Memorandum submitted by Dr Paul Benneworth,
Newcastle University
INTRODUCTION AND
SUMMARY
1. The Business and Enterprise Select Committee
have recently announced an Inquiry into the future roles and responsibilities
for regional development agencies. I welcome this Inquiry as a
timely opportunity to reflect on a decade of attempts to address
the "delivery deficit" in the English regions outside
London (where there is a directly elected Mayor). I am a Research
Councils UK Academic Fellow in "Territorial Governance"
at Newcastle University, and submit this evidence as part of RCUK's
commitment to outreach work by its fellows.
2. I can fairly claim to be one of the first
people in England active in researching the eight English RDAs
created by the 1998 Regional Development Agencies Act. I wrote
a bi-monthly column for the Regions magazine from the time
that the Act was passed into law until 2003. These columns were
later published by the Regional Studies Association as the book
Regional Development Agencies: the early years. I was subsequently
funded by the RDAs individually and collectively to undertake
very small amounts of consultancy for them[29].
I was also funded by two regional assemblies (the North East and
North West) to support their scrutiny activity. My evidence is
informed by all this work, with various elements (developed with
colleagues at Newcastle University) presented to previous Parliamentary
Inquiries[30].
3. In this memorandum, I argue that the
RDAs suffer from an image worse than their performance justifies,
and contemporary calls for their abolition are driven as much
by a drive for revenge as dispassionate analysis (paras 4-5).
I argue that the continuing salience elsewhere for a regional
approach to economic development implies its continuing significance
for the English regions (paras 6-12). RDAs are indisputably an
improvement on the way that spatial policy was previously carried
out (paras 13-23). RDAs have delivered strategic projects in the
regions with wider national benefit, but which would fall between
the "silos" of Whitehall ministerial thinking (paras
24-35). However, not all functions are suitable for RDAs to execute:
both small business support and regional spatial strategic functions
are too different from RDAs' core integrative roles to sensibly
be executed by RDAs (para 36-44).
PREAMBLE
4. There is clearly a gap between the performance
of Regional Development Agencies and the way they are perceived
by key stakeholders. In comparison with the piecemeal institutional
framework which preceded them, the RDAs are qualitatively better
in ensuring all the English regional economies contribute to the
national wellbeing. However, it is a problem that the RDAs have
made some very simple and largely inconsequential mistakes which
have apparently generated a disproportionate level of ill-feeling
towards them.[31]
There also appears to be in some recent publications a sense of
revenge, that the very idea of regions is part of an overall political
project very much in retreat. RDAs may well become the early sacrificial
victims satisfying a demand for visible signs of change around
a wider political watershed, which will be demonstrably very harmful
for the northern regions.
5. Some analogies can be drawn between the
current situation and that in Wales in the early 2000s. The Welsh
Development Agency (WDA) were initially very dismissive of the
newly elected Welsh Assembly Government (WAG) and there were some
ill-timed salary increase announcements. This contributed to the
decision by Rhodri Morgan's decision to bring the WDA within the
Welsh "bonfire of the quangos".[32]
In this memorandum, I will argue that the RDAs perform a vital
administrative function with national economic benefit. Launching
into another round of administrative reforms, and especially abolition,
has risks not just for the regions but also for the national economic
interest.
THE NEED
FOR A
REGIONAL ECONOMIC
DEVELOPMENT TIER
RDAs in an international comparative perspective.
6. There is an increasing recognition of
the increasing importance of "place" to economic activity.
As innovation becomes central to economic performance, and inter-personal
interaction is vital for innovation, regions are increasingly
important as the "natural scales" for interpersonal
interaction, innovation and competitiveness.
7. Regions are also the natural scale for
the exploitation of strategic infrastructure such as airports,
hospitals and universities. The interaction between these investments,
often located in core urban areas, and the potential beneficiaries
in their hinterlands, requires that public bodies ensure that
these infrastructures' benefits are spread as far as possible.
8. An increasing number of governments recognise
the need for a sub-national tier to optimise policy delivery within
in these "natural" regions, both for the benefit of
the regions, and also for the nations of which they are part.
9. Professor Mike Danson (University of
the West of Scotland) and Professor Henrik Halkier (University
of Aalborg, Denmark) are the leading European experts on the purposes,
functions and roles of regional development agencies.[33]
Danson & Halkier emphasise that effective RDAs occupy a middle
ground between top-down central approaches and local bottom-up
mobilisations. They are creatures of neither local nor national
government, but a means to ensure that each benefits as far as
possible from the other's policies.
