Select Committee on Environmental Audit Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 201-219)

PROFESSOR PAUL EKINS

24 JULY 2007


  Q201 Chairman: Good morning and welcome back. What potential do you think there is for personal carbon trading?

  Professor Ekins: It depends what you mean by "potential". Clearly in theory it can limit the carbon emissions from the household sector in those areas of activity for which it is defined. We have some experience now with cap and trade systems. This is a cap and trade system for that particular sector in the personal carbon allowance sense of the term rather than the DGQ[5] one. Therefore, the theoretical potential is established. There is the feasibility potential about whether you could do it and that seems to me also to be well established. It is clearly something we could do if we wanted to. The interesting question which you have already been exploring in some detail is: is it a formulation of the problem that the public would be likely to accept? Might there be other, better ways of trying to achieve the same objectives?

  Q202 Chairman: I guess most, if not all, of us on this Committee think that the issue of reducing emissions is far more urgent than any of the current policy instruments is anywhere near achieving. We are facing a global crisis of momentous proportions and therefore urgent progress in cutting emissions is the overriding need. Comparing PCT with much higher green taxation, where are the merits in the short term? Which is going to be likely to be most effective?

  Professor Ekins: I do not think either of them are politically acceptable at the moment. It is not politically acceptable to impose policies that will cause people to reduce their emissions. That is the baseline where we unfortunately are. With you, Chairman, I agree that that is not where I would like to be. I would like to be somewhere else. We know that environmental taxes are not popular. On the other hand, carbon allowances are rationing and it would not be long before it was being referred to in the popular press as rationing carbon and therefore energy use. I suspect that is not likely to be popular either. Once it starts being talked about in those terms, especially politically, if it is tied to the very large, redistributional effects that equal per capita allowances of carbon emissions would entail. You introduce the concept of rationing. Everyone looks back with horror at the experience of the Second World War and says, "Oh dear, back there". You also introduce very large redistribution from those people engaged in activities that are iconic activities of our time, driving cars and flying round in aeroplanes et cetera. I suspect you have a political problem. I am not a politician but it looks to me as if you probably have.

  Q203  Chairman: We would love to have your help because we are politicians. Is there any way of making either of these alternatives remotely popular?

  Professor Ekins: The message that to me has never been properly marketed, if we are looking at the two instruments of taxation and personal carbon allowances, is that if one was to charge very much more through taxation for environmental goods one would be able to reduce taxes elsewhere. That connection has never been properly made in the political discourse. We have had large scale increases in environmental taxes in the past, most notably during the nineties with the fuel duty escalator, which undoubtedly fiscally enabled some of the income tax reductions which we saw during that period if one looks at the numbers, but the connection was never made politically. The income tax reductions were presented as give aways from a generous Chancellor, whereas the fuel duty escalator was perceived as a stealth tax from an ungenerous Chancellor. The connection between the two in the fiscal system was never made. It may be, and I hope that might be one way of making this shift in relative prices much more attractive. The benefit of the personal carbon allowance approach and indeed of all trading approaches in the long term—I draw a distinction between short term and long term—is that it does enable you to get a pretty clear handle on the quantities. In the long term it is clearly the quantities that are important. I am enough of a brainwashed economist to believe that if you raise the price by a significant amount you will in fact reduce the quantity. We know what elasticities have been in the past when prices have gone up. They are often said to be very low but in fact they are not that low. They might be between 0.3 and 0.5 on a long term basis, which would result in very significant energy and carbon demand reductions if you were to increase energy prices significantly. You could probably increase those elasticities through information, through awareness and through generally instilling in the public a will to reduce carbon emissions. Unless one manages to instil in the public a will to reduce carbon emissions, one is not going to get personal carbon allowances through politically either. That seems to me to be a sine qua non of creating that discourse whereby not just you, me and the other Members of this Committee and probably most of the people sitting behind me think it is essential to reduce carbon emissions, but that becomes an absolutely clear public objective among people at large. I think we have made progress in the 10 or 15 years that I have been working intensively on this issue, but it is nothing like as much progress as the science has made showing that global warming will overwhelm us if we do not do things on a much faster timescale. That is the challenge.

  Q204  Mr Caton: Would there be any problem in fitting personal carbon trading into the wider environmental policy landscape? In particular I am thinking of the EU ETS.

