Business Rate Supplements Bill


[back to previous text]

Robert Neill: We come to a fresh and important set of considerations. It was dealt with in some detail by the witnesses who gave evidence to us, and it comes back to the issue of the interaction of the BRS with BIDs. I am happy to say that many of us have seen BIDs work well in our areas. I know that Ministers do not desire to harm BIDs schemes, but those who gave evidence expressed real concern that there is, not for the first time, a risk of unintended consequences and of an adverse impact on BIDs schemes.
Why does that risk arise? First, as we said earlier, the tax-raising power in the Bill is given right across the country. Secondly, it is done against a background of serious economic downturn and pressure on businesses. Thirdly, it is done at a time when, for a number of reasons, there are real constraints on local authority budgets. Finally, and in particular, it is done against the background of a reduction in the funding made available to local authorities for a number of economic development-related purposes, through the cutbacks in the funding of the LABGI scheme. Whether we call it mainstreaming LABGI, or whatever else, the fact is that there will be significantly less money available in the coming two years than was available over the previous years—£150 million as opposed to £1 billion.
The real concern that many people have, and which a number of my hon. Friends share, is that this may create almost irresistible pressure upon a local authority to use BRS as a means of making up some of that loss and to push the envelope of the rules to the maximum permissible extent. One might then get a situation where an authority that can justify the economic reasons for a scheme within the rules decides to proceed using a formulation whereby 25 per cent. or 30 per cent. of the monies are raised by the BRS, so the ballot provisions are not triggered. That, of itself, might be well and good, but the evidence suggested that the real concern for many business organisations is the interaction between that scheme an existing or future BIDs schemes in the area. Fear was also expressed about the cumulative effect if other measures are introduced, such as those involving voluntary contributions, the community infrastructure levy, workplace parking levies, and so on. There is a limit to how much can be squeezed out of businesses in those circumstances—one cannot get a quart out of a pint pot.
Because the threshold is not met to trigger a ballot, the business cannot ultimately say yea or nay to the BRS scheme. Realistically, it may not have much choice about the community infrastructure levy because, again, there is no ballot provision for that; nor would it have a choice in relation to the voluntary contributions—that is a matter of negotiation. The one area where it can say no is the BID scheme. The temptation in those circumstances will be for local businesses to say, “The only way that we can prevent an accumulation of burdens upon us is to say no to the one thing that we can say no to: the BID scheme,” even though, if the relative value of the BID scheme was ranked against the BRS scheme in a wholly dispassionate world and with an even playing field between the two, they might prefer the BID scheme.
In the current economic climate, the most important thing to them is containing their costs. That creates a perverse incentive to say no to BID schemes that might otherwise have been approved. That might not be the desired consequence, but it is the reality for lots of businesses. That was highlighted in the evidence of a number of witnesses on the effect of the economic downturn.
6.45 pm
Even the big multiples are shedding many jobs because their turnover is being squeezed. The Federation of Small Businesses made the point that for many of its members who may be caught above the threshold, cash flow is king. The one thing that they will do is restrict avoidable overheads. If they cannot avoid the BRS because they do not have a ballot, they will avoid the BID scheme. That would be tragic, because BID schemes have worked well and been hugely successful. I accept that the case for them has been proved by experience. They work well because businesses have real and genuine buy-in and the ultimate ability to say no. That is the background and why the measures are an area of concern to us. It is not a fanciful concern; it was flagged up, in one way or another, by all the various business organisations that gave evidence to us.
How can that unfortunate consequence be prevented? It seems to us that the best and safest way is to adopt the desire of all the business organisations to allow an automatic set-off for BID levies. In some cases, it may be said that the BRS deals with a different magnitude of scheme than BID schemes. Sometimes that is the case, but sometimes there will be an overlap. Another idea that might have been available, but which the Government have not made available in the Bill, is to have some reduction in the business rate multiplier to compensate, giving a set-off that way. However, that is not on the table, so we cannot sensibly advance it.
How can we protect the growing BID sector from damage in this difficult time? We can permit the automatic set-off. That could then be compensated in other ways, such as how thresholds or other poundages are adjusted within the scope of the Bill. It would at least create a situation of clear linkage between the area of a BID scheme, which might cover the whole of a local authority that also wants to do BRS, where there is substantial overlap. The automatic set-off would be a reassurance to businesses that they will not be hit, in effect, by a double whammy. That is the thinking behind the amendment. As you will have noticed, Mr. Atkinson, the amendment’s main thrust is to insert a new subsection (1) into clause 16 to achieve that effect, and other consequential amendments follow.
Mr. Raynsford: My particular interest focuses on new clause 1 and amendment 45, which stand in my name. They deal in a different way from that proposed by the hon. Member for Bromley and Chislehurst with the problem of the potentially unhappy interface between BIDs and BRS.
We have established that the two vehicles are broadly designed to meet different needs. BIDs are focused predominantly on local measures to improve the viability, attractiveness, safety and therefore commercial success of shopping areas, business districts, town centres and so on. BRS is predominantly likely to be used for major infrastructure investments or longer-term improvements to the economic attraction of a particular area; Crossrail will definitely be used for that purpose. However, despite the differences, there could still be circumstances in which the introduction of the BRS could have an adverse impact on BIDs. We heard strong evidence from Dr. Julie Grail and others about the possible knock-on consequence for the viability of bids—particularly where they are coming up for renewal—if businesses have been required to pay a BRS levy and feel that that is enough and they cannot therefore justify continued support for BIDs. That is a genuine problem that we need to address.
