Finance Bill


[back to previous text]

Mr. Field: That was an interesting contribution from the hon. Gentleman. I, too, shall be a little more candid than perhaps is entirely wise. I hope that no one on this side of the Committee will be too hard on me.
Luckily, some of us do not have second homes—well, actually, I do have a second home, but it was paid for entirely out of my own resources rather than anyone else’s. About eight years after becoming a Member of Parliament, I have discovered that there are some benefits in representing an inner-London constituency that were not immediately apparent when a variety of scams were being operated outside the public gaze.
I agreed with much of the hon. Gentleman’s contribution, and if the under-30s were twice as likely to vote as the over-55s, rather than the other way round, I would bet that all Governments would do a lot more to tackle the problems of housing supply. The reality is that it has been a political issue, as much as anything else, to maintain a relatively buoyant housing market, not least because those who are twice as likely to vote—the over-55s, rather than the youngsters—also tend to be home owners and their wishes have to be considered to a large degree.
I also agree with the main thrust of the hon. Gentleman’s argument: realistically, there is not much that most Governments can do. We have a ludicrously complicated system of property in this country, and adding layer upon layer of complication does not make things any easier. I agree with our new clause 3 and think that it is fine, but it would work only slightly, at the margins.
We already have in this country a capital gains tax exemption for main homes. That ludicrous distortion has a knock-on effect, as the hon. Gentleman rightly pointed out, in relation to investment for small business, and it is in great contrast to the regime in many European countries. Many elements of stamp duty land tax further distort the distortion, and that is regrettable in many ways. For many people, property has become the most important asset. I do not want to see peoples’ aspirations cast aside, but let us be absolutely honest about it: home ownership, given the chaotic lifestyles and earning patterns of many people, should not necessarily be regarded as a right.
Mr. Todd: The hon. Gentleman is making an extremely interesting speech, which I have to assume does not reflect current Conservative policy. I am sure that he has read about extraordinarily advanced societies in western Europe where home ownership is far less prevalent and less sought after—for example, Germany and Switzerland—and of very poor societies where home ownership in is sought after but to no effect. We seem to have an unusual fixation.
Mr. Field: We do have that fixation. Let us be honest, home ownership provides stability and, potentially, collateral for doing other things—or it has done in the past. The crux of some of the present financial problems is in the sub-prime market and the idea from the mid-90s in Clinton Democrat America that home ownership should be encouraged. The financial services industry in the United States created products for people who should never have owned property, given their chaotic earning patterns, and I sense that we risk the same happening here.
An Englishman’s home is his castle—a great aspiration. As someone who bought their first property at the earliest opportunity, at 23, I would not say that people should not aspire to it, but we have to realise that for many people it can be a mirage. They go down a path to property ownership and quickly find that it is more of a shackle than a benefit. Part of the difficulty has been that miss-selling and poor returns has shattered the savings and pensions industry’s reputation, so it was logical for many people—
The Chairman: Order. I apologise for interrupting the hon. Gentleman. He is making a very interesting speech, but it is meant to be about stamp duty land tax.
Mr. Field: It is fair enough that you pulled me up, Mr. Atkinson, but the point I was trying to make was that there has been a herd-like mentality—a logical one, particularly for those in their 20s and 30s—to aspire to own property. I am not apportioning blame—this is about the political establishment, although probably not as far back as the last Liberal Government. Even the hon. Member for Taunton will acknowledge that successive Governments have found ways to complicate the system ever more. I am not suggesting that we can start with a blank sheet of paper, because that, inevitably, is difficult. We have a crazily complicated system for housing. The notion that a main home is a capital gains tax-free investment is not prevalent around the world and is perhaps peculiar to this country. It has been a huge distortion, which has, obviously, led to tinkering with stamp duty land tax.
I wanted to make only a brief contribution. I am comfortable agreeing to new clause 3, but ideally we, the whole political class, would have the benefit of a more open and broad debate which considered the distortions, the public’s aspirations and why our system is different. I suspect that historical reasons surround the disparity between the situation here and that which pertains in other European countries, as the hon. Member for South Derbyshire points out.
Mr. Jeremy Browne: The hon. Gentleman is making an interesting speech about not assuming that owning a house is a right and about downsides as well as upsides to property ownership. However, I would not wish anyone to infer from what I said that I was hostile to people’s aspirations. I observe only that those who say how desirable it would be for more people to rent rather than own property almost invariably own property themselves.
Mr. Field: I agree, and I am not downplaying people’s aspirations. If one reads The Sunday Times money pages, as we all do, every week people say that their best investment has been property, and over a 30 or 40-year period that seemed to be the case. With lower interest rates and political pressures, which make bringing supply and demand together difficult, that may not be the case for years to come. For the first seven of the 20 years that I have owned property, between 1988 and 1995, there was no capital gain, and of course since 1995 up until the last year or two, property has been a terrifically good investment.