  Professor Ekins: There are two possibilities. You could design it so that it did not overlap at all with the EU ETS. In other words, you only designate those emissions to come under the PCA rubric that were not in the EU ETS. That is interesting because, as you know, there are talks about bringing road transport for example in the EU ETS. As far as I am aware, we have not had detailed proposals as to how that might work. It is clear to me that it would have to work rather differently from the current EU ETS unless you were simply to give all the allowances to the oil companies. At the moment in the EU ETS, you give the allowances to large enterprises, large businesses. Road transport is not generally carried out by large businesses, certainly not in the personal sector. You would have to find some other way of distributing the allowances. As far as I am aware that has not been properly investigated. I guess this is most likely to arise now with personal carbon allowances if and when aviation goes into the EU ETS, because many of the proposals for personal carbon allowances suggest that aviation should be included in the personal carbon allowances. In principle, it does not seem to me that there is a problem if there is overlap. I do not at all agree with the analysis in the document done by the Centre for Sustainable Energy which suggested that there might be an increase in emissions because in any cap and trade scheme the total number of emissions is set by the cap. If you do not change the cap, you will not change the total number of emissions. If under the personal carbon allowances aviation was included there and in the EU ETS and people reduced their aviation because that was the way the cap was going, what effectively that would mean would be to loosen the cap in the other sector, but you would still have the same number of emission permits. That would reduce the price in the other sector. It would take the pressure off the price because effectively you would have had reductions there that had not been done in that sector. I am not sure that that is a problem, though obviously you would need to account for it carefully and make sure that each sector's emissions were being reduced in the terms in which they were accounted.

  Q205  Colin Challen: We would all probably agree that it would be best to have a very steep curve in the reduction of emissions. Using this scheme or perhaps other mechanisms for achieving that, do you think we would have the capacity to change our behaviour? We have our systems geared up to a high carbon consumption rate. How fast do you think we could get that cap introduced, reducing steeply our emissions?

  Professor Ekins: In terms of personal lifestyles, the potential is very great. Some people live rather low carbon lifestyles at the moment without being obviously disadvantaged. For fun, I did my own personal carbon lifestyle on the recent government calculator that has been released. My emissions are about 30% of the per capita average across this, according to this and according to the graphs that I was shown. It leaves a certain amount to be desired in the transparency and knowledge of how these graphs are being constructed but I am not normally regarded as a particularly deprived person. I found it possible over a number of years to reduce my carbon emissions in an absolutely systematic and determined way, while still participating as a full member of society. I am sure lots of people could do that if they wished to but it obviously does have implications for the kind of life you lead. Most of the ways in which one does that are discretionary things that one can perfectly well learn to do without and still lead a full and participatory life in other ways. That sector of emissions is potentially very discretionary. Were people to be appraised and to feel the urgency of the situation, we could get large reductions from that sector relatively quickly, as undoubtedly we would have to if we went into something like a war situation. All sorts of things that people take for granted simply would not be possible. I am not sure how climate change could be presented in those lights, although I am quite certain the damage it will inflict in the long term will be fully equal to war time damage. It is not a totally inept analogy but clearly public perceptions of climate change are going to be very different to the kind of public perceptions of external threat that come about in war time. Part of the political discourse has to be to try to get across the seriousness of the situation without invoking analogies that can be shot down because they clearly do not recreate people's perceptions of these situations.

  Q206  Colin Challen: To make anything like this work, surely we are going to have to go beyond the individual. We are going to have to look at the way society tells us we ought to lead our lives. When people like Mark Dirkin produced that programme, The Great Global Warming Swindle, he accused his detractors of being anti-globalist, anti-capitalist, anti-consumerist and that is the real agenda. If you take the possibility that that is the real agenda, for a lot of people who want to buy their BMW 7 series and live preferably a bit higher than on the flood plain in a detached house with a good garden, it is a very intuitive thing to get across. Would we have to introduce parallel legislation to control what the marketing industry feeds us every day in terms of the message? It is going to be very difficult for people to make individual choices, as many people in this room have done very laudably, when out there this great torrent of information is coming at them every day which tells them that it is okay to buy a Lexus.

