[back to previous text]

Mr. Binley: No; I am listening intently.
6.45 pm
Mr. Hands: He said:
“Freezing the threshold would suck thousands more people in, particularly if big fiscal deficits, low interest rates, a weak pound and quantitative easing unleash a period of high inflation.”
The sudden, hasty introduction of the 50p rate is a huge blow to Britain’s reputation for tax stability and reasonable tax predictability.
On the complexity of UK taxes, the measures introduced will increase the differential between capital gains tax at 18 per cent. and income tax at 50 per cent., fuelling interest in structuring investments to fall within the CGT legislation rather than the income tax legislation. The reasons given for CGT unification in 2007 were, as the argument went, that the differential between the top rate of income tax, which was then at 40 per cent., and the 10 per cent. CGT rate was causing all sorts of people—mainly private equity—to dress up income as capital gains. The Government argued that they needed to unite the CGT rate as a way of preventing people from moving what was essentially income into capital gains. The differential then was 30 per cent. and under the proposals it will now be 32 per cent., so it remains to be seen what on earth is the basis for the Government’s 50p rate, as referenced to CGT.
I mentioned earlier The Sunday Times report at the weekend, “Five ways to turn income into capital gains”, which says:
“Converting income into capital gains has become the holy grail of tax planning following the government’s plan to increase the top rate of tax to 50 per cent.”
Is this really what the Government wanted? Grant Thornton accountants said:
“If you are able to put your earnings into a business you can really take advantage of the...CGT...rate—however, the ordinary man on the street has limited opportunities here.”
Is this really what the Government wanted? The ordinary man on the street would not be able to avoid high rates of tax through CGT, whereas those who can afford their own accountant could.
I think that I will end there. [Hon. Members: “Shame.”] All right, in that case I will talk about trust dividends and pensions, because there seems to be some level of popular demand. On trusts, I was interested to read the briefings provided by the Low Incomes Tax Reform Group and the Disability Benefits Consortium. This is an area of immense complexity, but I will try to do justice to the serious concerns of those organisations about the trust and dividend tax rates.
Clause 6 increases the trust rate and the dividend trust rate for discretionary and accumulation trusts from 40 per cent. to 50 per cent. and from 32.5 per cent. to 42.5 per cent. respectively. That point was also raised by the hon. Member for Dundee, East. The 32.5 per cent. to 42.5 per cent. rates were originally prescribed in the Finance Act 2004 to counter the use of trusts for tax avoidance purposes.
In the Finance Act 2005, provisions were introduced with the intention of protecting vulnerable beneficiaries of trusts from the effects of those high rates. The focus of that legislation was mainly disabled persons and children with a deceased parent. So clause 6 has an important impact on Britain’s tax code. Those provisions work currently by allowing the trustees of trusts with a vulnerable beneficiary to deduct from their tax liabilities at the appropriate trust rate, which we have just discussed, the difference between it and what the tax would be if computed at the rate that would be chargeable on the vulnerable beneficiary as an individual. So it is designed to help vulnerable individuals, but I have been told that the mechanism for computing relief is too complicated and, from my brief examination of the relevant parts of the clause and the schedule, I believe that that is so. Also, the statutory definition of a disabled person for those purposes is too narrow. Consequently, from April 2010 some small trusts for vulnerable individuals will be charged income tax at 50 per cent. on trust income.
I cannot imagine that that will be popular on the Government Benches. We are talking about vulnerable individuals and disabled people being charged income tax at 50 per cent. on the income of their trust, which was set up specifically for them. None of that can be reclaimed on behalf of the beneficiary. Under the Mental Health Act 1983, a disabled person is defined as someone who is in receipt of attendance allowance—the highest or middle care component of disability living allowance—or someone who has a mental disorder that prevents them from looking after their affairs. That definition is too narrow, which means that a trust for people who are disabled, but whose disability is of the wrong sort will be liable for the 50 per cent. trust rate. Is the Minister satisfied with that result of his proposed changes?
Who loses out? According to the Disability Benefits Consortium, the beneficiaries who are likely to suffer from that unintended side effect of clause 6 include the following: first, those with conditions such as Down’s, bipolar disorder or severe autism; secondly, vulnerable beneficiaries who do not come within the definition; thirdly, those without the right combination of benefits; and, fourthly, those who are entitled to the prescribed benefits, but who do not claim them. That raises many issues for the Minister to deal with. It seems that the law of unintended consequences has struck many times over.
