" of these industries which will be forced, by the
manipulated price of EU credits, to relocate to lower, or no,
emissions cost countries.[9]
The potential impact on employment has recently been acknowledged
by leading Member States including France and Germany.[10]
Recently floated remedies for this include creating tariff barriers
against imported products which do not pay the cost.[11]
This is not just the economics of the 1930's that lead to a worldwide
depression, such a policy will lead to no net gain to the atmosphere.
The losses to the tax base, the inevitable increase in unemployment
and associated welfare costs will be exacerbated, in climate terms,
by the inevitable loss from the EU of those companies whose management
is the most capable and the most willing to focus their efforts
on innovation in the very industrial sectors where it is most
needed.
Finally, the ban not only contradicts the EU's
policies on poverty alleviation, sustainable development and biodiversity,
it actually prevents the achievement of the EU's stated goal of
climate stabilisation by mid-century. The forecast EU carbon price
which will result from the Commission's proposal is as high as
48/tCO2e.[12]
This is close to the price used by McKinsey in its analysis of
scenarios leading to climate stabilization by 2030.[13]
That analysis demonstrates that offsets from the forestry sector,
particularly tropical and sub-tropical forestry, must account
for a larger share of potential reduction abatement (25%) than
any other sector over that time frame to achieve that goal.[14]
The Commission, in its rationale, suggests that
its position might change if a successor international treaty
is ultimately agreed.[15]
In the meantime, it proposes to phase out virtually all project
credits, thus severely damaging the market and market participants
by artificially reducing demand for CERs.[16]
The resulting chilling effect on the market and on investment
in emissions abatement everywhere outside of Europe is already
apparent. The Commission proposals are already making it clear
to those who invest and develop climate change projects outside
of Europe that no reliance whatsoever can be placed on European
demand for carbon credits. The Commission also seeks the power
to prevent Member States from meeting their Kyoto obligations
with credits, such as CERs, which are excluded from the EU ETS
and to determine itself whether or not any such credits will be
admitted to the EU ETS (or used by Member States) in future whether
or not a successor treaty is entered into.[17]
The result, of course, will be to raise the
price of compliance in the EU and to EU Member States and to reduce
the price of compliance to other Annex 1 countries and their industries.
As the Prime Minister and GLOBE 8 have recently
suggested, it is time to take regulation of the carbon markets
out of the hands of DG Environment and the United Nations and
put it in the hands of a regulator with the expertise in financial
markets required for an undertaking of this size and importance.[18]
If further evidence were required that this war is too important
to be left in the hands of those whose experience is elsewhere,
the recent DEFRA proposals to limit "voluntary offset"
providers to supplying CERs, which are full compliance instruments,
provides it.[19]
Why DEFRA thinks it makes any sense for anyone to pay the additional
and redundant regulatory costs to it (for its "quality mark"
approval) after all of the costs incurred to get CDM approval
and then to sell the resulting CERs to voluntary purchasers, as
opposed to mandatory purchasers, which are bound to pay a higher
price, is beyond most rational observers.[20]
The overwhelming majority of respondents to
the clearly perfunctory DEFRA consultation said that the UK voluntary
market should include forest credits and credits from other projects
which could either not afford CDM costs or did not come within
its rules such as avoided deforestation; this has simply been
disregarded by DEFRA.[21]
To then demand that industry provide a single voluntary standard
and prove its efficacyby essentially creating replica CERsis
disingenuous at best. DEFRA knew that robust standards pre-existed
the consultation (Chicago Climate Exchange, WWF Gold Standard
and the Climate, Community and Biodiversity Alliance Standards)
and that a further comprehensive standard was promulgated, with
widespread industry support, during the consultative period (the
Voluntary Carbon Standard). Its conclusion that none of them,
despite years of wide consultation with all categories of stakeholders,
are adequate to protect the UK public is arrogant to say the least.
The DEFRA standards amount to no more than a reiteration of CDM
rules; this is not "leadership"; it is a retrograde
step indicative of a failure to understand or accept market demand
and market evolution. This rigid, prescriptive, as opposed to
flexible, principles-based, approach to regulation has come to
typify the regulatory approach in Europe and under the CDM. It
is also an approach which is failing and is destined to fail.
What seems to have been lost on these regulatory
bodies, or indeed seen by them as a negative impact, is that the
reason that market-based approaches were adopted to deal with
climate change is to lower the cost of achieving mankind's climate
goals. The persistent effort by regulations such as the EU's explicit
ban and the CDM Executive Board's implicit ban, on LULUCF credits,
is to rig the market to achieve a higher price than necessary.
Whether the result of confusing the role of markets (which is
to seek the most efficient use of capital) with that of subsidies
(which is to replace profits in early stage innovation) or the
result of what one informed observer has called "magical
thinking", the clear intention is to command a sudden and
radical change in the economy. There have been several such efforts
in the past, China's "Great Leap Forward" comes to mind
and the results have been uniformly destructive. The EU Commission's
current effort to rig the price of carbon to administer shock
treatment to the European economy is no more likely to succeed.
It will certainly do nothing to mitigate climate change as no
other country will follow suit in seeking higher rather than lower
cost (ie more efficient) solutions to climate change.[22]
In the context of global warming a "fortress
Europe" approach is futile and counterproductive. The suggestion
made by some, that this is just a bargaining position to force
the US and China into a successor regime, may sound clever but
is, in our view, "too clever by half". It is virtually
inconceivable that the United States will accede to UN regulation
of its carbon market particularly given the UN's performance as
a regulator thus far. It is also unlikely that China will adopt
regulations which mandate high carbon prices in an economy at
its stage of development. It is unlikely in the extreme that those
developing nations which remain dependent on agriculture and forestry
will regard being cut off from investment and the carbon market
for another 5-10 years as being a signal that they will one day
benefit. Their disappointment in the decade of non-delivery by
the CDM was palpable at Bali. Given the economic logic of the
EU Commission's proposed exclusion of virtually all project credits
for the indefinite future, even if a future treaty is negotiated,
the likely response of developing nations is obvious: continued
response to real, as opposed to imaginary, market signals. Increased
timber harvest of native forests, conversion of forests to agriculture
and increased production of commodities with real demand (palm
oil, beef, soya and sugar) are inevitable. Precisely what we all
want to avoid.
Finally the suggestion that revenues from the
auctioning of permits will be earmarked for various project sectors
is, to be polite, disingenuous at best. Finance ministers have
already made it clear that they will not accept hypothecation
of auction proceeds and even if they did there is no structure
for them to allocate such revenues.[23]
Projects supported by aid will not suffice. Leaving aside the
sorry history of such attempts, the billions of dollars which
are required annually and for decades to come to deal just with
deforestation will not be forthcoming from the public sector.
The private sector, the only realistic source of such funding,
will only make large long term investments if it is confident
in the long-term stability and predictability of the markets for
carbon credits. The persistence of political and regulatory interference,
particularly with supply and demand (and hence prices) will only
delay and in many cases prevent, such investment. Participants
in the carbon market, which is centred in London, are already
reconsidering its viability in the face of the EU Commission's
proposals and the manifest inefficiencies of the CDM. Once a market
collapses it is hard and often impossible to resurrect. Given
that the Commission proposes to exclude project-based carbon credits
for years to come it is all too likely that other trading centres,
such as New York, will take its place.[24]
SPECIFIC COMMENTS
ON EAC QUESTIONS
How might mechanisms to tackle emissions from
deforestation be developed? How can we ensure that such mechanisms
contribute to wider sustainable development aims? Will such mechanism
deal with the need to ensure the protection of indigenous people,
land use rights and governance? How might forest degradation be
dealt with? Are additional mechanisms required to enable the creation
of carbon sinks?
The Mechanism
The mechanism for dealing with emissions from
deforestation and forest degradation already, at least in principle,
exist: the carbon trading market. No new mechanism is required
although radically improved regulation is necessary. If forest
carbon is made freely available for compliance purposes, as well
as in the voluntary sector, of the carbon marketplace the critical
problem of tropical forest deforestation and degradation will
be successfully addressed and emissions from that source radically
reduced. All that is required to accomplish this is the setting
of long term targets for emissions reductions and structural change
in the regulation of the market as recently proposed by GLOBE
8.[25]
Sustainability
Deforestation and forest degradation is fundamentally
about land use. The land will be used for something and the question
is what affects the choice of use. Today, in the absence of any
market value for forest carbon, the land is and will continue
to be used to produce timber and agricultural products. These
products, whether on the scale of agri-business or subsistence,
have a real value to the landowners, whether public, communal
or private. Unless the landowners are offered a price for an alternative
land use, such as carbon storage and sequestration, which is at
least equal to or higher than what they get for timber, soya,
palm oil, beef, sugar or maize, what economists call the "opportunity
cost", deforestation and forest degradation will continue.
The demand for these products will not abate given rising population
and living standards; the question is how to direct such production
into sustainability. But there will be no sustainability unless
there is long-term commercial sustainability. The moment that
payments for carbon storage cease conversion of forest land with
its attendant emissions will resume.
The requirement, therefore, is for continuous,
predictable payments of the relevant opportunity cost for each
forest area for decades to come. No one has yet proposed anything
that can be seriously considered capable of accomplishing this
aside from crediting carbon stored or sequestered in biomass for
use in the compliance markets. The failure to do so for the last
15 years is a tragedy and has compounded the difficulty mankind
now faces in dealing with climate change in the limited time left
before it goes beyond our control. Fortunately, considerable work
has been done and continues to be done to assess the opportunity
cost of carbon storage in tropical and sub-tropical forests and
it is affordable; that is, it can be done at a price equal to
or lower than the cost of technological sources of emissions reduction.[26]
The only barrier to these payments being made to landowners and
incentivising change in land use is the regulatory structure thus
far imposed on the carbon markets particularly by the EU and the
CDM.
The opportunity cost of reduced deforestation,
was the basis of a study carried out for the Stern Review. This
estimated the opportunity cost for eight countries that collectively
are responsible for 70% of land-use emissions. If deforestation
in these countries were to be reduced by 50%, the opportunity
cost would amount to at least $5-10 billion annually (approximately
$1-2/tCO2 on average).[27]
Although there are various proposals for public sector funding,
donor governments and agencies show little sign of being able
to contribute funding necessary at that level for the decades
required.[28]
<IMG SRC="8031101.gof">
Chomitz, K, 2007, At Loggerheads? Agricultural
Expansion, Poverty
Reduction and Environment in the Tropical Forests,
The World Bank
Carbon credits from avoided deforestation allow
a real commercial alternative value to be placed on tropical forests
if they are integrated into carbon credit trading systems in a
fungible and transparent manner. The carbon market can in many
cases "tip" the balance of economics in favour of forest
conservation. According to the World Bank's most recent study
of the subject, tropical forest cleared to pasture is worth between
$200-500 per hectare. Based on its average CO2 storage
per hectare of 500 tonnes, its value is between $1500-10,000 per
hectare (@ $3-20/tCO2).[29]
Even at the low end range of carbon prices continued deforestation
would become unprofitable in many land systems if it is credited
in the carbon markets.[30]
The international community, prompted by a proposal
from 15 developing countries,[31]
now understands this and has been in dialogue over the inclusion
of emission reductions from avoided deforestation and degradation
in the post-2012 regime for the last two years. At COP 13 in Bali
the parties resolved in their decision on "Reducing emissions
from deforestation in developing countries: approaches to stimulate
action" a number of measures to assist in evaluation
and implementation of mechanisms to tackle emissions from this
source.[32]
In relation to specific mechanisms it was resolved "that
policy approaches and positive incentives on issues relating to
reducing emissions from deforestation and forest degradation in
developing countries will be considered in the context of land
use . . . [33]The
role of the carbon market in this effort was recognized in the
Bali Roadmap where it is stated that "various approaches,
including opportunities for using markets, to enhance the cost-effectiveness
of, and to promote, mitigation actions, bearing in mind different
circumstances of developed and developing countries".[34]
Forests, in short, are finally being recognized as a critical,
"cost-effective" key to a future climate change treaty
as well as being important for the other environmental services
they provide[35]
including services which are also essential to adaptation to climate
change by the rural poor.[36]
It is also now acknowledged that the carbon market is the most
appropriate vehicle to deliver these policy goals.