  Professor Ekins: There is a fundamental inconsistency in having a recognition of the need for a ration, which is what the PCA is, and a marketing industry that tells you to go on consuming more and more of those particular commodities that are particularly intensive in respect of that rationing. I throw it back to politicians in that it is unlikely that we will get political acceptance of the need for the rationing while the message from the very powerful marketing industry is that we can go on consuming more and more of all the things that would breach this rationing. If we want acceptance of the rationing, we will have to sort out something in terms of the consistency of the messages which people are getting so that at every moment when you are encouraged to emit more carbon, whether through patio heaters, plasma TVs or motor cars of a non-efficient kind, you do get the message that this is going to hit the ration at some point in the future. We therefore need to weigh this up and balance it against reductions elsewhere.

  Q207  Colin Challen: Would it need a statutory code, as has been suggested with advertising fatty foods to children or whatever?

  Professor Ekins: It seems to me that the climate change issue is every bit as important as the nutritional issue. Therefore, yes, information, persuasion and understanding of what is at stake are absolutely critical. Part of the problem is that we have heard quite a lot over the last few years about climate change being just about the most important issue on the domestic agenda from scientists and politicians without anything resembling the policy mechanisms being put in place or developed that would cause people to believe that. Until we start having a very great range of policy mechanisms put in place so that people can say, "They really do look as if they are serious about this," they may reject it. The political danger is that the people who put those policy mechanisms in place will not win the support of the people. That is clearly a problem in a democratic context. At the moment I do not think people believe the politicians who say that this is the greatest threat facing us. They look at things that politicians clearly do take seriously like terrorism and obesity and they see a whole raft of policy instruments being wheeled out that do impact quite significantly on people's lifestyles and convenience and they say, "We know when politicians and government take this kind of stuff seriously. They do this sort of thing" and then they believe it.

  Q208  Jo Swinson: Turning to the issue of how you would divvy up the allowances, we have heard already this morning the case for an equal per capita basis but your memorandum suggests that it does not need to be that way. Given the complexities involved, what would you propose would be an alternative model that would be workable and also perceived to be fair?

  Professor Ekins: No one model is going to be perceived by everybody to be fair. Fairness is something that is fought out in the political process day by day. This will have to be too. The EU ETS is interesting because that was allocated not on the basis of equal per capita, whatever that might mean in company—you could have given it on the basis of turnover for example—but effectively on the basis of historical use, which is grandfathering on historical use, and that would be another way of doing it with perhaps some version of the contraction and convergence principle such that those people who were using most would be expected to reduce most quickly, so that one came down and narrowed the differences between various uses. Another option would be to give what you might describe as a basic allowance to everybody free which might cover 60% of emissions from the sector. Then you might want to sell the rest. That would be a kind of hybrid between what is being proposed for the EU ETS, in that you auction some proportion of the emission allowances, and that would become a kind of hybrid between a tax and an allowance scheme which would raise revenue which would allow other taxes to be reduced or you could spend in other ways. There are lots of possibilities for this allocation mechanism and I suspect the equal per capita one is unlikely to help its political acceptability. Quite a lot of people, as soon as they realise what equal per capita emissions meant in terms of redistribution and reallocation, would demand that while they might accept that that was a possible, long term objective, they would certainly demand an adjustment and a transition period. One would have to think quite carefully about the whole trajectory of allocation of these allowances.

  Q209  Mark Lazarowicz: Surely there is the danger that the more complicated we become the more politics comes into it to decide what is equitable, in terms of how you make the adjustments to the per capita allocation and then you take away from the whole attractiveness of the scheme as being one which has a long term consistency taken away from the approach. My Liberal Democrat friend here will no doubt want to have higher allowances to allow people to fly to the Highlands and Islands of Scotland more easily. Other people will want to do something for health and all the rest of it. The more you allow that kind of variability, are you not going to detract from the simplicity behind the concept of a PCA?