2.30 pm
We are tinkering at the edges and there needs to be a more sensible debate, beyond a slanging match between political parties that suggests that one side does not look to help first-time or aspiring buyers. Such a slanging match takes out some of the real problems that we all face with planning applications in our constituencies—well, I probably do not. Many more properties need to be built, but ideally some five or 10 miles outside my constituency, from where we will reap the benefits but not get any of the downside. I hope that we can have sensible debates on the matter in the future, and that sense will prevail and new clause 3 will be added to the Bill. However, I suspect that that will be another hope and aspiration that will not be fulfilled, at least not now.
Ian Pearson: I shall respond briefly and try to focus my remarks precisely on new clause 3 and clause 10. I do not want to go over old ground with the hon. Member for South-West Hertfordshire, regarding some of the comments that appeared in the press last August. However, I want to emphasise that, although the press speculate daily on many aspects of Government policy, that does not make them right. As I said at the time, the press comments were unhelpful. I do not feel the need to say anything more on the matter, but I would like to respond to some of the hon. Gentleman more substantive points.
I confirm that the estimated impact of the holiday on the Exchequer is £340 million, which includes the cost of the extension announced in the Budget. It is right to say that we have looked closely at the costs. It is not possible to estimate precisely the impact on transactions because we are dealing with a counter-factual situation—what would have happened in the absence of a stamp duty land tax holiday. In the pre-Budget report we said that the figure was £280 million and we revised that down in the Budget to £250 million plus the extra £90 million for the September to December 2009 extension. On the hon. Gentleman’s comments on disadvantaged areas, there is no need to disapply the £150,000 figure because the £175,000 threshold makes that unnecessary. However, once the holiday ends, policy will go back to what it was, and the limits will be £125,000 generally and £150,000 in disadvantaged areas.
Mr. Hands: Has the Economic Secretary looked at the example of Australia? He mentioned Ireland, but I understand that Australia successfully introduced a similar scheme.
Ian Pearson: My officials are certainly aware of the Australian scheme and have looked extensively at a number of issues.
Mr. Hands: Will the Economic Secretary give way?
Ian Pearson: I am not saying that it is impossible to do so, but I am pointing out that it is not as simple and straightforward as was perhaps suggested by the hon. Member for South-West Hertfordshire when he moved the new clause.
Mr. Hands: I thank the Economic Secretary for giving way again; he is being most generous. He says that his officials looked at the Australian example extensively. Surely after such a considerable look, they must have come up with some conclusions or lessons that could be learned.
Ian Pearson: We believe that the policy of the holiday that we introduced on 2 September is targeted, temporary and timely. It was right in the circumstances not to favour first-time buyers over other buyers of properties with a value lower than £175,000.
The hon. Member for Taunton’s interesting speech covered many areas and not just his concerns over first-time buyers. He spoke of other factors that people take account of when buying a home. Everybody recognises that people take many circumstances into account when considering a house purchase. Even following his lengthy speech, I am not sure whether he is in favour of the principle of a stamp duty holiday or even of a stamp duty threshold. The Government have made it clear that we see this measure as temporary and targeted.
I will respond briefly to the hon. Member for Cities of London and Westminster. I do not wish to speak about his comments on capital gains tax, but I do want to rebut his implied criticism of Government policy. It has not been an instrument of Government policy, as he seemed to suggest, to keep house prices high to help over-50s because they are more likely to vote than under-30s. On the contrary, the Government have set extremely ambitious house building targets, which have been alluded to. We want those targets to be met. We want people to be able to rent or buy the roof over their heads. That is Government policy.
Mr. Stuart: I am surprised that the Liberal Democrat spokesman did not leap to his feet. Just for the elimination of doubt, it was clear to me from what he said that he was utterly opposed to special relief for first-time buyers. He thought that it was impracticable and we seem to be opposed to it in principle.
Ian Pearson: The hon. Member for Taunton has put his comments on the record. I happily give way to him.
Mr. Browne: For the avoidance of doubt, if the Conservative party comes up with coherent, well-researched, thought-through and practical policies that would be of benefit to my constituents, I will be sympathetic to them. However, it would be embarrassing for the Conservative party and the country if policies such as new clause 3 were included in the Finance Bill.
Ian Pearson: For the reasons I explained in my introductory remarks, I do not believe that new clause 3 should be supported. It would not be effective. If the hon. Member for South-West Hertfordshire presses it to a vote, I invite my colleagues to oppose it and to support clause 10.
Mr. Gauke: I do not intend to go over the debate again. I appreciate that we will not vote immediately on the new clause. I am not persuaded by the Minister’s comments. I note he said that it is not impossible for first-time buyers to be defined. When there is an opportunity, we will press new clause 3 to a vote.
Question put and agreed to.
Clause 10 accordingly ordered to stand part of the Bill.