The Opposition proposal, which came from the hon. Member for Bromley and Chislehurst, is to have an automatic offset against the BRS to provide and direct financial compensation. As we heard from other witnesses, and as the hon. Member for Cities of London and Westminster rightly pointed out in the evidence sessions, the problem with that is it will provide a perverse incentive for essentially bogus BIDs to be set up to provide a means of getting out of the BRS contribution. The Mayor of London has emphatically said that that would seriously risk the viability of Crossrail. I notice that the Opposition have tabled an amendment saying that that would not apply in the case of Crossrail, but those are pretty desperate measures on the part of the Opposition, who all the way through have tried to say that they support Crossrail, but that they do not like this mechanism.
Robert Neill: Surely, the right hon. Gentleman should be jumping up to welcome the fact that we recognise the desire to protect the calculations in relation to Crossrail that he was so concerned about. He should reflect on the fact that this is a means of achieving both that and the degree of consistency that he has been urging upon us with the Crossrail Bill.
Mr. Raynsford: One thing is clear: there is no consistency whatsoever in the Opposition’s position. In order to try to reconcile the irreconcilable, they have made a series of manoeuvres, like the antics of mediaeval theologians trying to work out how many angels can dance on the head of a pin. The Opposition do not like this BRS thing, but because the Mayor of London is committed to Crossrail, they are committed to it. They have therefore got to find a way of squaring of circle—it is not very convincing. I personally take the Mayor of London’s advice on this, rather than that of the hon. Member for Bromley and Chislehurst.
The point we must recognise is that BRS could well apply elsewhere. If it did apply elsewhere, exactly the same problem would arise in another city or community where there was an existing BID. The formulation presented to us would have an automatic offset that would not be excluded in that context, because the exclusion only relates to Crossrail. Therefore, we could have exactly the circumstances that the Mayor of London has identified, scuppering the viability of BRS in that context because an automatic offset undermined the financial calculation. That is not a satisfactory solution.
Dr. Grail suggested an alternative, which was a modest, partial offset. That seemed a better approach, but it was not adequate and it was inevitably a bit ad hoc. Her argument was that if it was a modest offset, it would not really provide the incentive to do bogus BIDs in order to avoid liability to BRS. Nevertheless, it would have an impact on the viability of the financial estimates for the BRS, so it is not an entirely satisfactory option.
However, a more fundamental problem that has been around since the beginning of BIDs is that the levy is paid by the occupier, not the landowner. That is inevitable because that is the basis of our rating system. Businesses that are liable to pay rates are on the business rates register and that is the vehicle used to collect the BRS or, indeed, the BID levy. From the outset, when BIDs were first being discussed, people said it would be better to have a system whereby the landowner paid for the BID. That would require the creation of an entirely new rates register that relates to the value of the properties owned by individuals in that area. That, of course, is a complex operation because international ownership would pose serious difficulties in getting an entirely accurate and satisfactory register. It would certainly require a lot of work, and in areas where there was no certainty that a BID would proceed, it would be disproportionate for a local authority to have to go through the process of compiling a theoretical landowner register to put forward a BID proposal that might never happen.
When we introduced BIDs, we accepted that they would have to apply to the occupier—the tenant. We encouraged the concept of voluntary contributions from landowners who stand to benefit from the introduction of the improvements to the area. That has happened to a degree, and in some areas more than others. None the less, there is the problem of the freeloader. With a voluntary contribution, one cannot compel compliance, and some do the right thing and contribute, and others do not. The problem of the freeloader has been there from the outset, and has been a recurring leitmotif that people involved with BIDs have wanted to see addressed.
This is not the occasion to address the BID problem because we are dealing with BRS. None the less, new clause 1 gives us an opportunity to provide a mechanism to introduce a landowner levy to ease interface problems in areas in which BRS will replace BIDs. In that situation, it would not be too onerous a task on the local authority to introduce a register to create a landowner levy because there is an existing BID there. That would give authorities the confidence that some landowners are already contributing. The whole ownership and the knowledge of who owns the property in the area will be better understood because of the presence of the BID. There would be a clear interest on everyone’s part to get a viable landowner contribution levy into existence to ensure that the tenants have a reduction in their BID levy, which will be a genuine offset against the BRS. I am sorry if hon. Members are struggling to follow what I am saying, but this is very complex stuff.
Robert Neill: I am following the right hon. Gentleman very closely. In many ways, it is an attractive option; perhaps we can explore it a bit further in due course. Does he envisage an automatic correlation between the moneys raised by the landowner levy and the offset? I am not sure whether that is apparent from the wording of his provision, which I am trying to get my head around; or is it something that would have to be in regulations? I am interested to hear how we can achieve what may be a very satisfactory objective.
Mr. Raynsford: I am very grateful for the hon. Gentleman’s support. It could not ever be an automatic balancing item because we do not know enough. We would not know the composition of the landowning register until it was compiled, so there would be an ad hoc element to it. None the less, at least there is the prospect of this larger contribution from landowners, which would then allow some reduction—we do not know how much—in the contribution of the BID tenants. That is the key to avoiding a conflict between BRS and BIDs.
I do not expect my right hon. Friend the Minister to accept the amendment, because it involves a change in the title of the Bill, as those who have looked closely at the effect of the amendment will see. We have had to change the scope of the Bill to allow this measure to be included. This is quite big stuff, and I understand that although my right hon. Friend may be sympathetic, he will probably not be able to accept this.
Mr. Field rose—
Mr. Raynsford: I am getting very near to the time to finish, so if the hon. Member for Cities of London and Westminster will bear with this until Thursday morning when I complete my remarks, I will start by giving way to him at that particular point in time.
Ordered, That the debate be now adjourned.—(Mr. Watts.)
7 pm
Adjourned till Thursday 29 January at Nine o’clock.
 
Previous Contents
House of Commons 
home page Parliament home page House of 
Lords home page search page enquiries ordering index

©Parliamentary copyright 2009
Prepared 28 January 2009