  Professor Ekins: Yes, one is. On the other hand, the whole purpose of doing it would be to make it more politically acceptable, just as taxation is often regarded as politically unacceptable unless it is related to ability to pay. This concept of equal burden of adjustment as opposed to equal allowance is one that has a certain currency. It certainly has a currency in trading schemes. It is the way in which for example the Kyoto Protocol was divided up among the nations of the European Union and the reductions there, on the basis of how easy the countries thought it was going to be for them to meet the overall target that Europe was allocated in that process. Because I am not in favour of lengthy bureaucratic processes by and large, I certainly would not be wanting to argue for particular exemptions on the grounds of particular kinds of travel. The point Dr Fawcett made about the possibility that there may be some medical conditions that could, on a doctor's prescription, get you an extra allowance might have some weight, because otherwise you will certainly get very high profile opposition to a scheme from people who by and large are very good at generating column inches in the tabloids about unfairnesses to do with people with certain medical conditions who are not given special dispensation. I would certainly want to keep those to a minimum. It would seem to me that some scheme that combined a basic allowance for everybody with certain well thought out, broad distinctions such as perhaps based on medical conditions, perhaps even based on age given that very often older people are less mobile, spend more time at home and need and use more energy, where some extra part of that basic allowance gets allocated on that basis and then perhaps selling some portion of the rest. That would still be a very simple scheme compared to something like the Climate Change Levy that took armies of bureaucrats to negotiate these climate change agreements with very large numbers of energy intensive sectors. I like the simplicity of the idea but I do not think it is likely to be politically acceptable straight off like that.

  Q210  Jo Swinson: On the politically acceptable point, the Energy Saving Trust has described personal carbon trading as overwhelmingly unpopular amongst people. You said earlier on that any form of significant carbon reduction is not likely to be popular but clearly we, as politicians, need to find a way of encouraging people to take that seriously. First of all, how confident are you that the public can be convinced? Secondly, what do we need to do to make that happen?

  Professor Ekins: Looking at the evidence of the way in which social change has happened over the last 15 years, it is quite clear to me that the public can be convinced. We have moved a very long way down the track of people being aware of this issue and being vaguely perturbed about it. The problem is that the length of time that this trend if projected before we would do anything serious about reducing emissions is simply at variance with what the science is telling us. As you will know, a particular characteristic of the climate change issue is that there is no smoking gun. There is no single event that you can ever point to definitively and say, "That is the result of climate change. Therefore we must do something about it." There are people swimming about in the Midlands after an event which is the kind of event which, 15 years ago, we were told was likely to become more frequent and worse. It entirely fits with what the climate scientists were telling us was more likely. I cannot say, you cannot say, no one with any credibility can say that it is definitively because of climate change that these guys are swimming around in Tewkesbury. It is one of these probabilistic events that our political system finds it very difficult to deal with. We need to have a much more sophisticated discourse, I am afraid, than that television programme that Colin Challen referred to earlier.

  Q211  Mark Lazarowicz: I think you were here for the question from Colin Challen about whether the public were engaged in a system of actively trading allowances and take advantage of the market. What are your views on that issue?

  Professor Ekins: I think it depends on the extent to which the public understands what a really radical innovation it can be. One would be setting up I think for the first time in history a projected, second currency to run alongside the first currency. It is a very peculiar kind of currency because it is both a commodity, a thing that you can buy and sell, and it is a money, a means of exchange. We have moved away from money being a kind of commodity in anything except the most esoteric, financial markets so most people do not think of money as a commodity any more, although of course it used to be. We are reintroducing that idea in an absolutely explicit way. If people understood that carbon was money, they would take it very seriously. They would participate in any scheme that was set up. They would find that they would need carbon bank accounts. In my memo, I suggest I cannot envisage how you would implement the scheme except through a whole parallel bank accounting system in which all adults had their account and carbon fell into their account monthly or whatever and they had their smart cards and they could use it in the same kind of way that they use any other kind of money. As soon as people recognise that that is what it is all about, they would participate in it. They need not necessarily understand it any more than most people understand the financial system at the moment which is not very much if the survey evidence that I have come across is anything to go by. The challenge will be to really connect that very abstract, transactional environment which will resemble the money environment with people's energy use and perceptions of energy use and a recognition that, when they turn the central heating up, that will mean that this parallel money as well as their normal money is going to be hit. The big difference about the parallel money is that it is rationed. There is a fixed amount out there in the nation and they will need to buy in a market that is fixed. That is quite a different kind of market to the one people are used to.