The 26 developing countries in the Coalition
of Rainforest Nations[37]
have made it clear that either they receive compensation for the
carbon sequestration services which their native forests provide
to the world or they must continue to exploit them as sources
of energy, food and wood products.[38]
The implications of the latter are illustrated in that Indonesia
is now the third largest emitter of greenhouse gases in the world,
almost entirely the result of continued deforestation, and Brazil
is fourth for largely the same reason.[39]
It is only through linking emission reductions from avoided deforestation
and degradation to the carbon market, and in so doing linking
forests with the world financial markets, that sufficient capital
will be available to ensure that a substantial reduction in deforestation
globally and a shift to sustainable sources of supply actually
occurs in the time remaining to us.
It is also critically important to understand
that the payments to landowners, while necessary, are not sufficient
to sustainability. New sustainably managed sources of timber and
forest product supply must be created to meet ever increasing
demand. This too was acknowledged at Bali.[40]
These too require annual investments measured in the billions
of dollars. The continued discouragement of such investment in
the developing world by the EU ban on forest credits and the CDM
rules on afforestation and reforestation compound the difficulty
of reaching the goal of sustainable supply and sustainable development.
We cannot just reduce or end the harvest of native forests without
creating such alternative supplies; in Kyoto-speak: we cannot
have REDD without A/R.
Methods
The methods of linking the land with the capital
markets are now well developed and understood. The SBSTA workshop
(Cairns, 2007) concluded that "there is general agreement
that methods, tools and data are robust enough to estimate emissions
with an acceptable level of certainty and that the IPCC Good Practice
Guidance for LULUCF and the 2006 IPCC Guidelines provide a good
basis for the estimation of emissions from deforestation and their
reductions".[41]
Since the early 1990s, changes in forest area
have been able to be measured by satellite with confidence.[42]
Analysis of remotely sensed data from aircraft and satellites
supported by ground based observations is now well developed at
the national level.[43]
Some developing countries have national level monitoring initiatives
in place for the land use sector such as Brazil[44]
and India[45].
Other countries are developing these capabilities or have successfully
monitored forests with aerial photographs that do not require
sophisticated data analysis or computer resources. A variety of
methods that are applicable to varying national circumstances
regarding forest characteristics, cost constraints, and scientific
capabilities are available and adequate for monitoring deforested
areas and verifying the accuracy of such measurements. Additionally,
the historical remote sensing database is sufficient to develop
a baseline of tropical deforestation in the 1990s.[46]
Based on current capabilities, GHG emissions
from deforestation can be accurately estimated. These estimates
come from changes in the carbon stocks in the above-ground biomass
of trees and from other forest carbon pools using models and default
data in the IPCC Good Practice Guidelines report.[47]
Forest inventories can provide biomass values according to forest
type and use, such as mature forest, intensely logged, selectively
logged, fallow etc. Many developing countries do not have sufficient
data from national forest inventories and they should be assisted
in developing this information and the related administrative
systems.[48]
However, even in their absence, the FAO database provides a default
value for national carbon stock with stratification into main
ecological zones.[49]
Compilation of data from ecological or other permanent sample
plots can provide estimates of carbon stocks for different forest
types subject to the design of site specific scientific studies.
There are a variety of approaches and potential
mechanisms to crediting avoided deforestation and degradation
activities which reflect the variety of historical experiences
of the countries which are the intended beneficiaries. A flexible
combination of approaches is the best way forward whether based
on mandatory or non-mandatory emissions targets being adopted
by such countries. A sectoral approach based on national boundaries
and national administration established under broad principle-based
regulation, as opposed to the current CDM approach of prescriptive,
project by project assessment, is required both because of its
simplicity and its respect for sovereignty and because it eliminates
many of the methodological problems, such as leakage and additionality,
which have plagued development of the CDM market thus far. National
forest sector emission targets adopted by developing countries
are by far the most efficient way of encouraging sustainable forest
management and reducing deforestation. This approach lays the
foundation for the capital markets to operate in a coherent regulatory
environment.
Indigenous Peoples, Land Use Rights and Governance
The Bali decision on "Reducing emissions
from deforestation in developing countries: approaches to stimulate
action" specifically recognizes "that the needs
of local and indigenous communities should be addressed when action
is taken to reduce emissions from deforestation and forest degradation
in developing countries". One of the key aspects of markets
that seems to elude most participants in the debate over forest
carbon credits, is their requirement that land ownership and entitlement
to land use rights are clearly established. Unless the buyer is
confident that the carbon credits it purchases have been lawfully
created and transferred he will not buy them. Exchanges and clearing
houses are specifically designed to ensure that "good delivery"
takes place in the commodities which they list and trade. Purchasers
of carbon credits in particular, exposed as they are to public
and regulatory oversight, do not want to find that the credits
they buy are sourced through abuses of human rights or from stolen
land. It is critical to all markets that ownership be clearly
established and the market for land use rights, like carbon storage
and sequestration is no exception.
Markets quickly punish and exclude those who
fail to deliver what was bargained for. The carbon markets have
appropriate standards for "good delivery" of forest
carbon; these standards have already been developed and are being
adopted by exchanges, in over-the-counter transactions and in
the voluntary sector.[50]
By the same token good delivery requires lawful delivery requiring
compliance with both domestic and international law such as ILO
169.[51]
In short, good governance is integral to well-regulated markets
and is demanded by them. The opportunity to benefit from the payments
such markets offer is itself a powerful incentive to improved
governance including acceptable standards of land tenure and registration
and the adoption of the safeguards for vulnerable communities
required by long term investors of capital.
Forest Degradation
Although carbon emissions from forest degradation
may not be as large per unit area as the complete removal of forest
through deforestation, forest degradation occurs over large areas
and can contribute significantly to overall emissions from forest
loss.[52]
Differences between forest and degraded forest are more subtle
than in the case of deforestation, and degradation patches are
generally small compared with clearings. Monitoring degradation
is technically more difficult than monitoring deforestation but
is now practicable. Techniques have been developed and are being
steadily improved. A team at the Carnegie Institution of Washington,
for example, has developed techniques for automated remote-sensing
analysis of selective logging utilising Landsat satellite imagery
combined with extensive fieldwork. Their work highlighted that
exclusion of selective logging from a monitoring system would
miss a substantial source of emitted carbon and that such activity
can be monitored remotely.[53]
Forest degradation therefore must and can be included in the calculation
of biomass subject to emissions reduction targets and for crediting
in the carbon marketplace.
Our recommendation is that countries that have
the capacity and funding to measure and monitor degradation should
be encouraged to do so by the opportunity to sell the carbon credits
generated from reduced forest degradation in the same manner as
those generated from avoided deforestation activities. We recommend
that countries be able to choose the level of carbon accounting
for their country (with periodic review). This would allow countries
which have the funding and capacity to generate emissions reductions
from reduced degradation to generate carbon credits immediately
while those countries who have not reached a stage to implement
this level of technological capacity are assisted to do so.
Additional Mechanisms for Carbon Sinks
As will be apparent from the remarks above,
some developing countries, although by no means all, lack the
infrastructure for full realisation of the markets' potential.
The key is to provide them with the capacity to reap those benefits.
Some need assistance to measure, monitor and verify their carbon
stocks. Some have weak systems of land tenure and registration,
others require assistance with administration and public accountability.
Some need assistance with law enforcement. These are essential
elements to a functioning market. It is here, in capacity building,
that the public sector and multinational institutions have a key
role to play and a role in which they have expertise and institutionalised
experience. If the available resources from the public sector
were utilised for this purpose carbon sinks everywhere can be
fully valued by the market for the benefit of all concerned. If
there is a role for a "fund" (which was the original
intention behind the creation of the CDM) this is surely it.
Are the Clean Development and Joint Implementation
Mechanisms functioning effectively? How might they be improved?
How might they better be used in relation to forestry or other
land use emission reduction projects? Should CDM and JI projects
play a greater role in sustainable development more widely? To
what extent should credits such as those from the CDM and JI be
permitted to be used in emissions trading schemes, or contribute
to emissions reductions targets?
It is now evident that insofar as land use and
forestry is concerned both the CDM and JI have failed to make
any contribution. This was, in many ways, failure by design. Despite
the fact that all forestry and land use is accounted for in Annex
1 countries, at the outset of the debate over the role of developing
countries, the CDM excluded deforestation entirely.[54]
Then, in 2001 at COP7 in Marrakech, it adopted rules (the "Marrakech
Accords") which by their terms and in subsequent interpretations
by the CDM Executive Board, made it nearly impossible even for
afforestation and reforestation projects to be approved.[55]
Needless to say, investment in the forestry
sector through the CDM has been virtually nonexistent, despite
a relatively large number of approved methodologies for CDM projects
in general. Out of 106 approved methodologies, 10, or 9.4%, relate
to afforestation and reforestation. However, out of 945 registered
CDM projects, only 1, or 0.1%, is an A/R project.[56]
Moreover, this project is projected to generate only 340,000 tCO2
by the end of 2012,[57]
in comparison to the projected 1.17 billion tCO2 from
the other registered projects. As of today, there are no forestry
projects approved under JI.[58]
The obvious bias against LULUCF is such that no meaningful commercial
investment is likely under the present regime.
Despite being initially excluded from the CDM,
deforestation in developing countries has finally returned to
the agenda. The consensus in Bali on the urgent need to deal with
tropical deforestation and forest degradation speaks for itself.
The developing nations have also made their position clear: unless
they are paid for their carbon sinks they will not accede to a
post-2012 treaty. The logic of their position is unassailable.
Unless they receive compensation for not converting forests to
agriculture they cannot develop their economies sustainably or
otherwise. They are the low cost producers of many agricultural
products as well as the principal source of timber demanded by
the industrial world and they will not give up that competitive
advantage for nothing. They also must feed growing populations.[59]
To be understood, deforestation has to be seen
primarily as a response to market forces both international and
domestic. The world's growing demand for food and forest products
will not abate; it can only be directed toward sustainable supplies
by the same market forces that create the demand. This is the
critical role which the carbon markets can play if, but only if,
appropriate regulation is now introduced. There needs to be both
structural and regulatory realignment before that market can have
its desired effects. We suggest below seven steps which need to
be taken urgently if tropical forest loss is to be arrested.
The first step is to rectify the bias against
the developing world now codified in the Kyoto Protocol. Any successor
treaty must treat North and South alike by extending the same
comprehensive crediting of forests and agricultural land allowed
to Annex 1 countries to all treaty adherents. There is no longer
any justification for and many reasons against, continued discrimination
against tropical carbon sinks.[60]
The goal should be full carbon accounting, whereby all biomass
is accounted for in measuring progress toward achieving each country's
emission reduction goals. The scientific and technological techniques
for this now exist.[61]
The only requirement for qualifying for such treatment should
be demonstration of technical and administrative capacity. Those
countries which do not have, or cannot afford, such capacity should
receive internationally funded support to achieve it such as that
proposed by the World Bank's deforestation initiative.[62]
The second step is to remove from the CDM the
authority to approve carbon projects for crediting. No agency
in the world has, or can have, the requisite capacity, expertise
and resources to make judgements as to every project in over 100
countries spanning everything from agriculture to industrial processes.
