[back to previous text]

Steve Webb: I beg to move amendment 27, in clause 6, page 3, line 18, at end add:
‘and the costs associated with disability.’.
I should alert you, Mr. Key, to the fact that my hon. Friend the Member for Edinburgh, West will also seek to catch your eye on the amendment. You have probably heard enough of me, but the treatment of disability is an important issue. As we discussed in the evidence sessions, people receiving certain disability benefits to reflect additional costs may have a perverse effect on the statistics as they are currently constructed. The living standard of those people is measured by their income, which includes the benefit they get because they have extra costs, but nowhere are those costs taken into account. Those people, therefore, appear higher up the income and living standards scales than they truly are. Their promotion up the ranking is artificial, because all the benefit does is make good the costs that non-disabled households do not face.
We simply suggest that account be taken of the costs associated with disability, and in a particular way. There are two obvious ways of taking account of disability benefits. One is to exclude them. I am grateful that the Under-Secretary of State for Work and Pensions, in following up a question I asked in a previous Committee sitting, has supplied us with a briefing note on the impact of excluding disability benefits from the HBAI measure. In parentheses, the note suggests that five topics are covered, but marginal deduction rates do not appear anywhere in it, so I hope we can have the missing section at some point.
The analysis shows that the aggregate number of those in poverty is pretty much the same whether or not disability living allowance is excluded. The totals are not affected. I am grateful for that useful information. However, we were getting at the composition, not the totals. The commentary on the numbers precisely states that if DLA is taken out, the median income is reduced, and therefore a set of children goes out of the figures. Presumably, they are children in households where nobody is disabled. However, there is presumably another set of children who will come into the figures—children in households where there is a disabled person. Although the total may be the same, the composition may be different. I do not think we yet have information about the composition.
If one is trying to measure relative living standards, excluding DLA is closer to the truth. One argument for excluding DLA is that we would get the right children. The total may not be different, but we would include more children in households with a disabled person than we do on the current definition, and the policy response may therefore be different. That all sounds like nerdy statistical stuff, but the point is that if our poverty figures include more children in households where there is someone with a disability, we will do more about disability—it follows. We need to get the right people in the figures, and not just the right totals. Therefore, there is a case for excluding DLA.
The ministerial comment on the Government’s figures stated that if we excluded DLA and then had a take-up campaign—so that more people received DLA—it would not show in the figures. That would be a bit odd, as clearly the Government have done something about poverty and it would not be fair if that did not show in the figures. I can see the logic, but our amendment proposes to tackle the issue in a slightly different way.
We have linked amendment 27 to the process of equivalisation. At the moment, we do not quite say that in a household two people can live as cheaply as one, but rather that a second mouth does not take twice as much as the first one, so there is a scaling. We take the total household income and scale according to the number of mouths to feed, the ages and all the rest of it to get an equivalent income—to scale households with different costs. We are arguing that we should have the same process for disability. Hence, rather than exclude a piece of income that someone is getting, which is one way of doing it, when we scale different households to reflect their different costs, we recognise that households with a disabled person have additional costs. They should have a higher equivalence scale, so that we compare like with like.
Andrew Selous: Members might remember that this was a point on which I questioned the Under-Secretary of State for Work and Pensions during our evidence sessions last week. I think the hon. Member for Northavon has made his points well. Disability living allowance is given to offset the increased costs of disability, which are many and varied, depending on the disability. Certain types of product may need to be bought to cope with the disability, and there may be increased heating costs, extra transport costs, as public transport is not suitable, or specialised child care costs. The issue will become larger as individual budgets start to loom on the horizon.
I, too, looked at the note we had from Ministers yesterday evening. I will be grateful if the Financial Secretary can explain something that appears curious. We were told that 23 per cent. of children were in households with below 60 per cent. of median income, with DLA and attendance allowance included as income. We were then given the figure for children in households with below 60 per cent. of median income, but excluding those allowances as income. The figure actually fell by only 1 per cent. to 22 per cent., which is slightly counter-intuitive, unless I am missing something. It tends to suggest that DLA is being taken up by slightly wealthier families, and that we have a problem with take-up at the lower end of the income scale. Those figures certainly are not what I expected, and I am left rather puzzled from a policy perspective, as to what that tells us and what we should do about it.