  Q212  Mark Lazarowicz: You are right to say that it is radical and probably arguably revolutionary. It is not only a second currency; it is also one that wipes out the savings in relation to that particular part of the market covered by the scheme because you would not be able to rely upon your savings to buy your travel. You would have to rely on your allocations of carbon allowances.

  Professor Ekins: You would be able to rely on your savings provided your savings were large enough to purchase carbon allowances from somebody else. The difference would be that that total fixed number of carbon allowances, especially if we are going out to 2030 and one can see that one is on a declining trajectory by 35 or 40% on the carbon emission reductions envisaged in the Climate Change Bill by that date, one would be talking about very large sums of money needing to change hands in order to buy discretionary carbon allowances. This would be a serious commodity and would require a revolution in the way that we view these activities. I am a little doubtful that that kind of revolution and perception will happen very fast in the absence of some really fundamental event that causes us to re-evaluate this issue.

  Q213  Mark Lazarowicz: You are assuming people would not turn down free carbon allowances but there have been plenty of examples where members of the public do not appear to take advantage of free money. For example, there are areas to do with energy efficiency where we all know people do not make rational choices in terms of insulating lofts and so on when it would save energy. We have the example of the Child Trust Fund where a substantial number of people do not take any active steps to try and get hold of free money. Can we really be sure that we would have sufficient liquidity in the market?

  Professor Ekins: The key is, firstly, information and, secondly, public perception. There are different reasons why people do not take up energy efficiency options, partly due to transaction costs, hassle factors, all those other things that people like the Environmental Change Institute have written lots about and so have many other people. People have to do quite a lot. As soon as you go into your house and think, "What do I have to do to take advantage of all these free energy efficiency options?" it immediately gets extremely boring and rather tedious. You have to make lots of telephone calls to people you do not really trust. They come and wander about your house and suggest to you all sorts of things which you think will not make it look very nice. There are serious problems in that sector. On the non-take up of benefits, I believe that there is still a stigma factor which people have worked hard to try to overcome. There are some people, perhaps quite laudably, who feel they do not want to take advantage of benefits. This scheme will be different in the sense that you would have a bank account. There are not many people who have a bank account who do not draw on it. Under this kind of scheme, you would have to have a bank account. People would have to have a carbon allowance bank account which received these things on a regular basis. They would be sent statements about how much they had. I do not think there is any evidence that people who have bank accounts do not draw on them. That is the correct analogy. If people understood that this was money and they knew that they had an account in which this money resided, they would spend that money on a regular basis as they consumed energy and as they emitted carbon; but they would know if they had money at the end of the year they would know that they could sell it. There would be any number of brokers, marketers, people sending them flyers and e-mails saying, "If you have carbon, come to us. We will reduce the transaction costs. We will offer you however much real money you want." There might even be a problem that people would participate too freely in the carbon market to start with. They might sell all their allowance because they did not really know what it meant. They would then find that they have to buy further allowance back at a later date when they started consuming and they recognised that they needed this secondary kind of money in order to cover their energy consumption. I think people would cope with that after a while but the introduction of the scheme would have to be very carefully prepared and people would really need to understand what was going on which is why I am a little sceptical about the value of a pilot. I do not think that with something as fundamental as people's perceptions of money—and that is what we are talking about—there is any substitute for the real thing. We know in many instances when people are asked hypothetical questions about money it is quite different to what happens when the real thing comes along and it affects their behaviour in an absolutely concrete way.

  Q214  Mark Lazarowicz: It is money but it is not money as we know it. Are you confident that we can operate a system of personal carbon allowances through the banking system? There have been examples where IT systems have not always worked quite as wonderfully as they ought to have.

  Professor Ekins: I am not confident because I am not an expert in this. We have a very sophisticated banking system which seems to work. To me, this scheme would probably be best operated through that banking system. I do not see that the kinds of transactions people would be making through their carbon accounts would be far less frequent and far less complicated[6] than the kinds of transactions that they make through their normal money accounts. I would be very confident that the banking system could handle it. Some of those who are doing detailed work on this issue might be coming up with other schemes which they think could work even better. I do not know about those. When I look at the way in which the banking system works and the way in which it enables people to engage in this very wide range of transactions in hugely different contexts, in many different ways, from cash to cheques, to Internet trading, to electronic accounts, to credit cards, to debit cards, I think some adaptation of some small subset of those possibilities would enable a carbon market to work pretty well.