I may talk more about trusts and pensions when we debate the schedule in due course, but I want to draw some conclusions purely in relation to the 50p tax rate. First, like the right hon. Member for North Tyneside, we think that the 50p tax rate is a crass political move, rather than a considered and well thought through change to the UK tax code. Secondly, its significance is big and could be monumental in sending out signals about doing business in the UK—this is first increase in the highest rate of income tax since 1974.
Thirdly, we doubt whether the Treasury has properly modelled the impact—indeed, in terms of modelling the impact, there is no differentiation between 50p and the phasing out of the allowances, as we heard earlier. Also, the Treasury is using behavioural assumptions about average taxpayers to suggest the behaviour of 300,000 highest earners, which is clearly nonsense. Fourthly, there is a complete lack of clarity on whether the change is permanent, which is what the Leader of the House said, or temporary, as the Chancellor, the right hon. Member for Airdrie and Shotts and other old stalwarts of Labour said on Second Reading. It is vital for us to get clarification on the matter.
Fifthly, the changes are likely to have a perverse impact on pensions, dividends and trusts. Disincentivising people to put money away in pensions will retard the savings culture that we need to encourage and, after 12 years of a truly dreadful UK stock market performance, it is perverse to make it less attractive to invest in UK equity—I will talk about that when we debate the schedule. On trusts, the biggest impact is, shockingly, likely to be on disabled people, recipients of compensation from accidents and other vulnerable persons.
Finally, the 50p tax rate has broken a clear Labour manifesto pledge, which I believe was made by every single Labour Member who is a member of this Committee.
Mr. Jeremy Browne: It is a pleasure to follow an extremely comprehensive contribution. I do not say that sarcastically; this is an important policy development and it is right that it is scrutinised in detail. The hon. Member for Hammersmith and Fulham performed a service to the Committee by examining the proposal in the detail that he did. However, I do not wish to speak at quite that length—not least because I agree with some of the points made by the previous speaker and I do not wish to repeat them just for the sake of form.
The only thing I would say to the Conservative party is that, although the intellectual case made by the hon. Gentleman—many other members of the Committee also make such a case—seems reasonably compelling and the Conservatives certainly believe it with great fervour, they appear to lack the courage of their convictions. I have heard Conservative MPs—including some who do not serve on this Committee, for example, the right hon. Member for Wokingham (Mr. Redwood)—say that this is an elaborate trap that has been placed by the Government to lure the Conservatives into being typecast as defenders of the rich and privileged. All Government policies and taxes are a trap in the sense that they provide an opportunity for differentiation between the governing party and those parties not in Government. To refuse to engage with Government policy merely because there is a risk that it will be contrasted unfavourably with one’s own policy is to abandon all democratic politics and give the electorate a diminished choice. The Conservative party, as the largest Opposition party, have some duty to try to articulate choices with regard to not only how they contribute to debate, but how they frame votes and manifestos at the general election.
Turning briefly to the proposal before us, I echo the point that it is a betrayal of Labour’s 2005 general election manifesto commitment—the quote has been given and I will not repeat it. The manifesto on which the Labour party stood and won an unprecedented third general election in 2005 emphatically did not state that they would leave income tax rates the same unless economic circumstances make it attractive for them to do otherwise. It was perfectly possible for the Labour party to have put that caveat in their manifesto and to have said that it was an aspiration to leave the top rate of tax as it was at 40 per cent. but that they could not make a firm commitment or an absolute promise to do so because they were not in a position in 2005 to know how the economy would be in 2009-10. It would have been entirely honourable for the Labour party to put forward that position at the general election, but it did not do so.
As the hon. Member for Hammersmith and Fulham has said, the then leader of the Labour party, apart from promising to serve as leader for the entire duration of this Parliament if Labour won, also spoke disparagingly about the concept of a 50p tax rate for people on higher earnings. He made that case, which Labour Members at the time cheered with great gusto and then made to the electorate in their constituencies. Who knows, quite a few Labour Members here today might not be Members had they, when speaking to the electorate in their constituencies, squared with them and said, “We cannot give you a commitment to keep the top rate at 40p.”
Mr. Russell Brown (Dumfries and Galloway) (Lab): May I ask the hon. Gentleman a simple question? How many letters or items of correspondence has he had from any of his constituents complaining about the increase from the 40p rate to the 50p rate, because I have not had one?
