[back to previous text]

Q 218 Mr. Love: But there may be people outside the business improvement area who do give a damn about someone else getting a discount or a bribe, whatever we call it. You have a business improvement area where there is a clearly justified reason why business would want to be involved and pay the levy. You have a business rate supplement scheme which one assumes business will support and a clear economic rational for why they would want to do so. The question that I am really asking you is: why should businesses inside the improvement zone get some form of reduction? They are getting an economic benefit in the same way as others, so why should they not pay like everyone else?
Dr. Grail: Because they would be paying twice. The businesses outside the BID area are not paying for the BID levy.
Q 219 Mr. Love: But they are not receiving the benefit of the BID levy or of what is happening inside the business improvement zone. A business that sits outside the business improvement area and gets no benefit from it does not pay anything towards it, but when it makes a contribution to a wider scheme on business rate supplement, those businesses on the inside get some sort of discount or bribe, whatever you want to call it. Would that not be objected to by businesses outside, or do you think that they will be happy that others are getting a reduction?
Dr. Grail: That presupposed that those who propose a BID can clearly demonstrate that for every pound they spend they get at least a pound back, and that is difficult to achieve and demonstrate. I am saying that what we are trying to do is look pragmatically at how we maintain a BIDs movement in this country, because we are in grave danger of losing it. That is how we could recognise that there is a compromise that we could achieve, so that the business community is not given carte blanche to create low-level BIDs but recognises at least some subsidy.
I think that it is an entirely different matter whether the business community supports business rates and what the relevance and focus of that is. How do we protect business improvement districts, which are working well in this country? Business communities, when faced with a 2p levy over which they have no choice and a 1p-ish levy on a BID, will vote against it in many cases at the moment. There are ways to try to safeguard that, at least in part.
The Chairman: On that point, Dr. Grail, we have reached the end of this session. Thank you very much for coming along, and for your informative contribution to our debate.
5.31 pm
The Chairman: Good afternoon and thank you for coming along. We have until 6.15 for this session. Could you please identify yourself for the record?
Blake Penfold: My name is Blake Penfold, and I am a chartered surveyor with GL Hearn, which has offices in London and elsewhere in the UK. I chair a policy panel on rating and local taxation for the Royal Institution of Chartered Surveyors, a body governed by a royal charter. We are not a lobby body; we are here to speak in the public interest in respect of the business rates system.
Jerry Schurder: I am Jerry Schurder, head of rating at Gerald Eve LLP, chartered surveyors and property consultants. I am a member of the RICS rating and local taxation policy panel and Blake’s immediate predecessor as its chairman.
The Chairman: Thank you. Nick Raynsford.
Q 220 Mr. Raynsford: Your written submission implies that the RICS takes a rather negative view of the legislation. First, in paragraph 5, you say that there is little sound economic reason for introducing supplements and little enthusiasm from the business community for such supplements. Do I take it from that that the RICS is opposed to Crossrail?
Blake Penfold: No, we are not opposed to Crossrail. We are in favour of it.
Q 221 Mr. Raynsford: So how do you propose that Crossrail should be funded?
Blake Penfold: I will start with a negative, which is a slightly consultant-y way of starting an answer. Our concern about using business rates as a tool to fund Crossrail is that essentially, business rates are, as you will know, a tax on the occupation of property. They accrue on a daily basis, and therefore may accrue over quite a short term. Crossrail is a major infrastructure project by nature whose construction period will be many years and whose life will be way beyond that. We are not satisfied that a tax to do with the occupation of property levied on property occupiers is the correct way to fund a major infrastructure project.
Q 222 Mr. Raynsford: The Mayor of London said to us in his evidence that the passage of the Bill allowing the supplementary business rate for Crossrail is essential to enabling Crossrail to be built. Without it, the funding package collapses.
Blake Penfold: That must be a decision for Parliament. It would fall outside my remit as a rating valuer.
Q 223 Mr. Raynsford: But I am sure that the RICS has considered the implication. You are not saying that you would be quite relaxed if Crossrail collapsed.
Blake Penfold: No. In 2003, the RICS produced a report with GVA Grimley on funding options for Crossrail. One of those was a supplement on the business rate, but there were a number of others as well. For the reasons that I have tried to explain, we do not see a tax on the occupation of property as the best way to fund a major infrastructure project.
Q 224 Mr. Raynsford: Okay. You say that the existing uniform business rate is set at a high level. You will be familiar with the Lyons report.
Blake Penfold: Yes.
Mr. Raynsford: He made the very strong case that that was an unsound argument, because other business taxes are low by international comparisons. If you take things in the aggregate, therefore, the uniform business rate is not uniquely high. It itself might be, but the total package of tax on business is not.
Blake Penfold: I understand that entirely. The general rule that seems to me to be good for taxation is that it should be three things—low, simple and compulsory.
Q 225 Mr. Raynsford: Fine, okay. Are you familiar with what has happened to the business rate as a contributor to local government expenditure over the past decade or so?
Blake Penfold: Yes.
Q 226 Mr. Raynsford: Do you know that the proportion of local government expenditure met by the business rate has fallen from about 25 per cent., a decade or so ago, to about 20 per cent. currently?
Blake Penfold: Yes.
Q 227 Mr. Raynsford: Do you think that that is equitable?
Blake Penfold: It is a proportion of an increasing sum. The actual amount raised from business rates is increasing.
Q 228 Mr. Raynsford: But the domestic rate payer and the national tax payer has had to meet a much higher proportion as a result. Is that equitable?
Blake Penfold: They are voters, I suppose. That would perhaps be the position of business.