  Q215 Joan Walley: Can I press you a little more on what you said about pilot schemes? You said that you did not see much point at this stage in pilot schemes because you would be dealing with not having real money or it would all be not properly worked out. Is there anything else that we should be doing in preparation for getting some kind of public readiness to accept this kind of a proposal? Do you rule out pilot schemes completely?

  Professor Ekins: What I am sceptical about is that a pilot scheme would tell you very much about how such a scheme would work in the real world when it was for real. Quite apart from anything else, anyone engaging in a pilot scheme would know it was going to finish in 12 months. All the strategies and perceptions they might have would have this very time limited character whereas obviously, if a PCA scheme were to be introduced, it would be for real and for ever. Just as no one suggested having a pilot scheme for decimalisation that I remember and I do not think any country had a pilot scheme for the introduction of the euro, they just had to set it up, prepare it really carefully, ensure that people really understood what was involved. Of course you did get your glitches in the transitions with people being fraudulent and all that kind of stuff. One would just have to try to prepare against that. That seems to me to be the correct analogy of the sort of thing that is being introduced. If however you wanted to play games in schools in order to get across the idea that energy is linked to carbon and carbon will need to be rationed and this is a game in schools which kind of enables you to do that, you might link that in some way to carbon calculators. I think carbon calculators are a very interesting innovation. They are interesting as an educational tool, trying to make palpable and real to people this very abstract idea that energy contains this stuff, when we use it, of carbon dioxide which we cannot smell or see and it is changing the climate. This is pretty difficult stuff for people to grasp in their every day life. You do not find very often any more people thinking it but I remember 10 or 15 years ago members of this August House who did not know that climate change was not the result of depletion of stratospheric ozone. These are difficult issues to get across. There may be all sorts of ways in public education processes that would help. That is fine. You can call those pilots and I would entirely think that they could be very useful because clearly there is lots of public education that is required in the field. I am doubtful as to how much useful information they would give about how such a scheme would work in practice.

  Q216  Joan Walley: Presumably the difficulty is how do we bridge that gap and prepare a public who are not ready to understand the issue and the urgency of it, who are not as informed as they could be even despite the floods that we have just had over the last few days, where we do not have as much education for sustainability in schools being taught and at every professional level? How do we get people to prepare to be ready with some kind of readiness to accept this when it comes in? If pilot schemes are out, are you saying that we should be relying upon academic work behind the scenes in preparation for when there would be some public acceptability that doing nothing is not an option? It has to be done quickly.

  Professor Ekins: The kind of work that Tina Fawcett was talking about, about trying to understand better the distribution implications, is very important. The work that Simon Dresdner and I did on the distributional consumption of energy, the data is rotten. It is very poor indeed and I think we will need to get a handle on what the detailed distributional impacts of these different allocation mechanisms are likely to be. That seems to me to be a very important area where we need to understand it but again we need to understand that for all sorts of reasons, not just because of PCAs. We need to understand that because if we were serious about climate change in the domestic sector we would already have a complete characterisation for domestic housing stock. We would already know through a GIS system what every single house was in terms of its U value and the kinds of energy efficiency measures that you could put in place in order to bring it up to scratch. Then we would have proper incentives to get people to do that. In a sense, we need to do all that stuff just to show that we are serious about the issue and for people to perceive that politicians are serious about the issue. It is very damaging when what to me is an extremely important innovation—the home information pack, which would start to give people detailed information about the carbon performance of their building—fell apart because we could not train 3,000 or 4,000 people in time. When that sort of thing happens, it is not surprising that the public thinks, "These guys do not take this issue seriously" because they would have ensured that we have enough surveyors out there in time, given that this Directive has not exactly been sprung on us. This has been in preparation through the European Commission for at least ten years so this is not something that just hit us between the eyes without us knowing about it. Those are the kinds of things we need to do in order to raise the acceptance among the population that politicians of all parties—it will not be possible to vote for a party that says, "This issue does not matter" and that is not serious about putting in place policies that would cause people to believe that. Once we are there I think we are in a much better position to start having a sophisticated discussion about the kinds of policy instruments that we want, the balance between taxation, regulation and trading and all those other things which policy wallahs like me spend their lives thinking about. At the moment frankly, it is not something that most people are ready to engage with at that level because we are not even at the basic level of being able to characterise the issue.