It is really a question of being honest. I hate to use that word, and I do not imply anything negative by it, but we have to reflect the reality of people’s lives. If income is given to cope with specific extra costs, one cannot really count it as ordinary income in the way that people who are not disabled would count additional income. That should be a given across the board; it is not a party political point, but a statement of the reality of the situation. I look forward to hearing what the Financial Secretary has to say.
John Barrett (Edinburgh, West) (LD): My hon. Friend the Member for Northavon does not often leave his colleagues with much to say on such issues, so I feel like an apprentice with the master by his side.
One group of people who have been very keen on the Bill are those with a disabled child or a disabled parent in the family, because they realise that the move towards the targets will have a great impact on them. As has been mentioned, it is vital that increased costs for heating, diet, transport or child care are recognised as additional costs on the family, and that additional income from DLA or other sources should not be seen as disposable income that the family will be left with. When we consider clause 6(c), which concerns
“what is to be regarded as the income of a household”,
and when we consider what deductions are to be made, it makes perfect sense to consider the costs and the deductions that have to be made to put a family on a level playing field with all the other families who do not have a disabled person in the house. My hon. Friend’s amendment therefore makes perfect sense.
Mr. Timms: Equivalising incomes to take account of the costs of disability is tricky, and we discussed the issue in last week’s evidence sessions. I am not sure whether the hon. Member for Northavon was proposing a methodology for doing that—if so, I should be interested to know a bit more—but it is certainly a difficult issue and there is no consensus on how it should be done.
Last week, we were asked whether it is possible to determine the impact on child poverty levels of not counting DLA as income. My hon. Friend the Under-Secretary then quickly produced the letter that has been mentioned. As we have heard, the figures show that there is almost no difference in the number and percentage of children who are counted as being in relative poverty using income figures that include, and exclude, DLA and attendance allowance. The hon. Member for Northavon explained why that was, but let me express it slightly differently.
Excluding DLA and attendance allowance from household income would reduce median household income. Attendance allowance and DLA are more likely to be received by families without children. There are, as the hon. Member for Edinburgh, West has rightly pointed out, families with children who receive DLA for those children. On the whole, however, it is more likely to be received by older people who are under state pension age and who do not have children, or whose children have grown up, whereas attendance allowance is more likely to be received by pensioner households. The effect of taking those components of income away would be to improve the relative position of households with children in the income distribution, because fewer households with children would have had their incomes reduced, and to worsen the position of pensioners, as a higher number of households’ incomes would have been reduced. That is another way of looking at the issue.
It is also worth noting that the households below average income series, where our child poverty statistics are published, is carefully reviewed. As national statistics, they have to be. The most recent review, in 2004, which is on the Department for Work and Pensions research website, addressed the issue of the extra costs of disability and how disability benefits should be treated. The review recognised that disability benefit recipients’ position in the income distribution figures is quite high. That might be a poor representation of their standard of living, but the review concluded that removing disability benefits from income would not be the solution, as it would not reflect any changes over time in the receipt of those benefits, and would then overstate the living standards of non-recipients who had extra costs.
5.30 pm
Once again the combined low income and material deprivation indicator comes to our aid. It allows a fuller assessment of the living assessment of those households facing particular difficulties due to high living costs such as the cost of disability because they will then have less disposable income available to meet other needs. That indicator will capture families who have an income that is higher than that captured by the relative low income target, but who still have a lower standard of living because they have additional costs related to disability or other additional costs to bear.
In developing the child poverty strategy, we will consider the evidence on which groups are likely to be most vulnerable to poverty and what measures are needed to meet their needs. Those groups are likely to include children in families with a disabled family member. The variable nature of the costs associated with disability make it difficult to equivalise income to take into account the costs of disability in the way proposed by the amendment. The hon. Gentleman has once again raised an important point. I am grateful to him for doing so but I hope that he will accept that his amendment does not give us a solution to the challenge here.
Steve Webb: If the amendment prompted the Department to do more work on the costs and impact of disability to assess the adequacy and coverage of disability benefit levels, that of itself would make it worthwhile. I accept that there is not a straightforward way of doing this and perhaps the work required to do it might delay the whole process, which we do not want. I notice the Minister again relies on the argument that the material deprivation indicator would pick this up. It is going to pick up disability costs and housing costs so it will take quite a fine statistician to work out what is going on in this catch-all. We need to pick these things up a bit more directly. I beg to ask leave to withdraw the amendment.
Amendment, by leave, withdrawn.
Clause 6 ordered to stand part of the Bill.