Instead of the current prescriptive approach of the CDM, the successor
treaty should adopt a principle-based approach to regulation such
as that now adopted by the Financial Services Authority. Project
approvals should be entirely devolved to participating countries
whose designated agencies would take on the responsibility to
conform their rules to broad principles established by or under
the successor treaty. There does not need to be paternalistic
second guessing by others provided that the market is then allowed
to operate within a stable regime.
A necessary third step is therefore an agreement
on long-term emission reduction goals which are not subject to
periodic political or regulatory interference. A key structural
weakness of both the Kyoto Protocol and the EU ETS are the five-year
compliance periods at the end of which political and regulatory
interference is virtually assured. This creates wholly unnecessary
uncertainty. Investments which must perform over decades cannot
be implemented in this context particularly those dealing with
forest and land use. Clear overall targets for emissions reduction
must be set and adhered to both in terms of the level of reduction
and the period in which they must be accomplished. A realistic
time period is at least until 2030 and preferably beyond. Fundamental
changes in the world's economy will not take place in any shorter
period and neither the capital nor trading markets can operate
to facilitate that change if the challenge is compounded by periodic
political and regulatory interference.
The fourth step is to increase the participation
of the private sector in the regulatory process. Uniquely in recent
history, the development of climate change goals, legislation
and regulation has taken place without any meaningful consultation
of the private sector, the capital markets or even financial market
regulators. The Stern Review, the first government sponsored economic
analysis was published in 2007, some 15 years after the Rio Conference
which launched the Kyoto process. Until its publication virtually
no economic or financial analysis was referred to in the climate
debate. To the authors' knowledge no meaningful input has yet
been sought, by the UN or by the EU, from those most experienced
with capital and commodity markets such as central bankers, market
regulators and market practitioners. This sealed box approach
has lead to such recent fiascos as the price collapse in the market
in Phase One of the EU ETS; the acceleration of tropical deforestation
and increase in food prices caused by mandated bio-fuels standards
and most recently the suppression of the market for CERs.[63]
Fifth there must be far more open and efficient
decision making whether at international or national levels. The
lack of transparency in decision making by the CDM is now legendary
and has caused enormous harm particularly to those seeking to
work within its rules.[64]
Symptomatic of the causes of damage to investment is the time
it takes to get a project from the period of public comment to
the registration. The CDM requires an average number of 237 days
for a project to progress from the start of the public comment
period until a request for registration; then there is a further
average delay from the request for registration until registration
of 84 days. It thus takes well over a year to create a CER and
the process is slowing down, not speeding up as should be the
case now that the CDM Executive Board has years of experience
to draw upon. In June 2005 it took an average of 70 days for a
project proposal to proceed from a registration request to registration.
By June 2007, this had increased to 110 days. For projects that
require a new methodology, it takes an average of 305 days from
the point of submission of a new methodology to its approval.[65]
In other words a project developer seeking innovative solutions
will be required to wait two years or more to find out if he can
proceed. We simply don't have time for such a bureaucratic process
if the developing world is to make a meaningful contribution to
dealing with climate change. There is also substantial anecdotal
evidence of political and personal bias in decision making.
The sixth step is to repeal, and certainly not
to replicate or extend, the regulations and regulatory interpretations
which have stifled investment in the forest and land use sector.
The required use of counterfactual scenarios and the adoption
of arcane concepts with no meaningful analytical underpinning
have created a "parallel universe" of regulatory requirements
which are completely detached from commercial reality. The first
and key step, as mentioned above, is to extend to developing nations
the same scope of forest project credit types as is afforded to
Annex 1 countries. This leads to the second reform which is to
provide for the inclusion of the full spectrum of land use: avoided
deforestation, forest degradation, reforestation (natural and
assisted), sustainable forest management, afforestation, low till
and no-till agriculture. Third, prescriptive rules such as those
created by the CDM for afforestation and reforestation should
be rejected. These include such counterproductive measures as
the following:
(i) Capping at 1% of compliance requirement
the use of A/R credits by Annex 1 countries
CDM forestry rules cap the use of A/R credits
to just 1% of an Annex 1's country's annual compliance requirement
over the first commitment period; equivalent to 120MtCO2
annually. The 1% rule has clearly had a "chilling effect"
on the market, discouraging investment in A/R projects, which
offer the only meaningful alternative to meeting timber and fuel
demand by continued deforestation of natural forests. There is
no such cap on Annex 1 countries.
(ii) A/R projects are limited in location
to lands deforested or in agricultural use prior to 1990 and which
remain deforested at a project's inception. Restoration of land
deforested since 1990 or of degraded land is excluded
The result of this rule has been to exclude from
the system any credit for regeneration or replanting of forests
destroyed since 1990. As a result between 125-195 million hectares
of deforested land is now ineligible for CDM forestry (an area
three times the size of France) and the area is growing (not least
because of the lack of any crediting of avoided deforestation)
by an area the size of Greece every year and it is happening in
the most bio-diverse areas and the home to many of the world's
last remaining indigenous peoples.
(iii) Requiring the replacement of A/R
credits after a maximum of 60 years
Forests are a long-term store of carbon. They
have covered vast areas of the earth's surface for millennia,
and contain 60% of the carbon stored in terrestrial ecosystems.[66]
CDM rules require that A/R forest credits be either temporary
("tCERs") or long term ("lCERs") and that
all of them be replaced at specific intervals which are unrelated
to the forest harvest cycle, with a maximum duration of 60 years.
This rule not only reduces incentives for forest restoration but
actually encourages the liquidation of healthy forests after no
more than 60 years in order to generate cash to buy replacement
credits. No other carbon market in the world finds such a rule
necessary.
New rules should be principles-based and should
allow for the recognition of the full value of tropical and subtropical
forest land carbon storage and sequestration. LULUCF projects
can bring multiple benefits, all of which are intricately linked
and promote sustainable development. They include ecosystem services
such as soil protection, erosion control, water purification,
reduced flooding, agricultural pollination, local rainfall and
biodiversity protection. They also include benefits to local communities
and indigenous people by encouraging the resolution of land tenure
issues, increasing resilience to adaptation to climate change,
such as drought, storms, wildfires and floods.[67]
New rules should encourage payment for these services in addition
to carbon storage and sequestration and thus begin to fully value
the multiple benefits of tropical and sub-tropical forests.
The seventh and final step is to ensure public
accountability both of the regulators themselves and the efficacy
of the regulations they promulgate. The CDM Executive Board, for
example, is appointed by an obscure process in which those most
affected by its decisions have no say. There is no requirement
that its members have any relevant experience or expertise and
its resources are not the subject of any budgetary scrutiny. Regulations
are promulgated without any serious attempt to determine their
costs or benefits, their impact on climate change or in the case
of land use and forestry, their impact on biodiversity, on communities
or on other critical resources such as fresh water. Neither the
markets nor the general public can have any confidence in such
a system of regulation.
SUMMARY
None of the manifold benefits and none of the
climate change mitigation potential of the tropical and sub-tropical
forests are now being realised precisely because of their exclusion
from the carbon markets by misconceived regulation. Markets, contrary
to many of the underlying assumptions of these counterproductive
regulations, are in fact are very good at ensuring the integrity
of the products they buy and sell and in punishing bad deliveries
and bad deliverers. Market discipline, supported by appropriate,
not manipulative, regulation will always be more efficient than
bureaucratic attempts to ensure capital formation and price discovery.
Markets are excellent at distinguishing the qualities of competing
products by pricing them and their associated risks. There is
no need to tell them what to do and efforts to do so, to pick
winning technologies or approaches, always fail at huge and unnecessary
cost. The EU bio-fuels targets are just one recent example of
this.
Structural change is required which removes
regulatory authority for the carbon market from the UN and EU
Commission and vests it in the hands of experienced and accountable
bodies such as central banks and securities markets. The role
of the UN should be to establish the emissions targets to be undertaken
by each country and to set out the broad principles which all
countries must adhere to. No attempt should be made to make special
rules which discriminate against the full participation of the
developing world in the carbon markets such as is embodied in
the CDM. The World Bank and other multinational bodies should
assemble and distribute public sector funds to capacity building
in the developing world so that all countries can benefit from
investment driven by the carbon market.
We are firmly of the view that use of forest
and land use credits, broadly defined to include the whole spectrum
of rural land use, should be permitted to an unlimited extent
in emissions trading schemes and in reaching emission reduction
targets. Climate research has shown that to avoid catastrophic
changes to the global climate and large scale irreversible systemic
disruption temperatures must not increase above a threshold of
2% those in pre-industrial times.[68]
Achieving this target requires significant emission cuts. The
task of reducing and mitigating greenhouse gases on this timescale
is enormous and to do so at a minimal cost to the world's economy
should be a priority for policy makers. Emission trading schemes
are designed to put a price on an industrial pollutant and to
yield the lowest cost sources of compliance. Thus, opening the
scheme as widely as possible to all sources of credits will allow
the market to drive investment toward these low cost solutions.
Unrestricted trading of REDD and LULUCF credits will provide a
major portion, up to 25%, of the solution, will lower the cost
of overall compliance and provide time for industry to implement
the balance of the solution. If we do not rectify the fundamental
error of excluding such credits from the carbon markets we will
fail in the attempt to stabilise the climate.
Is there adequate support for developing countries
to adapt to climate change?
No and there never will be without large scale
private sector investment in rural land use in the developing
world. Adaptation to climate change is costly, and to date it
is unclear where the necessary funding will come from. According
to the Stern Review in OECD countries the cost of making new infrastructure
resilient to climate change could range from $15-$150 billion
each year (0.05-0.5% of GDP), with their costs reflecting the
prospect of higher temperatures in future. The Stern Review highlights
that while there are few credible estimates of the costs of adaptation
in developing countries it estimates the additional costs of adaptation
alone in the developing world are $4-37 billion each year. This
includes only the cost of adapting investments to protect them
from climate-change risks, and it is important to remember that
there will be major impacts that are sure to occur even with efforts
at adaptation.[69]
Needless to say, many of the key elements of adaptation for the
rural poor of the developing world are integral to sustainable
management of the tropical and sub-tropical forests as well as
sustainable use of agricultural lands.[70]
In the absence of such investment and the stabilisation of their
local environments, particularly soils and sources of fresh water,
tens if not hundreds of millions of the 1.4 billion people dependent
on forest resources for their survival will become involuntary
environmental migrants with profound negative effects on their
societies and on ours.[71]
Sustainable Forestry Management (UK) Ltd
4 Grosvenor Place, London, SW1X 7HJ, +44 (0)20 7589
852
schedule 1: Rebuttal to DG Environment
29 January 2008
RESPONSE TO DG ENVIRONMENT'S STAFF WORKING
DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT ON LULUCF AND FOREST-BASED CARBON CREDITS
In December 2007, the staff of the European Commission's
Directorate General for Environment circulated a draft Staff Working
Document on an impact assessment of its proposal for a Directive
to amend Directive 2003/37/EC on the EU Emissions Trading Scheme
(the "Staff Working Document"). This paper responds
to the Staff Working Document's sweeping and unjustified assertions
on land use, land-use change and forestry ("LULUCF")
and in particular on forest-based carbon credits.
The crucial importance of the world's tropical
foreststhe second largest source of CO2 emissionsboth
to achieving climate stabilisation by mid-century and doing so
at a reasonable cost, has been authoritatively and repeatedly
documented by the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change ("IPCC"),
in the Stern Review and in numerous studies of other independent
parties, such as McKinsey.i It is also widely recognized that
reducing deforestation and encouraging reforestation are essential
to enabling the world's poorest and most vulnerable people to
adapt to climate change. ii
This widespread scientific, economic and political
consensus was emphatically endorsed at the 13th Conference of
the Parties of the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate
Change ("UNFCCC") in Bali last December 2007. There
is also a growing conviction among many influential scientists,
policymakers, and representatives of civil society and indigenous
peoples that carbon markets, and in particular the EU Emissions
Trading Scheme ("EU ETS"), represent the single most
important source of long-term and large scale investment that
is urgently needed to protect and restore the forests of the developing
world. iii
The Staff Working Document stands well outside
this mainstream view. It contains many extreme and very negative
allegations against the contribution of LULUCF activities to climate
change mitigation and the role of forest-based carbon credits.