Clause 12

Rates of tobacco products duty
Question proposed, That the clause stand part of the Bill.
Mr. Hands: May I begin by welcoming you back to the Chair, Mr. Atkinson?
Clause 12 relates to the levels of tobacco duty, which are superficially not particularly controversial. We do not oppose the increases in duty. However, a number of questions need to be asked about the Government’s approach to the structure of tobacco duty and I hope the Minister will provide some answers in her response. The effect of duty increases on illegal supplies is also a concern, particularly if sterling recovers ground against the euro.
For those less familiar with the structure of tobacco duty, I will briefly run through it—partly because it is more complicated than one might initially expect. I was a smoker for some years and used to await the announcement of the Budget and the number of pence it put on a packet of cigarettes. I imagined that the way it was arrived at was very simplistic; it is actually quite complicated.
There are two specific parts to tobacco duty. The first is called a specific duty, which is a set amount of duty. It translates into duty on a per-packet basis, but is assessed on a number of pounds per 1,000 cigarettes. As we see in clause 12, that is to rise to £114.31 per 1,000 cigarettes, up from £112.07 prior to 22 April. That is a rise of two per cent., which translates to the average packet of cigarettes—an interesting concept that I will come back to—to approximately £2.29 of specific duty.
Added to that is the ad valorem element, which is a percentage of the total price of the retail price of a packet of cigarettes. That was increased in the pre-Budget report from 22 per cent. to 24 per cent. That is important for our considerations, because that percentage is calculated after that has been applied to a packet.
As with the alcohol duties that we debated a couple of weeks ago, the context of clause 12 is last November’s pre-Budget report and the Government’s late-in-the-day efforts to offset the revenue they were going to lose through the cut in VAT by increasing tobacco duties. In the case of tobacco, it raised the ad valorem element of the duty on cigarettes by 2 per cent. to a total of 24 per cent.
The two figures were designed to be roughly equivalent, with the fall in VAT and the rise in ad valorem more or less offsetting each other when fed through to a change in the retail price of a packet of cigarettes. The pre-Budget report left the specific fix element of the duty unaltered and that change corresponded quite well to the VAT loss. However, like the alcohol duties when VAT returns to 17.5 per cent. in January 2010, there will be some important and significant effects on the overall pricing level of cigarettes.
It corresponded with the pre-Budget report because the ad valorem duty, as I have explained, is a proportional tax on the retail price of cigarettes. However, it has a unique feature: because it is a tax on the price of a packet of cigarettes, including the margin for the specific duty under VAT, this is a tax that taxes tax. In other words, the percentage of ad valorem is applied to VAT and other charges. There is therefore a consequent multiplier effect on the amount of tax paid as the cost of a packet of cigarettes increases.
That might seem esoteric, and perhaps not particularly relevant, but it has important consequences for the market price of a packet of cigarettes: the ad valorem duty widens the differential between the tax on cheaper brands and the tax on premium brands. That was true, of course, well before the pre-Budget report came along. The price gap between the cheapest cigarettes and premium brands, such as Marlboro or Rothmans, has increased from less than a pound to nearly two pounds in the last six years—a considerable change so far this decade.
The increasing element to the ad valorem tax has incentivised the new super low-priced brands that have either been around for many years, or those that have entered or re-entered the market, such as Pall Mall.
 
Previous Contents Continue
House of Commons 
home page Parliament home page House of 
Lords home page search page enquiries ordering index

©Parliamentary copyright 2009
Prepared 22 May 2009