10. In the last decade, there has been a
substantive shift in the tasks undertaken by European RDAs, from
helping local businesses to create jobs, to improving regional
capacity for supporting innovative, high growth or high-growth
potential businesses.[34]
In practice, this involves ensuring that business support offered
helps small, innovative companies to be formed and to grow by
local entrepreneurs working with global networks of knowledge
suppliers.
11. However, what has not changed about
effective RDAs is that what makes them successful are the long-term
relationships that they establish. These relationships enable
RDAs to national policies work better locally, to respond to external
shocks such as factory closures, and to take (or advise impartially
on) difficult decisions between competing local interests.
12. But RDAs are not just agents for central
governmentas well as implementing national policies, they
also help national departments to make policy that better reflects
the needs of all its regions by acting as repositories of knowledge
about the economic situation in their regions.[35]
The demand for a regional English economic development
tier
13. There are three main economic rationales
for why England needs RDAs, which are similar to the rationales
for regions elsewhere in Europe outlined above.
14. The first is that England is a very
big country, and different places face different challenges: RDAs
can tailor national economic development policies to regional
needs and responsiveness to these policy measures.[36]
15. The second is that there are persistent
economic disparities between the English regions, which undermine
England's overall economic performance. Regional institutions
provide a means to target this "regional growth gap".[37]
16. Thirdly, RDAs can ensure the most effective
public decision-making concerning flagship infrastructure investments
ensuring that all localities can benefit from these regional prize
assets, and advising nationally on the optimal location for these
assets.
17. England's administration remains as
heavily centralised as a decade agothe Public Service Agreement
process has subjected increasing numbers of publically-funded
bodies to meeting centrally directed targets. These three rationales
remain as important for effective policy delivery today as they
did a decade ago when the RDAs were created.
18. It is reasonable to ask how effectively
the RDAs have realised these potential benefits: that question
will be addressed in subsequent sections. However, there does
not appear to be a diminishment in the a priori case justifying
RDAs as a solution to deep-seated regional economic inequalities
limiting national economic performance.
19. One of the key debates which is still
salient is whether every region needs an RDAparticularly
the richer south eastern regionsif their purpose is to
"level up" poorer regions' performance towards the national
average. There are arguments both for and against the present
situation. I certainly follow Professor Kevin Morgan's maxim (Cardiff
University) that treating "unequals equally is hardly a recipe
for promoting equality".[38]
20. However, we also have sympathy with
the axiom that "services for the poor easily become poor
services": a policy focused on England's poorer regions could
easily become a poor regional policy. Having RDAs for all English
regions ensures that regional policy is not seen by central government
as something exceptional, but as something with salience for all
departments. This ensures that regional policy expenditures are
seen as investing in places' competitive potential (which are
a sensible use of public funds) rather than subsidies for past
failure (which are not).
RDAs contributions to effective national policy-making
21. This is not a hypothetical situationthere
are areas where the eight RDAs acting in concert have improved
UK policy-making by placing something on the national policy agenda.
The most obvious example of this is what is now called PSA 7,
namely to "improve the economic performance of all English
regions and reduce the gap in economic growth rates between regions".
This is a highly contentious PSA target for Whitehall ministries
because it runs counter to the notion of intervening only in market
failures.[39]
It has also been very difficult to operationalise, because of
a series of technical issues around how to fairly measure gaps
in regional economic growth rates.
22. In CSR2000, there was a much weaker
(in terms of implied economic rebalancing) target set for the
(then departments) DTI and ODPM to raise the average economic
growth rates of all regions and nations. The RDAs worked closely
with DTI to demonstrate that this target could be operationalised
and measured, and would not become a Trojan Horse for arguing
for directly redistributive regional policies.
23. The shift between this easy PSA and
the much more substantial 2002 PSA, in the 2002 CSR reflects this
work by the RDAs which laid the foundation for the more substantial
commitment, to closing divergence in growth rates. Working with
the Government departments, they were able to address a problem
that had long been regarded in government as "too difficult"
and contribute to more sensible public policy-making though the
Spending Review process. Having a network of development agencies
covering all regions allowed the RDAs to reflect a national position
from a regional perspective, rather than being seen as special
interest pleading from failing regions.