Yet, unsurprisingly given its ideological orientation, the Staff
Working Document fails to cite a single authoritative source for
any of its broad assertions.
This paper will show how most of the Staff Working
Document's assertions are factually incorrect, contradict international
scientific and technical consensus, and reveal an unjustified
bias against the contribution of sustainable forestry to climate
change mitigation.
Thus, for the reasons explained below, we urge
policy markers to set aside the Staff Working Document in formulating
the EU's approach to the revision of the ETS as it relates to
LULUCF and forest-based carbon credits.
1. EMISSIONS
FROM LULUCF ACTIVITIES
DG Environment's Staff Working Document
Allegation
Land Use, Land Use Change and Forestry (LULUCF)
activities can lead to emissions of greenhouse gas and their removal
from the atmosphere. These processes are inherently reversible,
and carbon stored can at some point be released.
THE FACTS
"Risk of financial loss from a damaging
natural event surely exists in timberland investments. Yet, 12
years of historical loss data reinforce what we have believed
all alongthat the risk of loss from a natural event has
been very small, averaging 0.04 percent (4 basis points) of loss
per year". (Hancock Timberland Investor) iv
Forests are a long-term store of carbon. They
have covered vast areas of the Earth's surface for millennia and
contain 60% of the carbon stored in terrestrial ecosystems.v Their
duration exceeds that of any industrial facility.
Robust methods are also available to address
and account for permanence, including maintenance of adequate
reserves or buffers to cope with unforeseen losses in carbon stocks,
insurance, discount factors based on the assessed risk of carbon
loss and general strategies to reduce risk to carbon stocks, such
as pest control and fire management. The risk of loss from a natural
event in managed forests is also very small, averaging 0.04% of
loss per year. vi In fact, it is so small that most large forest
enterprises self-insure.
2. THE CARBON
SEQUESTRATION POTENTIAL
OF FORESTS
DG Environment's Staff Working Document
Allegation
The capacity of carbon sequestration by forests
diminishes with time, and climate change will have further negative
influence on a natural carbon uptake by the terrestrial biosphere.
THE FACTS
"Experiments have unequivocally shown
that plants can grow faster and larger in a CO2-enriched
atmosphere, and the mechanisms of response are well understood".
(Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences) vii
"A series of carbon budgets based on
data from forest inventories have shown that carbon is accumulating
in northern mid-latitude terrestrial ecosystems". (Woods
Hole Research Centre) viii
In a study recently published in the Proceedings
of the National Academy of Sciences, an international team
of 19 researchers states that "experiments have unequivocally
shown that plants can grow faster and larger in a CO2-enriched
atmosphere, and the mechanisms of response are well understood".ix
Attention to the global carbon cycle over more than 30 years has
focused on the so-called "missing sink," missing because
the accumulation of carbon in the atmosphere that would be expected
has not been observed. In the last few years, several independent
analyses based on geochemical data (ie, data from the atmosphere
and oceans) and a series of carbon budgets based on data from
forest inventories have shown that carbon is accumulating in northern
mid-latitude terrestrial ecosystems.x
In addition, the Staff Working Document's allegation
is entirely irrelevant for credits from Clean Development Mechanism
("CDM") and Joint Implementation ("JI") projects,
and only serves to set a negative and biased tone. CDM and JI
rules require that changes in carbon stocks over time within the
project boundary be accounted for in the project's monitoring
system. As a result, credits can only be issued for ex-post verified
carbon sequestration above an established baseline, based on scientifically
accepted monitoring techniques (See eg, the IPCC's Good Practice
Guidance for LULUCF and the nine approved A/R CDM methodologies).
3. PROCEEDS FROM
AUCTIONING FOR
AVOIDED DEFORESTATION
DG Environment's Staff Working Document
Allegation
Proceeds from the auctioning of allowances within
the EU ETS should be used to mitigate greenhouse gas emissions,
in particular to fund measures to avoid deforestation.
THE FACTS
"A study carried out for this [Stern]
Review estimated opportunity costs on the basis for eight countries
that collectively are responsible for 70% of land-use emissions
(responsible for 4.9 GtCO2 in 2050 under BAU conditions).
If all deforestation in these countries were to cease, the opportunity
cost would amount to around $5-10 billion annually".
(Stern Review) xi
The resources required to combat forest degradation
and encourage forest restoration are very substantial, measuring
in the tens of billions of Euros and will be required for decades
to come. There is no likelihood that any fraction of the proceeds
from auctioning will generate sums of this magnitude. Avoided
deforestation activities will have to compete with a variety of
other climate change adaptation and mitigation activities for
a share of the proceeds resulting from the auctioning of emission
allowances. The Commission's proposal for a Directive amending
the EU ETS Directive provides for only 20% of the proceedings
to be destined to climate change mitigation and adaptation activities,
which include, in addition to avoided deforestation, contributions
to the Global Energy Efficiency and Renewable Energy Fund, the
development of renewable energies, capture and geological storage
of greenhouse gases ("GHGs"), facilitation of developing
countries' adaptation to climate change, addressing social aspects
in middle and lower income households, and administrative expenses
of the EU ETS. xii
In contrast, carbon markets and forest-based
carbon credits are efficient market based instruments that can
mobilize the huge amount of resources that are so necessary to
encourage developing countries to meaningfully engage in sustainable
forestry.
4. APPROVED CDM
LULUCF PROJECTS
DG Environment's Staff Working Document
Allegation
Only nine LULUCF methodologies have been so
far approved for CDM use, resulting in only 2% of all CERs for
the first phase. The official registry pipeline (UNEP Risoe) identifies
only one JI LULUCF project as registered. The reason for this
relatively small occurrence is primarily to be found in the complexity
of solving inherent inconsistency of the LULUCF projects: ensuring
permanency, verification and adequate monitoring of carbon storage.
THE FACTS
In fact, to date no JI LULUCF project and only
one CDM afforestation and reforestation ("A/R") project
has been registered. xiii Contrary to the Staff Working Document's
allegation, however, the key reasons for this are the following:
(i) The modalities and procedures governing
LULUCF were discussed and decided only at COP 9 in Milan. xiv
(ii) The slow bureaucratic process of the
CDM Executive Board has meant that there has been considerable
policy uncertainty compared to other sectors, with only the first
CDM A/R methodology approved in December 2005 and the first (and
so far only) project registered in December 2006.
(iii) The fact that LULUCF is excluded from
the EU ETS has been a disincentive for investors to develop projects
and methodologies in this sector as the market is limited.
(iv) With the exclusion of LULUCF credits
from the EU ETS, governments have been the only possible buyers
of CDM LULUCF. This means that minimal experience has been gained
with respect to forestry credits and governments have been wary
to utilize credits with which they have little experience. Thus,
market liquidity, which is necessary for the efficient functioning
of any market, has been denied to the forestry sector.
In essence the EUTS ban of forestry credits
has become a self-fulfilling prophecy which is now used to justify
its continuance.
5. EFFECTIVE
SOLUTIONS FOR
THE TEMPORARY
AND REVERSIBLE
NATURE OF
LULUCF ACTIVITIES
DG Environment's Staff Working Document
Allegation
All options under consideration pose problems
concerning the temporary and reversible nature of LULUCF activities.
As forests and cultivated land are dynamic ecosystems, changes
in carbon capture are not only linked to the developer's influence,
but are subject to temperature, weather conditions, outbreaks
of transmissible tree diseases and pests as well as fires. [ .
. . ]
The problems related to the temporary and reversible
nature of LULUCF have not yet been solved and no effective solutions
are in sight at the moment.
THE FACTS
"The EU notes that non-permanence is
not an issue when possible reversals are compensated. Approaches
to deal with non-permanence include (a) using temporary credits
in a manner similar to the current A/R CDM projects, (b) reducing
future financial incentives to take account of deforestation emissions
above the agreed level, (c) bank credits and debits from one period
to another, or (d) by mandatory banking of a share of the emission
reductions. The transition from unsustainable to sustainable land
use management reduces the risk of increases in emissions from
deforestation". (Submission of the European Union to
the SBSTA) xv
Forests and natural ecosystems are in dynamic
equilibrium. For many ecosystems, exposure to fire, changing weather
conditions, pests, and so forth are part of their natural disturbance
and successional regimes. xvi In the case of CDM A/R projects,
CERs are only generated ex-post at various intervals during the
project lifetime, and therefore, credits are only issued for carbon
which has been physically measured on the landscape. xvii
The risk of non-permanence of forests can in
fact be addressed in many different ways. These include insurance
products, pooled buffers, risk discounts, project rating services,
and the ton year approach, which takes the life time of a molecule
of CO2 in the atmosphere as a measure if permanence.
The CDM's creation of temporary credits (ie,
tCERs and lCERs) is yet another approach to the risk of non-permanence
of forests. However, this approach, while technically adequate,
is not optimal because it does not remove the perception of non-permanence
from potential buyers.
Other mandatory and voluntary schemes have addressed
the "temporary" nature of LULUCF in different ways.
For example, the New South Wales Greenhouse Gas Abatement Scheme,
which is the precendent for the announced Australian Emissions
Trading System, has designed measuring and accounting systems
that insure the permanence of forestry credits in the scheme.
xviii As a result, sequestration credits from forestry are considered
permanent in the New South Wales Greenhouse Gas Abatement Scheme,
and there is no differentiation on the compliance buyer's part
of a forestry credit from any other type of credit in the system.
The New Zealand Emissions Trading System likewise has no difficulty
in accounting for fluctuations in forest carbon accounting. xix
In the voluntary sector, the Voluntary Carbon
Standard requires a buffer of credits that are held in reserve
in the case of non-performance of the project. Project developers
can draw on this buffer if the project does not deliver the required
amount of credits. xx The Chicago Climate Exchange rules for forest-based
carbon credits are well established and similarly require a buffer
stock approach. xxi
6. LIABILITY
RISKS OF
TEMPORARY CREDITS
DG Environment's Staff Working Document
Allegation
Temporary credits create significant liability
risks. For example, companies that consider closing down might
be tempted to use temporary credits. If the company ceases to
exist, it can no longer replace the temporary credits hence requiring
that carbon cuts are made elsewhere to meet emissions targets.
As a result, the Member State in which the company operated would
have to cover for the expired credits. A key reason for not allowing
the use of credits from LULUCF in Phase I and II would be to avoid
the risk of liability falling on State where such credits have
been used by companies. A company that intended to close its operations
would have a clear incentive to use such credits and transfer
liability to the State, since these creditsowing to the
need for repeated surrenderwill be less valuable than permanent
credits. Council and Parliament also excluded any possible JI
credits relating to LULUCF from the EU ETS because, as mentioned
above, no modalities have been developed in relation to the non-permanence
and other issues arising in relation to JI LULUCF projects.
THE FACTS
The temporary nature of credits does not affect
the treatment of any liability of EU ETS operators in the case
of insolvency. The obligation to surrender allowances forms part
of the liabilities that belong to the legal estate of an operator.
All suppliers of carbon credits sell them for forward delivery
and, in the event of their insolvency, the liability for failure
to make delivery will be the same whether the credits are "temporary"
or not and regardless of how they were supposed to be generated.
It is extremely unlikely that an EU ETS operator
would purchase any EU allowances (and not only forest-based carbon
credits) in the face of bankruptcy. The liability to surrender
any allowances to the government is under most insolvency laws
not a liability that is given high priority. Certainly, an operator
would first have to pay taxes, salaries or service senior financial
obligations before it would have to fulfill EU ETS obligations.