  Q217  Joan Walley: In the evidence that you have given to us, you are suggesting that there is not so far a political acceptable state of affairs where intervention of this kind is necessary. What is it going to take for a government to be in a situation where it would be able to go along with proposals of this kind and take the population with it, without which it would not be in a position to do it in the first place?

  Professor Ekins: If I knew a definitive answer to that question, I would be a very successful politician.

  Q218  Joan Walley: You cannot just be an academic, can you?

  Professor Ekins: I absolutely agree. Political acceptability is a dynamic phenomenon. It is something that can change quite quickly and things that would not have been politically acceptable become politically acceptable. Clearly it is the work of the whole climate change action community, of whom I am certainly one in an academic and research sense, to try to work for that. The Climate Change Bill is a very important political innovation because that will make it more difficult for politicians to opt out of the agenda altogether. I think it will mean that politicians, given these targets, if they do not like one set of policies for carbon reduction, they will have to put forward another set of policies for carbon reduction instead of just saying, "We do not like that." That is potentially an important discipline. We might then start having a proper debate about the right tools for carbon reduction. At the moment if we look at aviation for example, there is practically no recognition in the mainstream political world that the rises in aviation that are currently being facilitated through government permissions are simply inconsistent with any sort of carbon target that we may be anticipating is likely to have purchase on the problem. For as long as that is the case, the public will not believe that politicians are serious. That is a very difficult place for politicians to be because, on the one hand, they say things that are so unpopular they get de-elected and, on the other hand, they do not say things and yet they have an important message that has to be articulated but they are not believed because they have not put in place the means to implement the necessary actions. We all have a role in trying to ameliorate the situation. There is still quite a lot of scope for adventurous political and policy activity which is not being taken and where we do need further leadership on all sides.

  Q219  Joan Walley: In terms of the evidence that you have given, you have very much one foot in the academic world but obviously you interact with politicians or through the UN in different ways. I take what you say about it being the sum total of what we each do and what we each do acting together that really makes a difference. You talked just now about leadership. Just thinking about the academic community, is there more leadership that the academic community could be giving in order to be able to provide the information, the education, the research, to make it much more likely for there to be political action on this?

  Professor Ekins: The academic community is in many parts. The natural scientific community over the last five years particularly has become far more vocal and perturbed about this issue, with all this talk of tipping points and potential catastrophe and this kind of stuff, which was ruled out as more or less not polite conversation back in the late eighties/early nineties. That aspect of the debate has changed and it has definitely had an impact on public perception. The academic policy community, of which obviously I am part, yes, we are driven as much as anybody by Research Council funding. The increase in Research Council funding for things like the UK Energy Research Centre which has a very large policy component enables us to do much more work and therefore we can come along and talk about it much more. We are able to be much more solidly grounded in the evidence base. That is very useful and helpful. The kind of work on behaviour change that has been funded and is going on has so far been very inconclusive, which is not terribly surprising to me because this is a really difficult systemic problem about not knowing where to push a system and what is going to happen at the other end. I am doubtful that we will ever get any magic bullets on that and I suspect that quite a lot of that will come about through the suck it and see actions of politicians. You are the group of people whose profession is to feel where public opinion is in certain ways and be able to articulate things in ways that will send the public off to where you perceive to be a good direction. When all the major political parties feel that this is a real priority and they do articulate it in those ways, I think we will make much more progress. That would be quite a different place to where we were five years ago with things like the fuel duty protests. The whole role of the fuel duty escalator in curbing car fuel demand and the environmental benefits of that almost went completely by default from practically all the parties, with some honourable exceptions. We are moving and we need to intensify and accelerate these processes by factors of ten or 100 if we are going to make the 15 year Stern window.



5   Note by Witness: The witness meant to refer to DTQ, not DGQ. Back

6   Note by Witness: The witness meant to say he did not think the kinds of transactions people would make through carbon accounts would be far more frequent and far more complicated that the kinds of transactions they made through their normal money accounts. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2008
Prepared 26 May 2008