THE EFFECTIVENESS
AND ADDED
VALUE OF
RDAS
24. In assessing the effectiveness and added
value of the RDAs, it is not my intention to look at the detail
of RDAs' value for money, as they were given a clean bill of health
by the National Audit Office as recently as 2007, a fact that
has been overlooked in much of the recent criticism of the RDAs.[40]
It is more instructive to consider how their organisational characteristics
and performance compares as against the organisations they replaced.
25. The RDAs (outside London) were created
from a number of antecedent organisations which were merged, depending
on which bodies were already present in the region. These bodies
included residual bodies of urban development corporations, Government
Office Regeneration teams, Inward Investment promotion bodies
and the Rural Development Commission.[41]
26. Prior to 1994, urban policy had been
a highly fragmented policy area, criticised for lacking a systematic
approach to dealing with the problems of poorer areas, often tackling
particular symptoms of deprivation without addressing its root
causes.[42]
One set of bodies which had avoided that criticism were the Urban
Development Corporations, which focused on comprehensive redevelopment
of highly localised land-parcels with special planning powers
to rehabilitate the land and facilitate urban land markets.[43]
A number of them had been relatively successful in developing
large multi-functional projects but these were often criticised
for failing to relate to local needs or support local business
activities, a result of their very narrowly specialised management
teams.[44]
27. The Single Regeneration Budget (SRB)
was introduced in 1994 in response to these criticisms of existing
urban regeneration policies. SRB introduced the opportunity for
a single regional authority to organise proposals into coherent
work programmes, avoid the situation where new programmes were
introduced to deal with the problems arising from past policy
interventions, and ensure that activities delivered a balanced
score-card of outcomes. What the SRB programme did not do was
use the funds as an investment tool to create wider regional spill-over
effects which addressed local deprivation more systematically.
It remained almost entirely focused on solving the problems of
the country's most deprived localities.
28. For the first three years of their existence,
RDAs budgets were primarily those inherited from the antecedent
organisations, and consequently SRB funds. These prior commitments
largely prevented the RDAs from supporting regeneration activities
embedded within "urban science policy". Underlying urban
science policy is the concept of using investments in science,
technology and innovationin an urban settingto drive
wider regeneration activities. Building a new science quarter
amidst or adjacent to pockets urban deprivation has proven a very
effective driver of gentrification. RDAs initially did not have
the budget flexibility or indeed the budget to invest in these
kinds of flagship activities.
29. Notable European examples include the
22@ Quarter in Barcelona[45]
or the "Västra Hamnen" district of Malmðöñ,
Sweden. Urban Development Corporations were successful in this;
in the North East, Tyne and Wear Development Corporation provided
new inner city campuses for Sunderland and Newcastle Universities
respectively at St. Peters and the Life Centre. European Union
structural funds played a similar role in the Objective 1 regions,
Merseyside and South Yorkshire, notably the Cornerstone campus
of Liverpool Hope University in Everton.
30. In 2002, in response to perceptions
within senior Government politicians that RDAs were achieving
their objectives, RDAs were granted the Single Programme Budget,
the so-called Single Pot. In return for agreeing a single set
of targets with central Departments, the RDAs were given considerable
freedom to spend their resources according to their own choosing.
This opened up the possibility of investing resources in large-scale
projects serving multiple aims, such as regeneration and innovation.
31. The RDAs received an additional encouragement
to engage in urban science policy in December 2004, when the then-Chancellor
of the Exchequer announced the designation of three "science
cities", Manchester, York and Newcastle.[46]
This group was later joined by three more southerly science cities,
namely Bristol, Nottingham and Birmingham. However, despite the
rhetoric of a "£100 million technology investment programme",
no new central funds were forthcoming.
32. Nevertheless, all six of these regions have
developed "science city partnerships" of some form.
Manchester Knowledge Capital (the Science City body) has won significant
funds from the National Endowment for Science, Technology and
the Arts (NESTA) to evaluate the generic benefits of urban science
policy exemplified by MKC. In Newcastle, the RDA, University and
city council have invested £30m in a city-centre regeneration
site to build a new knowledge marketplace bringing universities
and businesses together adjacent to poor localities.
33. These science city projects could not
have been funded under SRB, because they concentrate resources
in central urban locations rather than sharing them between all
locations. They would not have been funded by Urban Development
Corporations, because they lacked the depth of senior management
to juggle relationships with local firms, universities, municipalities,
hospitals and other bodies. National government would not have
funded them because urban science policy falls between too many
policy silos (science, industry, education and regeneration).