The same applies in the case of liquidation. The liquidator would
also service more senior liabilities first.
Furthermore, in the extremely unlikely case
that an operator would go out and purchase tCERs to meet its EU
ETS obligations in the face of bankruptcy, the obligation to replace
the tCERs would form part of the legal estate of the operator
and the outstanding liabilities that would have to be liquidated.
Consequently, the purchase of tCERs does not
change the liability situation or the treatment of a bankrupt
EU ETS operator in case of liquidation.
7. LULUCF MONITORING
TECHNOLOGIES AVAILABLE
DG Environment's Staff Working Document
Allegation
Current monitoring methodologies are still not
reliable enough to fully measure the actual net carbon capture
of LULUCF activities.
THE FACTS
"In the EU's view the IPCC guidance
for greenhouse gas estimation should be a basis for monitoring
emissions. The approaches to land identification developed by
IPCC allow for both ground-based and remote sensing methods. The
most cost effective combination depends on national circumstances
but in all cases it is very likely that both remote sensing and
ground-based data will be needed, and that there will always be
a requirement for an appropriate monitoring system".
(Submission of the European Union to the to the SBSTA) xxii
Concerns over measurement of carbon biomass
have been comprehensively addressed over the years following the
Seventh Conference of the Parties of the UNFCCC in Marrakech in
2001. Strong scientific and technical capabilities are now in
place for accurately assessing long-term gains and losses of bio-mass
carbon and other emissions from the forestry and land use sector.
Landholders and government agencies now measure and monitor forest
status and growth using a combination of techniques including
direct field measurements, satellite and aerial photography, and
computer modeling.
Many protocols for measuring and monitoring
carbon project benefits also exist. xxiii The Good Practice Guidance
for Land Use, Land-Use Change and Forestry ("GPG-LULUCF")xxiv
produced by the IPCC provides methods and guidance for estimating,
measuring, monitoring and reporting carbon stock changes and GHG
emissions. The GPG-LULUCF's guidance is consistent with that of
other sectors and can be used to quantify changes in GHG from
a diverse range of forestry and land-use management practices.
This guidance assists in measuring inventories for the sector
that neither "over" nor "under" estimate.
It supports the development of inventories that are transparent,
documented, consistent over time, complete, comparable, assessed
for uncertainties, subject to quality control and quality assurance,
and efficient in the use of resources.
The currently approved CDM A/R methodologies
have been developed, reviewed and approved by some of the leading
experts in the field of forest carbon accounting and monitoring
(see the UNFCCC's Roster of Experts, available from the Secretariat),
and are all based on the IPCC's GPG-LULUCF.
In stark contrast, the above Staff Working Document's
allegation is not based on any such references or credentials.
8. INTERDEPENDENCIES
IN ECOSYSTEMS
DG Environment's Staff Working Document
Allegation
Furthermore, interdependencies in ecosystems
are far from being fully understood, making it very difficult
to assess the actual change in GHG emissions. Whereas emissions
reductions in industry can be quantified by measuring input and
output values, ecosystems are inherently prone to leakage. They
are often referred to as flux rather than sinks.
THE FACTS
"Some methodological elements like baseline,
additionality, leakage and permanence have already been addressed
in the context of the Kyoto Protocol Clean Development Mechanism".
(Submission of the European Union to the SBSTA) xxv
The Staff Working Document's allegation shows
a clear misunderstanding of GHG quantification in the LULUCF sector.
Indeed, interdependencies in ecosystems are well studied and actual
changes in GHGs can be assessed.
First, carbon flux and sinks are distinct terms.
Carbon flux refers to "the transfer of carbon from one carbon
pool to another".xxvi Carbon sink is a carbon pool that,
during a given time interval, has more carbon flowing into it
than out of it. xxvii
Second, contrary to what the Staff Working Document
suggests, measurement uncertainties are very manageable in the
LULUCF sector. Measuring carbon pools is straightforward and scientists
have developed clear guidance and protocols for this (See the
IPCC's GPG-LULUCF). Furthermore, where uncertainties exist, all
methodologies require taking a conservative approach that favors
lower-end error margins and results so that projects are more
likely to be under-credited.
Third, the Staff Working Document's suggestion
that measurement uncertainties are equal to leakage is also incorrect.
Leakage is commonly defined as the emissions of GHGs not taken
into account because they occur outside of a project's accounting
boundary as a result of project activities. xxviii Such leakage
has often been raised as a major challenge associated with avoided
deforestation projects. However, methods are readily available
for avoiding leakage. These include providing economic opportunities
for local communities that encourage forest protection; providing
replacement products that are less carbon intensive, such as timber
from plantations rather than native forests, and improving the
productivity of agricultural lands. The Executive Board of the
CDM has now approved methodologies for the control and measurement
of leakage, and other practical methodologies have also been adopted
under various other standards. xxix
Real projects have also demonstrated that leakage
can be controlled and measured when it occurs. For example, the
Noel-Kempff Climate Action Project has demonstrated that active
management can reduce leakage, and that which cannot be eliminated
can be quantified and deducted from the project's total carbon
benefits. xxx Société Générale de
Surveillance ("SGS"), an internationally accredited
CO2 certifier and Designated Operational Entity of
the UNFCCC, validated the project design, and verified and certified
emission reductions for the project. xxxi
Finally, the Staff Working Document's suggestion
that non-forestry projects are not prone to leakage is also incorrect.
xxxii In fact, leakage is often overlooked in most non-forestry
CDM methodologies.
9. LULUCF AND
TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER
DG Environment's Staff Working Document
Allegation
Currently, the LULUCF sector is mainly driven
by voluntary emissions reductions, although a future increase
of their share in CDM and JI projects may become economically
attractive, as these projects can offer emissions reductions at
a low cost. [ . . .] LULUCF in CDM slows down technology transfer
and low-carbon technology development, as credits from forestry
and land use will be much more competitive on price and hence
crowd out other project types.
THE FACTS
"A substantial share of the overall
opportunities, including a large potential to reduce emissions
by protecting and replanting forests, lies in developing economies".
(McKinsey Quarterly) xxxiii
"To control climate change effectively
it will also be essential to halt tropical deforestation completely
within the next two decades and then reverse it through afforestation
or reforestation schemes. Deforestation currently contributes
around 20% of global greenhouse emissions, more than transport.
Discussions are taking place under the UN climate change convention
aimed at creating appropriate incentives for reducing deforestation".
(The European Commission) xxxiv
There is absolutely no evidence showing that
LULUCF in the CDM has slowed down technology transfer or the development
of low-carbon technology. On the contrary, inclusion of LULUCF
will allow the acceptance of stricter commitments, and therefore,
the achievement of climate stabilization goals. Without the inclusion
of LULUCF, however, climate stabilization simply cannot be achieved
at a reasonable cost. xxxv
It would be a mistake to exclude the forestry
sector simply because one favours other sectors. First, it cannot
be ignored that 20% of global anthropogenic GHG emissions are
from the LULUCF sector. Second, reducing the rate of emissions
does not reduce the concentrations of GHGs in the atmosphere,
but only the increase of those concentrations. The world is already
suffering the increasing impacts of climate change. A/R activities
are therefore essential to remove as much CO2 as possible
while mankind transitions to a low-carbon economy.
Climate research has shown that to avoid catastrophic
changes to the global climate and large-scale irreversible systemic
disruption, temperatures must not increase more than 2 degrees
Celsius above those in pre-industrial times. xxxvi There is a
medium likelihood of staying below this temperature increase if
GHGs are stabilized at a concentration around 450 ppm, xxxvii
but this would entail maximum cumulative emissions of around 2100
Gt CO2e between 2000 and 2100. xxxviii In turn, this
would require limiting emissions to 32 Gt CO2e/yr by
2030, xxxix a significant emission reduction in comparison with
the business as usual scenario.
Emission reductions of this scale require the
participation of the forestry sector. Offsets from the forestry
sector account for a larger share of potential reduction abatement
than any other sector, including potential reductions from the
power sector over that period. xl This was also proved by a McKinsey
study, which examined potential abatement scenarios for achieving
the necessary emission reductions at a cost below
40/tCO2e. xli
As the McKinsey report makes clear, assuming
a price of
40/tCO2e forestry accounts for 25% of
the additional reduction potential in emissions required to achieve
this target. It is clear that to achieve climate stabilisation
by mid-century requires both avoided deforestation and reforestation
(see Figure below). xlii Without the inclusion of forestry offsets,
achieving these emissions reductions targets at an acceptable
cost is impossible. In other words, the Staff policy makes it
impossible to achieve the EU's own key climate policy goal.
IPCC research has also demonstrated that the
potential of biological mitigation options is in the order of
100 GtC (cumulative) by 2050, equivalent to about 10 to 20% of
projected fossil fuel emission during that period. xliii The analysis,
however, also shows that emission reductions from the forestry
sector, while essential to achieving medium term abatement goals,
are also biologically constrained in their ability to mitigate
climate change beyond a certain point. xliv This, amongst other
considerations, should dispel fears that offsets from forestry
will "flood" the market and reduce incentives to technological
change. Forestry carbon credits and offsets are necessary but
are not, by any means, sufficient, to achieve climate stabilisation
goals. There is absolutely no reason to believe that they will
crowd out other projects. There is, however, significant evidence
that without them the cost of compliance will be so high as to
force the emigration of industrial plant and employment to countries
without binding emissions reductions commitments. xlv

Source: Vattenfall, 2007,
Global Mapping of Greenhouse Gas Abatement Opportunities up to
2030
10. THE ROLE
AND IMPACT
OF LULUCF IN
LEAST DEVELOPED
COUNTRIES
DG Environment's Staff Working Document
Allegation
Another issue is that EU ETS aims at long-term
emissions reductions in energy production and industry, the guideline
being to foster the development of a low-carbon economy. Currently,
the LULUCF sector is mainly driven by voluntary emissions reductions,
although a future increase of their share in CDM and JI projects
may become economically attractive, as these projects can offer
emissions reductions at a low cost. While LULUCF projects offer
a potential for the least-developed countries to benefit from
the carbon market and profit from formerly unpriced carbon sequestration
assets within forests and agriculture, they neither lead to technology
transfer nor to carbon-conscious economic practices, thus hindering
development towards a less carbon intensive economy by diverting
financial resources from more promising projects with long-term
benefits. LULUCF in CDM slows down technology transfer and low-carbon
technology development, as credits from forestry and land use
will be much more competitive on price and hence crowd out other
project types.
THE FACTS
Sustainable forestry promotes sustainable development
and technology transfer in least developed countries. In addition,
CDM A/R rules require project developers to follow carbon forestry
"best practices," which in turn require sustainable
development and provide for technology transfer.
Sustainable forestry's contribution to sustainable
development and technology transfer are well explained in the
positions taken by the IPCC and other bodies as explained below:
"No single policy instrument will ensure
the desired transition to a future secure and decarbonized world.
Policies will need to be regionally specific and both energy and
non-energy co-benefits should be taken into account".
(IPCC) xlvi
"Forestry can make a very significant
contribution to a low-cost global mitigation portfolio that provides
synergies with adaptation and sustainable development. However,
this opportunity is being lost in the current institutional context
and lack of political will to implement and has resulted in only
a small portion of this potential being realized at present".
(IPCC) xlvii
"Forests and trees cover nearly one
third of the Earth's surface. Sustainable forest management of
both natural and planted forests and for timber and non-timber
products is essential to achieving sustainable development as
well as a critical means to eradicate poverty, significantly reduce
deforestation, halt the loss of forest biodiversity and land and
resource degradation and improve food security and access to safe
drinking water and affordable energy; in addition, it highlights
the multiple benefits of both natural and planted forests and
trees and contributes to the well-being of the planet and humanity".