Q 229 Mr. Raynsford: So you are quite relaxed about the fact that on the one side is a declining proportion of business rates supporting local government, and on the other you do not want to see any use of that mechanism to support infrastructure? The RICS position appears to be that the whole burden for increased spending on necessary infrastructure or improving the local economy should fall either on the individual council tax payer or on central Government taxpayers.
Blake Penfold: There might be other options, one of which is outlined in the paper that we put forward: to hypothecate a proportion of the existing uniform business rate to local purposes. That could be levied, for example, by the Mayor of London, for Crossrail.
Q 230 Mr. Raynsford: How would that give additionality?
Blake Penfold: It would not.
Q 231 Mr. Raynsford: No. And therefore the funding of Crossrail could be achieved only by cutting other aspects of local government expenditure.
Blake Penfold: That is a circumstance with which I am familiar in my own household.
Q 232 Mr. Raynsford: Indeed, but if the view of the business community in London, of the Mayor and of central Government is that the Crossrail project is fundamental to the economy of London and the nation, and will require additional spending to get there, you would essentially say, “Sorry, but we don’t think that’s appropriate.” Is that correct?
Blake Penfold: I think that we are saying that the business rate system might not be the best way to achieve it, for the reasons that I have tried to explain.
Q 233 Mr. Raynsford: Forgive me if I sound a bit exasperated, but you seem to be advocating a position whereby the business rate payer has seen business rates providing a lower proportion of local government spending over the years, as a result of which the burden has shifted to national and council tax payers. When it comes to the need for major infrastructure investments, from which business will benefit hugely, as Crossrail has itself demonstrated, you do not think that there should be any additional contribution from business. That seems to me to be a totally untenable position.
Jerry Schurder: I am not sure that the RICS position is that business should not contribute. We are saying that we do not believe that the rating system is the best mechanism for finding that revenue. The key issue is that it is generally a tax on the benefits of occupation. In the main, but not exclusively, the property system in this country consists of owners and occupiers, and they are not always the same—in the majority of instances, they are not. The concern—and you raised this issue earlier—is that the burden will fall upon the tenant-occupier ratepayer. They might partly benefit from a successful scheme funded by the business rate supplement, but that would take some time to come through. Ultimately, however, the property owner would be the beneficiary of a successful scheme, and they would benefit from increased rental values and increased capital values without contributing to the scheme. The RICS has that concern about a number of the relief schemes that have been used and adopted over time in the business rating system. We do not feel that that is always the best way of targeting relief to what may well be deserving cases. Very often, the relief is targeted at the ratepayer tenant, but at least some of the benefits go to the landlord without them having contributed.
Q 234 Mr. Raynsford: I understand that and I hear the argument. However, that argument was used strongly and forcibly five years ago to oppose the introduction of BIDs. BIDs have come in, despite what we acknowledge may be a weakness, and the scheme has proved successful.
Jerry Schurder: I think there is a significant distinction to be drawn between the BIDs model and the business rate supplements. By their nature, BIDs are generally local and usually fund revenue expenditure, be that additional policing, street cleaning, street furniture or whatever. That brings fairly immediate returns to the tenant, the ratepayer. They contribute and they derive benefit. Some of that benefit may flow through to the landlord through increased values. The distinction that RICS draws with the business rate supplement is that generally these are major capital projects over a long time period. Clearly, there are significant elements of expenditure, and for the tenant to pay up front for a number of years—they might no longer be the tenant any more by the time the scheme comes to fruition—does not make this the best model or system to get business to assist with the funding of capital projects. It is not RICS’s position to say that businesses should not assist and contribute, but we are concerned that the business rate system is not the best measure to use.
Q 235 Mr. Raynsford: So, tell me your proposal in item 10 of your submission as to how we should introduce a scheme instead of this one, which would essentially derive similar benefits from property owners through supplements on them.
Jerry Schurder: That is a very good question and there is no straightforward answer. At the moment, we do not have a register of all property interests within the country. We have a complex scheme of property ownership with freeholders, head landlords, tenants and subtenants and so on, and that makes it very difficult. I appreciate that that does not assist with the answer to the question, but it is an important fact to bear in mind.
The only solution that we can come up with at this stage is our belief that tenants would feel more comfortable with the concept of contributing towards a BRS scheme if they could see equivalent, landlord contributions. It would not need to be one to one, but perhaps people could see that property owners are prepared to put their hand in their pocket. Property owners will ultimately be the beneficiaries and they should also contribute.
How does one achieve that? We cannot impose it—we do not see how we can have a system of imposing that on property owners. However, if there were a vote in all cases, which many of us are clearly calling for, that would focus the minds of those who propose a scheme to be funded by a BRS and ensure that they get contributions and funding from landlords. That would not only help reduce the element to be paid for by tenants, but it would enable the tenant ratepayer to see that their landlord is serious about the project and is playing a fair part. We cannot prove it, but our perception is that that would assist those voting in a ballot in favour of such a scheme. Perhaps the BIDs model, where landlords have come forward voluntarily and put their hands in their pockets, could assist with that.
 
Previous Contents Continue
House of Commons 
home page Parliament home page House of 
Lords home page search page enquiries ordering index

©Parliamentary copyright 2009
Prepared 21 January 2009