34. RDAs' effective adoption of an approach
proven elsewhere but unsupported by other institutional arrangements
demonstrates without question that RDAs can and do add value to
policy-making with overall national economic benefits.
THE ACQUISITION
AND DISCHARGE
OF NEW
FUNCTIONS BY
RDAS
35. The RDAs have acquired considerable
new functions since their formal investiture in 1999. There have
been two quite distinct rationales underpinning this build-up
of responsibilities. On the one hand, before 2004, DETR/DTLR/
ODPM sought to make RDAs the lead bodies for economic development
in regions, so that RDAs could provide the kernel of an executive
arm for elected regional authorities (ERAs). On the other, RDAs
acquired some functions as a consequence of the continual reforms
to which the general "machinery of government" has been
subjected in the last 11 years.[47]
In both cases, this has left the RDAs exercising some functions
for which there is no longer a clear rationale for them to exercise.
There is a also some ambiguity between whether RDAs are strategic
or operational bodies.
36. One of the most trenchant recent criticisms
of RDAs in recent months has been levied by the Opposition Industry
Spokesman.[48]
To paraphrase his words, the needs of small business support show
as much variation within regions as between regions, and what
is important is quality and consistency of delivery rather than
regional oversight of services. I wholeheartedly concur with this
point, but do not concede that this is an argument against RDAs.
The blame for this clearly lies with continual central government
tinkering with the Business Link and Small Business Service organisations.
Business support is an operational matter and it is probably better
delivered to national quality standards,[49]
but remains just one small element of what RDAs do, and is largely
irrelevant to their strategic, joining-up missions.
RDAs as regional planning authorities
37. The 2007 Sub-National Review was concerned
with rectifying inconsistencies at the regional level created
by the rejection of elected regional assemblies (ERAs) for England.
The "no" vote in the one region which did vote (78%
no in the North East of England) was of such ferocity to warrant
dismantling the structures created in anticipation of ERAs. The
1998 Act established Regional Chambers in each region to scrutinise
the work of the RDAs. The Regional Chambers contain a mix of elected
members and stakeholder representatives, and only made sense as
shadow bodies for ERAs. The 2002 White Paper designated them as
the statutory planning authorities for their regions, replacing
the Regional Planning Conferences.[50]
38. The sub-national review plans to disband
the Assemblies (or de-recognise them) and pass regional planning
powers to RDAs. This proposal is intuitively attractive, as RDAs
will be given the power to produce integrated regional strategies
bringing land use planning together with transport and economic
strategies. When I once highlighted the potential value of integrated
regional strategies as a valuable tool for improving regional
governance, my co-authors and I did not envisage a model where
a single body was responsible for all strategies.[51]
39. I see little merit in proposals to pass
regional planning powers to the Regional Development Agencies,
and envisage serious problems if this proposal is not moderated.
40. I anticipate that the UK's professional
planning bodies will be commenting on this specific proposal,
and do not wish to detract from their points. I would underline
the fact that RDAs Regional Economic Strategies follow very different
principles to regional spatial strategies. Regional Economic Strategies
are written to satisfy a bewildering complex of stakeholders,
and have held back from making hard decisions in favour of demonstrating
regional consensus and promoting a positive rather than critical
regional image.
41. The 2003 Regional Economic Strategy
for the North East of England identified 38 "strategic sites"
for economic development in the region.[52]
This large number was driven by a desire to ensure that all local
authorities with spare land parcels felt they would be eligible
for RDA support if a large inward investor proposed developing
the site. Whatever the rationale behind the designation, it was
not "strategic" in a way that land user planners would
acknowledge, namely a site whose development would stimulate pan-regional
economic development.
42. Taking hard decisions and being prepared
to talk critically about the region and differences between localities
lies at the heart of effective spatial planning. They create a
set of principles in which conflicts over land use are mediated,
recognising that development creates winners and losers, and it
is important to maximise the public gain from private developments.
These are not principles to which the RDAs have yet had to address
themselves, and there are potentials for conflicts between dispassionate
spatial strategy development and the more "boosterist"
elements of the RDAs' work.
43. I have grave reservations about RDAs'
to impose regional spatial strategies with the degree of firmness
necessary to provide a robust conflict resolution mechanism which
ensures the maximisation of the public benefit.