Mr. Jeremy Browne: I have had very few. Indeed, I am not sure that I have had any, but my point is about the ability to break the promises made in a party manifesto on which a candidate stood at the general election. The honour or otherwise of holding to one’s commitments to the electorate cannot be measured by the number of letters one receives. Had the hon. Gentleman received 50 letters, would he feel a degree of guilt about not abiding by the Labour party commitment? Had he received 100 letters, would he feel totally ashamed? Had he received 150, would he resign as a member of the Committee, and had he received 200, would he resign as a Member of Parliament? The idea that the number of letters one receives is the measure by which one can judge whether it is appropriate to break one’s promises seems to me to be an entirely new concept, and one I suspect the electorate are less enthusiastic about than he is.
Mr. Russell Brown: Surely the hon. Gentleman, along with the rest of the Committee and all Members of the House, recognises that the current economic climate, which we are dealing with here, is vastly different from what we went into in 2005—unprecedented.
7 pm
Mr. Jeremy Browne: The situation is indeed different from that in 2005, which is why the Labour party would have been well advised to say, “Our commitment as a party is not to increase the top rate of income tax if the current benign economic circumstances continue for the duration of the forthcoming Parliament”—but that is not what it said. The Labour party, under the leadership of Tony Blair, said that it would not increase the top rate of income tax during this Parliament. The Labour party has broken that promise—unless an election is called before the policy can be implemented. One could then, technically, argue that the policy was not reneged upon.
Mr. Todd: Surely the hon. Gentleman must accept that the current economic circumstances are unique within probably three or four generations. No reasonable person could have predicted the outcome back in 2005. To maintain a commitment in the defiance of the facts surely does not make sense.
Mr. Jeremy Browne: I have gone over the ground and heard the excuses. We have come to the conclusion that all Labour party promises in future ought to be seen with an invisible asterisk next to them: “This is what we promise you at the election”, but with an invisible asterisk leading down to some more invisible type at the bottom of the page, stating, “Unless we can see a change of circumstances sufficiently great to justify doing the precise opposite of what we promised when we put ourselves before you and asked for your vote.” That is what has happened.
The hon. Member for South Derbyshire may well think that the national interest is best served by the Labour party reneging on its manifesto promise. I think the national interest would be served by the Labour party reneging on a huge number of its promises—I can think of few of its promises that do serve the national interest. However, if that is what the hon. Gentleman thinks, that is what he should say, explicitly. At the moment the Labour party has hidden behind the claim that it has not broken the promise at all. I would argue that it has, although it may make the point that it was desirable to do so.
Mr. David Gauke (South-West Hertfordshire) (Con): The hon. Gentleman may be being a little unfair on this point. I did a radio interview with the Financial Secretary on LBC on the night of the Budget, and he confirmed that the measure was a breach of the manifesto pledge.
Mr. Jeremy Browne: In that case I apologise if I have not given full credit to the Government for admitting their own failings. It is right for us to recognise that point.
The first point that we can reasonably dwell upon, which I have done, is the broken promise from the 2005 election manifesto. The second point, also touched upon by the hon. Member for Hammersmith and Fulham, was the chaotic manner in which the Government sought to bring in what they now call not a higher rate but an additional rate of taxation. There is a lower rate and a higher rate, and one could be forgiven for thinking that the higher rate was as high as it got, but then there is an additional rate on top of that. Some people pay a marginal rate significantly higher than not just the higher rate, but the additional rate.
What has been so strikingly chaotic about the Government’s approach? They made a promise that the 40p rate would be stuck to for the lifetime of the Parliament. They came up with a whole new tax rate—45p—but made sure that the manifesto commitment was not breached by only putting that 45p rate into effect after the last possible date for a general election. However, before the 45p had been put into effect, the Government came up with a new 50p rate, to be put into effect before the possible end of this Parliament. It is entirely reasonable, when looking at the Government, to find it hard to conclude what they are going to do next. That is damaging for confidence and for anyone planning to set up a business or create wealth in some other way in this country.
The other point, examined in detail by the hon. Member for Hammersmith and Fulham, is that it is dubious whether the measure will raise the revenue that has been claimed for it. Many people estimate that the yield will be about one third of what it would be if there was no behavioural change, so the total revenue that the Government are going to raise as a consequence of the 50p tax rate pales almost into insignificance compared with the £175 billion of public borrowing—almost £0.5 billion every day—that we are currently suffering.
