Themes and Trends in Regulatory Reform - Regulatory Reform Committee Contents


Memorandum submitted by Europe Economics

HOUSE OF COMMONS REGULATORY REFORM COMMITTEE

Submission By Robert Young, Europe Economics

  Synopsis: this submission argues that the formation of larger regulators by merger of earlier smaller regulators has resulted in a shift of attention away from the limited number of basic tasks that economic regulators were created to carry out and towards an expansion of regulatory scope and ambition. The result has not obviously benefited consumers and it is not certain that it has resulted in greater regulatory efficiency. It is perhaps time for Government to pare back the scope of regulation but to ensure that it is rigorously and independently applied.

BACKGROUND

  1.  Europe Economics is a private sector consultancy that specialises in the application of economics and econometrics to business problems, primarily in the fields of competition, regulation and public policy analysis and formulation. The firm's clients include companies large and small, trade and professional bodies, regulators and competition authorities, and law firms. About half our business, measured by number of assignments, comes from outside the UK: our largest non-UK clients are the European Commission and Irish economic regulators.

  2.  My credentials for making a submission to the Committee are as follows. I spent some 20 years in private sector industry, completed a two-year secondment to the 10 Downing Street Policy Unit in the 1980s, and was then appointed and re-appointed a member of what was then the Monopolies & Mergers Commission (MMC), serving there from 1986 to 1992. In 1993 I began consulting in competition and regulation issues for Coopers & Lybrand, and joined Europe Economics five years ago. A good deal of my work in the past 20 years has been for regulatory bodies or for companies appearing before them. I have been involved in 31 inquiries by the MMC or its successor body, the Competition Commission, and in 17 inquiries involving UK economic regulators.

  3.  Competition and regulation involve overlapping skill sets: although the institutional arrangements differ, consulting experience acquired in one is almost always of value in the other. In some cases, competition and regulation may be closely intertwined. Sometimes an authority needs to establish whether an unregulated service ought to be regulated, or whether a regulated service ought to be removed from regulation and left to competition. It is no accident that some UK economic regulators have now been given competition authority powers, to be exercised in parallel with those of the Office of Fair Trading.

FEWER BIGGER REGULATORS

  4.  The single issue I should like to bring to the Committee's attention is whether the Government's apparently remorseless creation of fewer bigger regulators from a greater number of smaller, more specialised regulators has been a good thing for regulatory efficacy, or, more importantly, for consumers and UK society. My personal view is that it has not, and I suggest that the Committee may wish to explore for itself whether, in practice, bigger regulation has proved to be better.

  5.  The principal regulatory "mega-formations" that have taken place under the present Government are the Financial Services Authority (FSA); the Office of Communications (Ofcom); and the Gas and Electricity Markets Authority (GEMA), which conducts its day-to-day activities through the Office of the Gas and Electricity Markets, Ofgem. The consumer coverage of these organisations is immense: between them, the services regulated by the FSA, Ofcom and Ofgem reach into virtually every household in the UK.

THE OPERATING COSTS OF REGULATION

  6.  It has been said that the operational costs of the new mega-regulators are greater than the pre-merger totals of their predecessor bodies, although it is now hard to establish like-for-like comparisons. That said, some regulators have ballooned more than others:

    — As at March 2008 the FSA employed 2,535 people, compared with 1,762 as at March 1999, by which time it had taken over substantially all the functions of the predecessor bodies. The headcount increase amounts to 44%.

    — Ofcom, formed at the end of 2003, had 727 employees as at March 2004, rising to 812 in March 2008, an increase of 12%. However, this comparison conceals a substantial dispersion of almost 600 Radiocommunications Agency employees, and it is not clear that any of the implied productivity gain should be credited to Ofcom. The two principal sectors regulated by Ofcom—telephony and commercial broadcasting—accounted for some 420 staff (at Oftel and the Independent Television Commission) just before the creation of Ofcom.

    — GEMA and Ofgem replaced only two previous bodies, the Office of Gas Supply (Ofgas) and the Office of the Electricity Regulator (OFFER). Ofgem records that it reduced its headcount to 303 in its first year of operation from the figure of 380 employed by its predecessor organisations. Nevertheless, in the five years 2004 to 2008, the staff costs of GEMA and Ofgem rose by 18%, from £16.3 million to £19.2 million (the published accounts do not reveal numbers of staff).

  7.  The running costs of regulators are of course a burden on the regulated industries that finance them, and thus ultimately on consumers, and it is for the Committee to reach a conclusion on whether the increasing cost burden is either necessary or fair in relation to the regulation carried out.

THE APPARENTLY REMORSELESS EXPANSION OF REGULATION

  8.  However, my concern is less with cost increases—which, however objectionable, are still a small fraction of industry revenues—than with the expansion of regulatory scope. I am certainly not the first commentator to raise this matter, and I am sure I will not be the last, but I do join with others who might hold similar views in urging the Committee to include regulatory reach and ambition in its investigation.