19 September 2008
29 Benneworth, P. S. & ONE (2004) "Memorandum
of evidence on The Draft Regional Assemblies Bill"
in The Draft Regional Assemblies Bill Office of the Deputy
Prime Minister: Housing, Planning, Local Government and the Regions
Inquiry, London: The Stationary Office. Back
30
For example to Regional Development Agencies, Environment,
Transport & Regions Select Committee Inquiry (1999); Science
and the Regional Development Agencies, Lords Science and Technology
Sub-Committee B Inquiry (2003); Reducing Regional Disparities
in Prosperity, Office of the Deputy Prime Minister: Housing,
Planning, Local Government and the Regions Inquiry (2003); and,
What future is there for regional government, Office of
the Deputy Prime Minister: Housing, Planning, Local Government
and the Regions Inquiry (2006). Back
31
Stimulating for example criticism from the Taxpayers' Alliance
and Policy Exchange in August 2008. Back
32
Source: contemporaneous note of conversation with Anonymous WDA
official, 28 September 2004. Back
33
Cf. Halkier, H., Danson, M. & Damborg, C. (1998) (Eds)
Regional development agencies in Europe, London: Jessica
Kingsley. Back
34
Cf.. Halkier, H. (2006) "Regional development agencies
and multi-level governance: European perspectives" paper
presented to Regional Development and Governance Symposium,
Ankara, Turkey, September 7th-8th 2006. Back
35
Benneworth, P. (2007) Leading Innovation: Building effective
regional coalitions for innovation, London: National Endowment
for Science, Technology and the Arts. Back
36
H M Treasury (2001) Productivity in the UK: 3-The Regional
Dimension, H M Treasury, London. Back
37
HM Treasury (2004) Stability, Security and Opportunity for
All: Investing for Britain's long-term future, London: HM
Treasury. Back
38
Morgan, K. (2002), "The English Question. Regional Perspectives
on a Fractured Nation", Regional Studies, 36 (7) pp
797-810, citation from page 804. Back
39
The Green Book Back
40
National Audit Office Report (HC 1268, 2003-04): Success in
the Regions. In 2006-07, NAO performed Independent
Performance Assessments of all eight RDAs: two were adjudged as
performing well overall, and six as performing strongly overall.
The scores (out of 24) for the eight RDAs were EEDA 15, SWRDA
18, AWM 20, YF, 20 NWDA, 20, SEEDA 21, ONE 22, EMDA 22. Back
41
Benneworth, P S. (2001) Regional Development Agencies-their
early years 1998-2001, Seaford: Regional Studies Association. Back
42
Robson, B, Bradford, M, Deas, I, Hall, E, Harrison, E, Parkinson,
M, Evans, R, Garside, P, Harding, H and Robinson, F. (1994) Assessing
the impact of urban policy London: Her Majesty's Stationary
Office; Back
43
National Audit Office (1994) The achievements of the second-
and third-generation urban development corporations, London:
HMSO. Back
44
Inter alia Robinson, F., Lawrence, M., Shaw, K (1993),
More than Bricks and Mortar, University of Durham for the
Joseph Rowntree Trust; Hansard 1803 14 January 1998 Col 459 "Teesside
Development Corporation"; National Audit Office (2002) The
operation and wind up of Teesside Development Corporation,
HMSO: NAO. Back
45
Clos, O. (2004) "The transformation of Poblenou: the new
22@ District". In Transforming Barcelona, ed T Marshall.
Routledge, London and New York. Back
46
Hansard, 2 December 2004, Col. 782. Back
47
The latest being the Sub-National Review (2007) Back
48
Duncan, A. (2008) "The future for regional policy. What's
best for British business" Speech to the Policy Exchange,
London, England, 30 June 2008. Available on-line at www.policyexchange.org.uk/Events.aspx?id=655 Back
49
It is important also to acknowledge that there are regional differences
in the types of business start-up which emerge, and hence regional
variations in demand for business advice. Back
50
ODPM (2002) "Your Region, Your Choice: Revitalising the English
Regions" London: TSO. Back
51
Benneworth, P S, Roberts, P & Conroy, L. (2002) "Strategic
connectivity, sustainable development and the new English regional
governance" Journal of Environmental Planning and Management
45 (2) (pp 199-218). Back
52
Benneworth, P S & Vigar, G. (2006) "Strategic planning
in practice: the case of the North East of England" in H
Dimitriou & R Thomson (eds) Strategic Regional Planning
in the UK, London: Spon Back
|