(World Summit on Sustainable Development of Johannesburg ) xlviii
"Technology deployment, diffusion and
transfer in the forestry sector provide a significant opportunity
to help mitigate climate change and adapt to potential changes
in the climate. Apart from reducing GHG emissions or enhancing
the carbon sinks, technology transfer strategies in the forest
sector have the potential to provide tangible socio-economic and
local and global environmental benefits, contributing to sustainable
development (IPCC, 2000b). Especially, technologies for improving
productivity, sustainable forest management, monitoring, and verification
are required in developing countries. However, existing financial
and institutional mechanism, information and technical capacity
are inadequate. Thus, new policies, measures and institutions
are required to promote technology transfer in the forest sector".
(IPCC) xlix
"R&D and technology transfer have
a potential to promote forest sector mitigation options by increasing
sustainable productivity, conserving biodiversity and enhancing
profitability. Technologies are available for promoting mitigation
options from national level to forest stand level, and from single
forest practices to broader socio-economic approaches".
(IPCC)l
"The development of suitable low-cost
technologies will be necessary for promoting thinning and mitigation
options. Moreover, technology will have to be developed for making
effective use of small wood, including thinned timber, in forest
products and markets. Thinning and tree pruning for fuelwood and
fodder are regularly conducted in many developing countries as
part of local integrated forest management strategies".
(IPCC) li
"Globally, hundreds of millions of households
depend on goods and services provided by forests. This underlines
the importance of assessing forest sector activities aimed at
mitigating climate change in the broader context of sustainable
development and community impact. Forestry mitigation activities
can be designed to be compatible with adapting to climate change,
maintaining biodiversity, and promoting sustainable development.
Comparing environmental and social co-benefits and costs with
the carbon benefit will highlight tradeoffs and synergies, and
help promote sustainable development". (IPCC) lii
"LULUCF activities can reduce dependence
on fossil fuels primarily by providing a source of biomass that
can be used as a renewable alternative to fossil fuels in generating
energy and by supplying wood products that can substitute for
other products requiring more energy to produce. Fossil fuel substitution
will generally require investments in technology and infrastructure
to enable the adoption of biofuels and less carbon-intensive products
and processes". (IPCC) liii
"Savings in the emission of GHGs can
also be achieved through material substitution. Typical building
materials-such as steel, plastics and aluminum-have large energy
requirements for mining, processing, smelting, and, with some
materials, reduction of oxidized ore. These energy requirements
lead to corresponding CO2 emissions. Cement production
also leads to additional direct CO2 release during
manufacturing. Wood leads to the lowest emissions because it requires
only minor energy inputs in harvesting and sawing. Hence, any
substitution of wood for other materials could reduce energy requirements
and associated GHG emissions (Kirschbaum, 2000). Moreover, the
production of metals and plastics generates higher volumes of
air, water, and solid waste pollutants than wood products such
as lumber-particularly so with toxic chemicals (USEPA, 1997)
". (IPCC) liv
"Carbon forestry and agriculture are
the only meaningful methods of offering sustainable livelihoods
to the rural poor and the only way they can participate and benefit
from the carbon market". (Wangari Maathai) lv
An analysis of the potential to increase carbon
stocks in the Kakamega National Forest of western Kenya concluded
that: "The East African indigenous rainforest found in
Kakamega supports high levels of biodiversity and provides sundry
ecosystem services to Western Kenya. In addition, as a high carbon
density land cover type, it can provide a global service as carbon
store helping to mitigate climate change. While past human disturbances
have reduced forest areas and depressed forest carbon densities,
the results of this illustrates the potential to increase carbon
storage in the Kakamega National Forest at a scale that is economically,
and perhaps ecologically, significant for the region".lvi
11. LULUCF PROJECTS
AND OTHER
MORE COSTLY
MEASURES
DG Environment's Staff Working Document
Allegation
The risk of LULUCF projects crowding out more
costly measures, such as projects aiming at CO2 emissions
reductions (especially in the case of Option 3.15) is considerable,
taking into consideration that EU ETS is the most dominant buyer
of CDM CERs at 86% market share in 2006 (ENTEC 2007b). Thus, the
use tCERs and lCERs for compliance in the ETS would conflict with
creating sustainable emissions reductions.
THE FACTS
As of 17 January 2008, the CDM Executive Board
has approved only one CDM A/R project. lvii This project is forecast
to generate only 327,000 tonnes CO2e of emission reductions
over the first commitment period, lviii or just 0.27% of the amount
allowed under the Marrakech Accords. In fact, it is expected that
all CDM A/R projects combined will generate only between 7 and
14 million tCO2e reductions in the first commitment
period (2.8 million tonnes CO2e per year), lix or about
1% of the total predicted CER market of a billion tonnes. lx
In contrast, the average daily trading volume
in the EU ETS in 2007 was over 6.0 million tonnes CO2e.
lxi Therefore, at the high end of forecasts for credits from A/R
(2.8 million tCO2e), annual reductions from A/R would
be less than one half of the average daily trading volume in the
EU ETS or less than one half of one percent of the annual EU ETS
trading volume. Thus, the volumes of forestry credits in the trading
markets are currently negligible compared to the sector's contribution
to 20% of global greenhouse gas emissions.
12. PRACTICAL
IMPLEMENTATION OF
LULUCF PROJECTS
DG Environment's Staff Working Document
Allegation
Lastly, some issues relate to the practical
implementation of LULUCF projects. The potential use of non-native
or genetically modified species that are faster growing could
pose threats to local ecosystems. Furthermore, there are concerns
that indigenous or local populations could be denied access to
their traditional resource lands or access to subsistence-use
logging due to LULUCF projects.
THE FACTS
"We need a mechanism that will assist
people in developing countries, certainly in Africa, to protect
their standing forests and plant trees, to protect their soil,
protect biodiversity and protect livelihoods while reducing carbon
emissions for everyone". (Wangari Maathai) lxii
The CDM rules require project developers to
document and analyze environmental impacts associated with a project
(all projects including A/R). Furthermore, project developers
must also undertake a detailed environmental impact assessment
if the environmental impacts are considered significant. The CDM
rules also requires stakeholder consultations. lxiii
All of the leading voluntary sector codes, including
the Voluntary Carbon Standard and the Climate, Community and Biodiversity
Standards also require the assessment of environmental and social
impacts before credits are certified. lxiv
Potential corporate social responsibility ("CSR")
issues may apply to any CDM or JI project and not only to LULUCF
activities. These concerns are not a reason to exclude any sector
from the EU ETS, and should be addressed by taking the appropriate
care in the project design, as is the case with LULUCF projects.
Furthermore, the overwhelming majority of indigenous
people organizations supports forest-based carbon crediting. There
are clear and simple reasons for this. Carbon crediting is based
on verifiable land title and verifiable reduction in forest deforestation
and degradation, and this will serve to enhance indigenous peoples'
title to land and also provide them with direct benefits to reward
them for preserving the ecosystems on which they depend. lxv
13. THE COMMISSION'S
APPROACH TO
ADDRESS DEFORESTATION
DG Environment's Staff Working Document
Allegation
It is clear that very substantial action needs
to be taken to address deforestation in the coming decades, and
auction revenues could contribute towards such action. The Commission
has also proposed that proceeds from the auctioning of allowances
within the EU ETS be used to mitigate greenhouse gas emissions,
in particular to fund measures to avoid deforestation. Investments
made in this way would be in line with government's priorities,
rather than necessarily reflecting the market's natural incentive
to find the lowest-cost potential for crediting.
THE FACTS
As mentioned above, the scale of funding needed
to reduce and halt deforestation is estimated in the tens of billions
of Euros. lxvi It is inconceivableand disingenuous to suggestthat
this level of funding would be earmarked for avoided deforestation
measures from auction proceeds not least because of competing
demands for these funds.
14. ADDITIONALITY
AND DOUBLE
COUNTING OF
LULUCF PROJECTS
DG Environment's Staff Working Document
Allegation
The additionality and double-counting of projects
is a serious issue which can undermine the environmental credibility
of emissions trading systems. As broader initiatives advance to
tackle deforestation, the likelihood of potential double counting
and lack of additionality increases as regards the crediting of
project activities in this area.
THE FACTS
The CDM itself is such a "broader initiative."
The CDM process requires every project to demonstrate additionality
through its "Additionality Tool," both for projects
in the industrial sector and the LULUCF sector. lxvii This tool
could also be extended to REDD projects.
Double-counting is a registry issue. The EU
has addressed this issue in the EU ETS through its national registries'
interaction with the International Transaction Log. A similar
system could be designed for credits from REDD projects.
15. MONITORING
UNDER THE
EU ETS
DG Environment's Staff Working Document
Allegation
Allowing already existing CDM credits from LULUCF
in the ETS (Option 3.16) adds an additional monitoring burden
on the EU and the ETS, although monitoring is already covered
by existing UN CDM regulation. The main problem is that UN CDM
targets state-level trade of tCERs, whereas the EU ETS aims at
firms. Thus, while the ultimate liability would lie at the Member
State level, the benefits would accrue to firms. Such a situation
represents an indirect subsidy of LULUCF developers, as they would
receive all benefits, while a share of the liability risk would
be borne by the public.
THE FACTS
The project developer of LULUCF projects bears
the costs of monitoring just as with any other project developer.
This does not represent a subsidy.
Moreover, the EU already needs to monitor compliance
of operators under the EU ETS. This is because the EU ETS itself
is designed to transfer the liability of governments' Kyoto commitments
to private operators. In the case LULUCF credits, their expiration
would simply result in a debiting of the account of the holder
of the LULUCF credits. The EU ETS' penalties and enforcement rules,
however, ensure that liability always stays with private operators,
and this would not be different in the case of LULUCF credits.
16. LULUCF DOMESTIC
OFFSET PROJECTS
DG Environment's Staff Working Document
Allegation
Allowing domestic offset projects ("DOPs")
from LULUCF could be based on adopting existing monitoring guidelines
for CDM projects. However, as the existing guidelines prove to
be insufficiently satisfactory compared to EU standards, further
development is needed before credits generated from LULUCF DOPs
can be used for compliance in the EU ETS.
THE FACTS
The EU is free to impose stricter standards
than the CDM. The project developer can make the decision whether
or not invest in a project.
17. MONITORABILITY
OF LULUCF
DG Environment's Staff Working Document
Allegation
Including the forestry sector in the ETS (Option
3.18) poses major questions concerning the monitorability of all
forests included in the trading system. This would mean that a
large number of forest owners would need to report and verify
the change of the carbon content of their forests. The costs for
monitoring would have to be covered by all the participating forest
owners. Proportionally, the monitoring costs would be higher for
smaller forest parcels.
THE FACTS
The EU ETS currently covers around 12,000 installations,
lxviii all of which require monitoring. To limit monitoring and
compliance costs, the EU ETS excludes installations that do not
meet specified thresholds (eg, in terms of minimum power generation).
Similar criteria could be designed for the forestry sector by
including in the EU ETS only forests meeting certain thresholds
(eg, in terms of land area). This approach, like that in the industrial
sectors, would limit the amount of forestry "installations"
covered by the scheme.
In addition, EU countries already engage in
monitoring land use change in their calculations of national inventories
for reporting to the UNFCCC. In fact, the land use sector is projected
to account for about 12% of the reductions needed for the EU 15
to reach its Kyoto targets. lxix
As for monitoring costs being greater for smaller
forest parcels, economies of scale apply to the forest sector
like any other industry.
18. FUTURE INTERNATIONAL
TREATMENT OF
LULUCF
DG Environment's Staff Working Document
Allegation
Uncertainties are high concerning the future
treatment of LULUCF on the international level. Currently, the
use of LULUCF credits for compliance with Kyoto targets is only
acceptable in the first Kyoto period. Therefore, a recognition
of LULUCF in the ETS now would increase the uncertainties about
future supply. This contradicts one of the main objectives of
the ETS: predictability of carbon credit supply. Any solution
to this problem is likely to incur considerable higher costs compared
to the current situation.