Clause 7

The Child Poverty Commission
Steve Webb: I beg to move amendment 48, in clause 7, page 3, leave out lines 29 to 32.
I had not planned to table the amendment, as is apparent from the numbering, but the subject arose during the evidence sessions. The amendment would remove the part of clause 7 that provides for the child poverty commission to be abolished. I must admit that I had not noticed that, which is why I had not tabled an amendment on the subject, but when we were looking at the Bill and discussing it, I suddenly realised that it gives the Secretary of State power to abolish the commission. On the face of it, that might seem reasonable: one could argue that we do not want a plethora of quangos and that once it has served its useful purpose, the commission should drift off into the sunset.
I do not think it is quite as simple as that. Tackling child poverty is a bit like running up a down escalator. If we do not do very much, we end up going backwards. We had a discussion this morning about poverty rates in Europe and it was noticeable that in all sorts of different countries with different Governments of different complexions and different social environments, overall child poverty rates are going up because there are global forces at work. Globalisation has implications for the wage structure. There are social changes going on across Europe. There are forces at work which tend to lead to greater inequality and greater child poverty. I therefore find it hard to believe that, even if we reach that happy day in 2022, for example, when we decide that the 2020 target has been met, we are not then going to want to have some sort of infrastructure for not taking our foot off the pedal at that point.
The Minister said—I paraphrase ever so slightly—that it is all very well the Finns getting 5 per cent. for a few years, but they could not keep it up, could they? Likewise, if the United Kingdom happened to reach the 10 per cent. target and so on in 2020, that is marvellous compared with where we are now, but could we keep it up and sustain it? What happens beyond the end of that period? Given that the child poverty commission is not some sprawling bureaucracy that is going to leach vast amounts of taxpayers’ money—£180,000 a year or whatever, for four meetings a year and some biscuits—it does not seem to be unduly onerous for it to have a rolling role, just as the Committee on Climate Change will go on until 2050. In other words, the bit of clause 7 that we are trying to delete makes the assumption that child poverty will be fixed somehow—that will be a box that we can tick, and we would not even have the slightest overseeing, reporting mechanism that the child poverty commission would provide.
I would like to see the child poverty commission kept going post-2020—not just because it provides jobs for academics. It is said that the poor are always with us, so we cannot afford to take our foot off the pedal. We need a body that is always there to prod and to probe on child poverty so, with the amendment, I would like to remove the ability of a future Secretary of State to abolish the child poverty commission.
Mr. Gauke: May I say for the first time today, Mr. Key, what a pleasure it is to serve under your chairmanship?
I rise to make a couple of brief points. First, the amendment raises an interesting question. As the hon. Member for Northavon said, we could see the Bill as being about achieving the 2020 target and, clearly, the child poverty commission has a role in that. Once that target is achieved, assuming that it is, what then is the ongoing role for the child poverty commission? Is there an argument for it to be abolished? We do not believe that quangos should exist for the sake of it. We are interested to hear what the Minister has to say about that and about his defence of the Secretary of State’s ability to abolish the commission.
My second point is a technical one, which is that the amendment does not do all that it should do. It proposes the removal of clause 7(4), but subsections (5) and (6) should also be struck out. For that reason, if the hon. Gentleman intended to press the amendment to a Division, we could not support it. However, an interesting point is being made and we would be grateful to hear the Minister’s views.
 
Previous Contents Continue
House of Commons 
home page Parliament home page House of 
Lords home page search page enquiries ordering index

©Parliamentary copyright 2009
Prepared 28 October 2009