  9.  When economic regulators first came to prominence in the 1980s and 1990s it was expected that as the monopoly supply industries they regulated gave way to competition the need for economic regulation would wither away. This has simply not happened: no economic regulator has vanished except to form part of a bigger regulator. It is not too fanciful to say that economic regulation has become an industry in its own right, and that what has been referred to as "regulatory creep" is becoming accepted as a normal tendency.

  10.  There is copious evidence to suggest that regulators—and their sponsoring Ministers—now see the expansion of regulation into sector co-management as some sort of guiding principle. I quote from three sources to illustrate the point.

  11.  The first is a speech given by the then Deputy Chairman of Ofcom, Richard Hooper, to an Australian audience in November 2005. Here are some extracts from what he said:

    "The conclusion of the Telecoms Strategic Review earlier this year has led to greater investment confidence in BT, the incumbent and in both types of BT competitors—infrastructure competitors like Cable & Wireless, and service competitors like Carphone Warehouse—a win, win, win situation I believe…

    "We hope to have encouraged not just investment but also "innovation"…

    "Ofcom engages with its stakeholders not via remote control but with the emphasis on face to face meetings, presentations and seminars, not just in London but also around the devolved nations and regions…

    "The new building reminds visitors more of a professional services firm than a government department…

    "There is an entrepreneurial air to Ofcom's approach to regulation which might surprise people and might on occasion be more reminiscent of the private sector than the public sector. There is an element of deal-making in Ofcom's approach to some big regulatory issues, getting people around a table and hammering out an acceptable solution and way forward. Whilst there is and has to be great attention to process, process should not suck the regulator away from finding lateral, creative, innovative interventions…"

  12.  Ofcom's predecessor in the telecoms sector, Oftel, was set up to carry out such basic function as price-capping BT's retail prices and its wholesale interconnection charges. As regards the viability of BT, Oftel was required merely to ensure that the company could finance its regulated functions. One might ask: why is it now the business of Ofcom to encourage investment in BT or in any other competitor for that matter? Is it for Ofcom to take a position on innovation, and what exactly do the quotation marks round the word innovation imply? Is it appropriate for Ofcom to engage in deal-making with regulated, or even unregulated, entities? Mr. Hooper's remarks make Ofcom sound like an old-style sponsoring Ministry—the very thing that independent regulators were established to get away from.

  13.  My second source is evidence put to a House of Lords committee which in 2007 produced a report on Regulation.[205] The evidence I refer to comes from economist observers of the UK regulatory landscape, Messrs. Keith Boyfield and Tim Ambler.[206] Relevant extracts are as follows:

    "…regulatory agencies have grown dramatically since 1997 both in size and the roles they are now assigned. This trend can be attributed to the current government's relative scepticism about, or limited understanding of, market mechanisms, and perhaps regulatory agencies' utility as additional branches of government. The extent to which government should intervene in detail in markets is a matter of political opinion. What is not in doubt is that these agencies enable the party in power so to do…

    "The Labour government's consumerist agenda has proved hard to define in legal language. We would argue that it [is] open to doubt whether any government should devolve governmental responsibilities to unelected quangos in this way. Significantly, Ministers have provided the utilities with hardly any guidance on how to fund their social and environmental objectives. For instance, how far should prices rise in order to cross-subsidise those who can less afford fuel? And how high should prices go in order to address with [sic] specific environmental problems? Little attempt has been made to establish priorities and trade-offs. The theoretical independence of regulatory agencies is no excuse for not specifying what they are supposed to achieve."

  14.  My third source is again the 2007 House of Lords report on Regulation of which Chapter 7 reads as follows.

    "7.38.  A lot of the evidence we received highlighted the way in which regulators' roles kept on expanding, taking them further away from eventual demise. This is supported by the data we received on regulators' costs and staff numbers. Although a few regulators within our remit have reduced their individual headcount over the past three financial years, the number of staff employed by regulators collectively in the financial year 2006-07 was almost 6,246, a 9.14% increase over the comparable figure for the financial year 2004-05…

    "7.39.  Several witnesses commented upon the tendency for the regulators to keep looking for new things to do (Q 334, Q 485, p 296, p 459). Clive Davenport from the Federation of Small Businesses said, "when most of the regulators were formed the world was a totally different place and I feel that they have become self-perpetuating bodies, and there is a problem with that because they end up searching for something else to look at" (Q 334)…

    "7.40.  More often than not, however, we heard the view that the accretion of duties by regulators was caused by others—Government, Parliament and the EU—rather than regulators themselves. The Chairman of Ofcom made the following point about regulatory expansion: "the primary cause of that, I suspect, lies … in Parliament, because it is Parliament and Government that tend to expand the roles of regulators" (Q 41)."