THE FACTS
In terms of the Kyoto Protocol, there is, at
present, only one commitment period for all Kyoto credits as the
Protocol's trading periods ends in 2012. Therefore, future supply
of credits is equally uncertain among all sectors, not specifically
for LULUCF.
However, one of the main results of the UNFCCC
COP 13 at Bali is the consensus on the increasing importance and
certainty of LULUCF, lxx particularly in relation to reducing
emissions from deforestation and forest degradation ("REDD").
A cap and trade system functions through the
demand being set by the cap, and the market responding to the
cap to meet the targets. One of the consequences of this arrangement
is an inherent uncertainty of supply. This is best illustrated
in the EU ETS by the number and volume of HFC-23 projects, particularly
from China which accounted for 61% of the volume transacted in
the CDM market in 2006, of which HFC-23 projects contributed 34%
(down from 67% in 2005). lxxi
REFERENCES
i IPCC Fourth Assessment Report 2007: Mitigation
of Climate Change. Available on the Internet at (http://www.ipcc.ch/pdf/assessment-report/ar4/wg3/ar4-wg3-chapter9.pdf);
S Stern N. (2006), Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change,
published on the Internet at (http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/independent_reviews/stern_review_economic_climate_change/stern_review_report.cfm);
"A Cost Curve for Greenhouse Gas Reduction", The
McKinsey Quarterly (February 2007).
ii Communication from the Commission to the Council
and the European Parliament, Building a Global Climate Change
Alliance between the European Union and Poor Developing Countries
Most Vulnerable to Climate Change (September 2007).
iii "Reducing emissions from deforestation
in developing countries: approaches to stimulate action, draft
conclusions proposed by the Chair", COP 13, FCCC/SBSTA/2007/L.23/Add.1/12
December 2007 Rev.1. Available on the Internet at (http://unfccc.int/documentation/decisions/items/3597.php).
See Forests Now Declaration, available on the internet at (http://www.forestsnow.org/).
iv Hancock Timberland Investor, 2nd Quarter
2003, "Risk from natural hazards for timberland investments",
published on the Internet at (http://www.htrg.com/researchlib).
v IPCC, Land use, land-use change, and forestry:
a special report of the IPCC (Cambridge & New York: Cambridge
University Press, 2000).
vi Hancock Timberland Investor, 2nd Quarter
2003, "Risk from natural hazards for timberland investments",
published on the Internet at (http://www.htrg.com/researchlib).
vii Norby, R J et al, (2005) "Forest response
to elevated CO2 is conserved across a broad range of
productivity", Proceedings of the National Academy of
Sciences 102.
viii Woods Hole Research Centre, available on
the Internet at (http://www.whrc.org/carbon/missingc.htm).
ix Norby, R J et al, (2005) "Forest response
to elevated CO2 is conserved across a broad range of
productivity" Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences
102: 10.
x Woods Hole Research Centre, available on the
Internet at (http://www.whrc.org/carbon/missingc.htm).
xi Stern N (2006), Stern Review: The Economics
of Climate Change, published on the Internet at
(http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/independent_reviews/stern_review_economics_climate_change/stern_review_report.cfm).
xii Bali Action Plan, published on the Internet
at (http://unfccc.int/documentation/decisions/items/3597.php)
xii http://ji.unfccc.int/index.html).
xiii (http://ji.unfccc.int/index.html).
xiv (http://unfccc.int/cop9/latest/sbstal27.pdf).
xv Submission by Germany on Behalf of the European
Union to SBSTA, Views on issues related to further steps under
the Convention related to reducing emissions from deforestation
in developing countries: approaches to stimulate action (February
2007), available on the Internet at
(http://unfccc.int/resource/docs/2007/sbsta/eng/misc02.pdf).
xvi Frelish, (2002) "Forest Dynamics and
Disturbance Regimes", Cambridge Studies in Ecology.
xvii See (http://cdm.unfccc.int/methodologies/ARmethodologies/approvedar.html).
xviii See New South Wales Greenhouse Gas Abatement
Scheme, "Greenhouse Gas Benchmark (Carbon Sequestration)
Rule No 5 of 2003.
xix "The Framework for a New Zealand Emissions
Trading Scheme," Ministry for the Environment and the Treasury,
September 2007.
xx "Voluntary Carbon StandardGuidance
for Agriculture, Forestry and Other Land Use Projects".
xxi See (http://www.chicagoclimateexchange.com/)
and (http://www.maf.govt.nz/forestry/pfsi/).
xxii Submission by Germany on Behalf of the European
Union to SBSTA, Views on issues related to further steps under
the Convention related to reducing emissions from deforestation
in developing countries: approaches to stimulate action (February
2007), published on the Internet at
(http://unfccc.int/resource/docs/2007/sbsta/eng/misc0,.pdf).
xxiii Brown, S, O Maseru, J Sathaye (2000) "Project-based
activities" in R Watson, I Noble, and D Verardo (Eds), Land
Use, Land-Use Change and Forestry; "Special Report to the
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change", (Cambridge
and New Your: Cambridge University Press), Chapter 5; See also
The Revised 1996 IPCC Guideline for National Greenhouse Gas Inventories;
and MacDicken (1997) "A guide to monitoring carbon storage
in forestry and agroforestry projects". (Winrock International
Institute for Agricultural Development).
xxiv IPCC, (2003) Good Practice Guidance for
Land Use, Land-Use Change and Forestry, published on the Internet
at (http://www.ipcc-nggip.iges.or.jp/public/gpglulucf/gpglulucf.htm).
xxv Submission by Portugal on Behalf of the European
Union to SBSTA, December 2007, Views on issues related to further
steps under the Convention related to reducing emissions from
deforestation in developing countries: approaches to stimulate
action, published on the Internet at
(http://unfccc.int/methodsandscience/lulucf/items/3896.php).
xxvi Canadian Forest Service, available on the
Internet at (http://carbon.cfs.nrcan.gc.ca/definitions_e.html).
xxvii Canadian Forest Service, available on the
Internet at (http://carbon.cfs.nrcan.gc.ca/definitions_e.html).
xxviii (http://www.epa.gov/sequestration/leakage.html).
xxix For CDM approved methods See (http://cdm.unfccc.int/methodologies/ARmethodologies/approvedar.html).
For details of forestry carbon under the Chicago Climate Exchange,
See (http://www.chicagoclimatex.com/content.jsf?id=242).
xxx (http://www.fan-bo.org/pacuk).
xxxi SGS, Summary, Validation and Verification
Report, Programa Nacional de Cambio Climatico Noel Kempff Climate
Action Project (27 November 2005).
xxxii Chomitz, K (1999) "Evaluating carbon
offsets from forestry and energy projects: how do they compare?"
World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No 2357.
xxxiii "Cost Curve for Greenhouse Gas Reduction",
The McKinsey Quarterly, (February 2007).
xxxiv European Commission, Limiting Global
Climate Change to 2 Degree Celsius (January 2007), published
on the Internet at (http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=MEMO/07/16).
xxxv "A Cost Curve for Greenhouse Gas Reduction",
The McKinsey Quarterly (February 2007).
xxxvi European Commission Communication to the
Council and the European Parliament Limiting Global Climate
Change to 2 degrees Celsius: The way ahead for 2020 and beyond
(January 2007); Stern, N (2006) Stern Review: The Economics
of Climate Change; Meinshausen Malte "On the Risk of
Overshooting 2 degreesC" Proceedings from International
Symposium on Stabilisation of Greenhouse Gas ConcentrationsAvoiding
Dangerous Climate Change, (Exeter, 1-3 February 2005), published
on the Internet at (www.stabilisation2005.com/programme.html).
xxxvii IPCC (2001) The Scientific Basis (Cambridge
University Press); Meinshausen, Malte "On the Risk of Overshooting
2 degrees C" Proceedings from International Symposium
on Stabilisation of Greenhouse Gas ConcentrationsAvoiding
Dangerous Climate Change (Exeter, 1-3 February 2005), published
on the Internet at (www.stabilisation2005.com/programme.html).
xxxviii Stern, N, (2006) Stern Review: The
Economics of Climate Change.
xxxix "A Cost Curve for Greenhouse Gas Reduction",
The McKinsey Quarterly, (February 2007).
xl Ibid.
xli Ibid.
xlii Vattenfall, (2007) Global Mapping of
Greenhouse Gas Abatement Opportunities up to 2030.
xliii IPCC, 2001, Climate Change 2001: Mitigation,
Cambridge University Press.
xliv Ibid.
xlv "Emissions Target Threat to EU Industry",
Financial Times, 9 January 2007.
xlvi Page 255 of the IPCC Fourth Assessment
Report 2007: Mitigation of Climate Change. Available on the
Internet at (http://www.ipcc.ch/pdf/assessment-report/ar4/wg3/ar4-wg3-chapter4.pdf).
xlvii Page 543 of the IPCC Fourth Assessment
Report 2007: Mitigation of Climate Change. Available on the
Internet at (http://www.ipcc.ch/pdf/assessment-report/ar4/wg3/ar4-wg3-chapter9.pdf).
xlviii Paragraph 45 of the Plan of Implementation
of the World Summit on Sustainable Development of Johannesburg
of 2002. Available on the Internet at
(http://www.un.org/esa/sustdev/documents/WSSD_POI_PD/English/WSSD_PlanImpl.pdf).
xlix Page 577 of the IPCC Fourth Assessment
Report 2007: Mitigation of Climate Change. Available on the
Internet at (http://www.ipcc.ch/pdf/assessment-report/ar4/wg3/ar4-wg3-chapter9.pdf).
l Page 576 of the IPCC Fourth Assessment Report
2007: Mitigation of Climate Change. Available on the Internet
at (http://www.ipcc.ch/pdf/assessment-report/ar4/wg3/ar4-wg3-chapter9.pdf).
li Page 576 of the IPCC Fourth Assessment
Report 2007: Mitigation of Climate Change. Available on the
Internet at (http://www.ipcc.ch/pdf/assessment-report/ar4/wg3/ar4-wg3-chapter9.pdf).
lii Page 543 of the IPCC Fourth Assessment
Report 2007: Mitigation of Climate Change. Available on the
Internet at (http://www.ipcc.ch/pdf/assessment-report/ar4/wg3/ar4-wg3-chapter9.pdf).
liii Robert T Watson et al (Eds), Land Use,
Land-Use Change And Forestry: A Special Report of the IPCC (Cambridge
University Press: 2000). Available on the Internet at (http://www.grida.no/climate/ipcc/land_use/096.htm).
liv Robert T Watson et al (Eds), Land Use,
Land-Use Change And Forestry: A Special Report of the IPCC (Cambridge
University Press: 2000). Available on the Internet at (http://www.grida.no/climate/ipcc/land_use/101.htm).
lv Wangari Maathai, Climate Change A Pressing
Issue for Africa (13 November 2006).
lvi Julia Glenday, (2006) "Carbon Storage
and Emissions Offset Potential in an East African Tropical Rainforest",
Forest Ecology and Management 235 72-83, page 81. Available
on the Internet at (www.sciencedirect.com).
lvii See (http://cdm.unfccc.int/Statistics/Registration/RegisteredProjByScopePieChart.html).
lviii Project Design Document: "Facilitating
Reforestation for Guangxi Watershed Management in Pearl River
Basin, China".
lix Jung, Martina, (2003) The Role of Forestry
Sinks in the CDMAnalysing the Effects of Policy Decisions
on the Carbon Market (Hamburg Institute of International Economics).
lx (http://cdm.unfccc.int/Statistics/index.html)
lxi See Point Carbon, Global Carbon
Market Value Grew 80% to 40 billion in 2007 (18 January 2008).