There will be £173 billion of public borrowing next year and £140 billion the year after, assuming the rather heroic growth rates forecast for the economy as a whole, a forecast which seems not to be shared by many commentators. The Chancellor is unlikely to be in place to see whether his predictions come true, but I fear—it is not in the national interest for this to be the case—that he may be shown to be rather optimistic. The Government are borrowing more money this year and next year than the total Budget in the first year that the Prime Minister was Chancellor—total public spending then was less than two years’ borrowing today. Against that backdrop, the amount of revenue raised by a 50p tax rate, even if there were no behavioural change, would be fairly modest. However, if two thirds of the revenue drains away as a result of behavioural change, the central argument for the 50p rate, which is that the extra revenue is necessary and justified because of the scale of the Budget deficit, would seem to be unjustified.
As the hon. Member for Hammersmith and Fulham also said, tax avoidance will be further incentivised by the greater differential between the rate of capital gains tax and the top rate of income tax. Of course, there was a big incentive when the top rate of income tax was more than double the CGT rate, but now that the top rate is 10 per cent. higher, I assume that large numbers of people will avoid paying it not by relocating to another country—although that may happen with some star footballers and others whose labour is demanded internationally, and who can travel easily from one employer to another—but by choosing to receive their pay in forms that attract lower rates of taxation. Morally, that may not be particularly impressive, but people are given a greater incentive to do it, entirely legally. The Government are to some extent colluding in that process by further incentivising those people.
I have two final points. The Financial Secretary said in his opening remarks that it was only right that the people who benefited from economic growth should pay more now that the economy is shrinking. That is not the economic case for the extra, 50p rate, which, I maintain, is far from attractive or compelling, but what Labour MPs regard as the moral case—I think it was called the “ethical” case—for the 50p tax rate. The case is that when times are good, some people make a lot of money and therefore, when times are bad, they should be asked to contribute more. I have two things to say to that. First, those who are earning the most money already contribute a much bigger percentage of the total national income tax take than their numbers would otherwise indicate. One could argue that they should contribute more or that they should contribute less, but it is misleading to suggest that the top 1 or 2 per cent. of earners are not contributing in a substantial and meaningful way to the public finances; they most certainly are.
Secondly, one should not necessarily assume that people who will be earning in excess of £150,000 from next year onwards benefited during the period of economic growth. Someone could set up a company, having spent the last 10 years in low-paid employment, and the company could be so successful at capturing the mood of the country and attracting lots of customers that they were able to create lots of jobs and expand. If by about this time next year they managed to be on a salary that was in excess of £150,000, they would be hit by that 50 per cent. rate, despite never having benefited at a higher level of income during the time when the economy was growing.
Others may have been earning huge amounts of money, by my modest standards, for years and years but have now stopped working. They may have retired. They may have spent their money on an enormous house, or perhaps a series of enormous houses and all kinds of other rewards because of their years of success in the benign economic circumstances and have now decided to stop working. They will not be taxed on the basis that they were able to buy a very expensive house because they made so much money when the economy was growing for the last 10 or 15 years. They may be taxed in other forms, but not on their income. Those people will have paid a 40p tax rate when the economy was thriving and they will not pay the 50p rate because they will not be paying income tax, or not necessarily at that level when the proposal is introduced. So I do not accept that the ethical point automatically applies in this case as Labour Members appear to suggest.
Finally, it is reasonable to ask what the rationale is for 50 as opposed to any other figure. The Chancellor himself admitted—I think it was in the Treasury Committee—that there was no rationale and that the figure was plucked out of the air. That is a surprise because a lot of economic modelling and forecasting seeks to work out the point at which the revenue to the Exchequer is maximised. One would have thought that those considerations would have come into play when the Chancellor and other Treasury Ministers were deciding what was an appropriate rate at which to set this higher level of taxation.
My suspicion is that 50p was picked for the obvious reason that it is half and that there is a sense, probably in the Government and maybe in other political quarters too, that a line is crossed at the point where the Government take more of a person’s income than they are left to spend for themselves. Therefore the 50p is a sort of self-imposed moral line in the sand which MPs and other politicians, probably of all parties but perhaps in the Labour party as much as any, feel is as far as it is acceptable to go before it becomes unreasonable for the state to take that much private income.
 
Previous Contents Continue
House of Commons 
home page Parliament home page House of 
Lords home page search page enquiries ordering index

©Parliamentary copyright 2009
Prepared 20 May 2009