  15.  It may very well be true that Government and the EU are responsible for some—possibly even a large part—of the increasing activity of regulators. But the Committee may wish to question regulators on whether they take steps to contain or diminish the scope of regulation.

  16.  It has sometimes been said—rightly in my view—that the overarching objective of regulation is to command public confidence. Has this happened? I think not. It is hard to see that the new mega-regulators have undertaken thorough and fearless investigations leading to clinching successes. The current state of the banking sector speaks for itself, as does the intractably oligopolistic structure of gas and electricity supply. The impression one gets of the mega-regulators is that they have forgotten what their predecessors were created to do—to defend the consumer interest against supply-side abuse—and now see their role rather as brokering relationships with suppliers and furthering sectoral strategic goals.

A POSSIBLE SOLUTION

  17.  Worryingly, the Government has shown the same tendency towards agglomeration in reorganising consumer watchdogs, the independent bodies created to attend to matters of detail which (curiously) regulators are not expected to manage. Thus, last October, Postwatch, energywatch and the National Consumer Councils were merged, not without protest, into Consumer Focus. It remains to be seen whether Consumer Focus is more or less effective for consumers, and more or less costly to run, than the bodies that were merged into it—but recent history suggests that we should not be optimistic.

  18.  What, then, might be done? My suggestion would be to go back to basics—to pare back the scope of regulation and the duties of regulators to the essential things that only statutory regulation can do, but then to ensure that regulation is done yesterday and well. Such a reversal of current trends needs to jettison any fluffy partnering relationships in favour of a fierce regulatory independence. The regulatory tool-kit, one might argue, should contain no more than a hammer and nails—the hammer for banging companies into line, and the nails for holding them in place. I acknowledge that regulators cannot by themselves reinvent the regulatory world: Government has an ineluctable part to play in cutting back regulation to its essentials, and then in ensuring that these essentials are carried out effectively and efficiently, but such moves would benefit from a parallel commitment by regulators.

  19.  If we need to look for an example of how to do it, then in round terms it seems to me that Ofwat, the regulator of water services, remains a good model, perhaps because it has moved least far from its original form. One might argue that, unlike communications and broadcasting, the water and sewerage sector is technologically slow-moving, but that is to miss the point. Ofwat's strength and the source of its effectiveness is that it has continued to concentrate its efforts on those things—and only those things—that a genuinely independent regulator needs to do.

February 2009

Letter from Europe Economics

  Europe Economics is a consultancy that specialises in the application of economics and econometrics to economic regulation in many sectors of the economy, including finance, the utilities, telecommunications and broadcasting, pharmaceuticals, and sectors affected by competition policy investigations. Further information is on our website www.europe-economics.com

  One of our Principals, Bob Young, has already sent you a note on the optimum size of regulatory agencies, and I attach a copy of a substantial pamphlet just published by another of my colleagues, Andrew Lilico, addressing the strategic reasons for the failures of regulation in the financial sector.

  This letter comments on two apparent mistakes in the application of economic regulation, which could have been prevented without requiring more resources or any major reorganisation of regulatory authorities. In pointing out these issues we do not imply criticism of the people concerned; our purpose is with the benefit of hindsight to help to identify analytic mistakes that, being addressed, would improve future regulation both of the financial and of the other regulated sectors of the economy.

  The first is the general question of systemic risk. It should have been obvious to those involved in financial sector regulation that the new instruments and the processes by which claims were being valued involved risks to the system as a whole; and they should have had no difficulty in analysing policy options that would have contained or prevented those risks.

  Similar issues are present in other regulatory sectors. For example, in energy, is there a systemic risk of inadequate capacity? Or in pharmaceuticals, is there a systemic risk of facilitating the introduction of counterfeits through encouraging parallel trade and expecting pharmacists to act as traders? The question for your Committee's review, I suggest, is how well are systemic risk issues understood and addressed by regulatory authorities and Government Departments. There is no need for international collaboration in addressing this; within whatever scope each regulator operates at present, our question is how well are systemic risks being analysed and addressed?

  The second general issue is conflicts of interest. Obviously, this issue features in most regulatory debates, but our impression is that it is seldom explored in great depth. The crisis in financial regulation might have been much less serious if at an earlier stage the firms auditing the banks and other businesses involved in financial markets had questioned the values being placed on what are now called "toxic" assets; or if the rating agencies had been more effective. Similar comments may be made about parts of the labour market (bonus targets etc) and about the large scope of some of the banking institutions. It would have been possible for the OFT (for example) to investigate some of these markets in depth, seeking to understand what conflicts of interest there are, and what risks these imply. This would still be an extremely relevant investigation.

Dermot Glynn

Chairman

March 2009









205   http://www.parliament.the-stationery-office.co.uk/pa/ld200607/ldselect/ldrgltrs/189/18902.htm Back

206   http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/ld200607/ldselect/ldrgltrs/189/7060505.htm£n3 Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2009
Prepared 21 July 2009