There are 252 trading days per year.
lxii Wangari Maathai, Nobel Peace Prize Laureate
and Founder of the Green Belt Movement, published on the Internet
at
(http://www.forestsnow.org/news/pdf/ForestsNow-Declaration-PressRelease-26Oct07.pdf)
lxiii See (http://cdm.unfccc.int/Reference/Documents/cdmpdd/English/CDM_PDD.pdf).
lxiv Voluntary Carbon StandardGuidance
for Agriculture, Forestry and Other Land Use Projects (17
November 2007); and The Climate, Community & Biodiversity
Alliance Standards, published on the Internet at (http://www.climate-standards.org/).
lxv See The Forest Now Declaration, published
on the Internet at (http://www.forestsnow.org/endorsers/?filter=NGO+and+Research+Institutes).
The Declaration has been signed by over 300 high-level endorsers,
including Association of Indigenous Organisations of the Brazilian
Amazon (COIAB), the Governors of Aceh, Indonesia, Papua, Indonesia,
and Amazonas, Brazil, and President Oscar Arias of Costa Rica.
lxvi op cit. Stern.
lxvii See Tool for the demonstration and assessment
of additionality for afforestation and reforestation CDM project
activities, published on the Internet at (http://cdm.unfccc.int/methodologies/ARmethodologies/approved_ar.html).
lxvii (http://ec.europa.eu/environment/ets/).
lxviii http://ec.europa.eu/environment/ets/).
lxix See Climate change: EU on track towards
Kyoto target but efforts must be maintained, projections show,
published on the Internet at (http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=IP/07/1774&format=HTML&aged=0%3Cuage=EN&guiLanguage=en).
lxx See Decision -/CP.13 Reducing emissions
from deforestation in developing countries: approaches to stimulate
action.
lxxi The World Bank, State and Trends of the
Carbon Market 2007.
1 See Decisions COP 13, "Bali Action Plan,"
and "Reducing emissions from deforestation in developing
countries: approaches to stimulate action". Back
2
See http://cdm.unfccc.int/Statistics/index.html, passim. Back
3
op cit. Decisions COP 13. Back
4
http://www.rainforestcoalition.org/eng/ Back
5
Point Carbon, Global carbon market value grew 80% to 40 billion
in 2007 (18 January 2008). Back
6
See Commission for the European Communities, "Proposal for
a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council amending
Directive 2003/87/EC so as to improve and extend the greenhouse
gas emission allowance trading system of the Community",
23 January 2008. Back
7
Attached as Schedule 1 is a rebuttal to the DG Environment's various
rationales for the ban's continuance. Back
8
See Official Journal of the European Union, "Directive 2004/101/EC
of The European Parliament and of The Council of 27 October 2004
amending Directive 2003/87/EC establishing a scheme for greenhouse
gas emission allowance trading within the Community, in respect
of the Kyoto Protocol's project mechanisms". Back
9
op cit. Commission for the European Communities, 23 January
2008. Back
10
See "France, Germany Warn EU Climate Plan Risks Jobs",
at http://www.planetark.org/dailynewsstory.cfm?newsid=47167 Back
11
EU split over plan to levy import tax on polluters, 8 January
2008. www.timesonline.co.uk Back
12
See, "Fortis Raises CO2 Forecast, Prices Surge",
at http://www.reuters.com/article/rbssFinancialServicesAndRealEstateNews/idUSL2564255920080125 Back
13
A key difference is that Mckinsey uses the price as a marginal
cost whereas the EU Commission sees it as a base from which prices
are intended to be manipulated upwards. (cites). Back
14
McKinsey & Company, "A Cost Curve for Greenhouse Gas
Reductions" The McKinsey Quarterly, Volume 1 (2007). Back
15
op cit. Commission for the European Communities. Back
16
See "Trade in Agcert shares suspected, company seeks government
protection," Point Carbon 21, February 2008. Back
17
op cit. Commission for the European Communities. Back
18
See "UK PM calls for European bank to allocate EUAs post-2012",
Point Carbon, 21 February 2008 and "Carbon market control
should be taken off UN hands, legislators say", Point Carbon,
25 February 2008. Back
19
See written and oral submissions to this Committee by SFM on voluntary
markets: http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm200607/cmselect/cmenvaud/331/33102.htm Back
20
Even in respect to CERs, which must cross a multitude of hurdles
before approval, DEFRA imposes a further layer of regulation prior
to distribution to the UK public. See "Draft Code of Best
Practice for Carbon Offset Providers Accreditation requirements
and procedures-February 2008," at www.defra.gov.uk Back
21
Summary of responses to the consultation on establishing a Code
of Best Practice for selling offsetting to consumers http://www.defra.gov.uk/environment/climatechange/uk/carbonoffset/pdf/cop-summary-responses.pdf Back
22
By way of comparison, pending US Federal legislation proposes
to limit carbon prices at US$12 per tonne (Bingaman-Specter, Low
Carbon Economy Act, available at www.pewclimate.org) and prices
for the Australian system are projected at up to A$20 per tonne. Back
23
Council of the European Union, EcoFin 33, Env 51, "Report
on the efficiency of economic instruments for energy and climate
Change", Brussels, 5 February 2008. Back
24
See NYMEX Green Exchange http://www.greenfutures.com/ Back
25
See "Carbon market control should be taken off UN hands,
legislators say," Point Carbon, 25 February 2008. Back
26
Stern, N, 2006, Stern Review: The Economics of Climate and Nepstad
et al, 2007, The costs and benefits of reducing carbon emissions
from deforestation and forest degradation in the Brazilian Amazon. Back
27
Stern, N, 2006, Stern Review: The Economics of Climate. Back
28
Castro, G and I Locker. 2000. Mapping Conservation Investments:
An Assessment of Biodiversity Funding in Latin America and the
Caribbean. Washington, D.C.: Biodiversity Support Program. Back
29
Chomitz, K, 2007, At Loggerheads? Agricultural Expansion, Poverty
Reduction and Environment in the Tropical Forests, The World Bank. Back
30
op cit. Chomitz. Back
31
UNFCCC. 2005/CP/L2, "Reducing Emissions from Deforestation
in Developing Countries: Approaches To Stimulate Action".
6 December 2005. Back
32
See "Decision -/CP.13 Reducing emissions from deforestation
in developing countries: approaches to stimulate action". Back
33
See "Decision -/CP.13 Reducing emissions from deforestation
in developing countries: approaches to stimulate action". Back
34
Bali Action Plan http://unfccc.int/documentation/decisions/items/3597.php Back
35
Point Carbon, "Japan to make forest management a priority
at next G8 summit", 21 February 2008. Back
36
Adaptation to climate change in agriculture, forestry and fisheries:
perspective, framework and priorities, FAO, Rome, 2007. Back
37
http://www.rainforestcoalition.org/eng/ Back
38
Stilts, Joseph, "Cleaning Up Economic Growth", Project
Syndicate, 2005. Back
39
See Wetlands International: http://www.wetlands.org/ckpp/publication.aspx?ID=1f64f9b5-debc-43f5-8c79-
b1280f0d4b9a Back
40
Decision -/CP.13 Bali Action Plan. Back
41
Second workshop on reducing emissions from deforestation in developing
countries, Cairns, Australia. 7-9 March 2007. Preliminary Chairs'
summary. Back
42
DeFries, R, 2002, Carbon Emissions from tropical deforestation
and regrowth based on satellite observations for the 1980s and
1990s, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the
United States of America, Vol 99, No 22 p 14256-14261. Back
43
Herold, M et al, 2006. Report of the workshop on Monitoring Tropical
Deforestation for Compensated Reductions, GOFC-GOLD Symposium
on Forest and Land Cover Observations, Jena, Germany, 21-22 March
2006, GOFC-Gold report series, http://www.fao.org/gtos/gofc-gold/series.html Back
44
INPE. 2005. Monitoramento da Floresta Amazonia Brasileira por
Satelite, Projeto PRODES. Back
45
Forest Survey of India. 2004. State of Forest Report 2003. Dehra
Dun, India. Back
46
DeFries, R, et al, 2005, Monitoring tropical deforestation for
emerging carbon markets, Tropical Deforestation and Climate Change/
edited by Paulo Moutinho and Stephan Schwartzman, IPAM and Environmental
Defense. Back
47
Penman, J et al, 2003, Good Practice Guidance for Land Use, Land-Use
Change and Forestry. IPCC National Greenhouse Gas Inventories
Programme and Institute for Global Environmental Strategies, Kanagawa,
Japan. Back
48
Second workshop on reducing emissions from deforestation in developing
countries, Cairns, Australia. 7-9 March 2007. Preliminary Chairs'
summary. Back
49
FAO. 2006. Global Forest Resources Assessment 2000. FAO Forestry
paper 147. Food and Agriculture Organization of the UN, Rome. Back
50
Chicago Climate Exchange (CCX) http://www.chicagoclimateexchange.com/,
NYMEX http://www.greenfutures.com/, Climate, Community and Biodiversity
Appliance, CCBA: http://www.climate-standards.org/, Voluntary
Carbon Standard: VCS: http://www.v-c-s.org Back
51
Convention (No 169) concerning Indigenous and Tribal Peoples in
Independent Countries http://www.unhchr.ch/html/menu3/b/62.htm Back
52
Asner et al, 2005, Selective logging in the Brazilian Amazon.
Science 310: 480-482. Back
53
Asner et al, 2005, Selective logging in the Brazilian Amazon.
Science 310: 480-482. Back
54
See COP7, Decision 11, "Land use, land-use change and forestry". Back
55
See COP9, Decision 19, "Modalities and procedures for afforestation
and reforestation project activities under the clean development
mechanism in the first commitment period of the Kyoto Protocol". Back
56
See http://cdm.unfccc.int/Statistics/index.html Back
57
See http://carbonfinance.org/Router.cfm?Page=BioCF&ft=Projects Back
58
See http://ji.unfccc.int/JI-Projects/ProjectInfo.html Back
59
Global Environment Outlook, The United Nations Environment Programme
in 2007 Back
60
See Marrakech Accords Decisions, COP 7 of the UNFCCC, Decision
11/CP.7IPCC, 2000, Special Report of the Intergovernmental Panel
on Climate Change: Land Use, Land-Use Change and Forestry, Cambridge
University Press. Back
61
See National Carbon Accounting System, Australia http://www.greenhouse.gov.au/ncas/ Back
62
See Forest Carbon Partnership Facility http://carbonfinance.org/Router.cfm?Page=FCPF&FID=34267&ItemID=34267&ft=About Back
63
op cit. Commission for the European Communities. Back
64
op cit. Trade in Agcert Shares. Back
65
See UNEP Riso Centre at http://cdmpipeline.org/ Back
66
IPCC, Land use, land-use change, and forestry: a special report
of the IPCC. (Cambridge & New York. Cambridge University Press,
2000). Back
67
Swingland, I, 2002, Capturing Carbon and Conserving Biodiversity:
The Market Approach, The Royal Society. Back
68
European Commission Communication "Limiting Global Climate
Change to 2 Celsius: The way ahead for 2020 and beyond".
Stern, N, 2006, Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change,
Meinshausen, Malte. "On the Risk of Overshooting 2C".
Proceedings from International Symposium on Stabilisation of
Greenhouse Gas Concentrations-Avoiding Dangerous Climate Change,
Exeter, 1-3 February 2005 at www.stabilisation2005.com/programme.html Back
69
Stern, N, 2006, Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change. Back
70
Adaptation to climate change in agriculture, forestry and fisheries:
perspective, framework and priorities, FAO, Rome, 2007. Back
71
Global Environment Outlook, The United Nations Environment Programme
in 2007. Back
|