Memorandum submitted by Dr Michael Pollitt, ESRC Electricity Policy Research Group,
· What should the
Government's vision be for · How do we ensure the regulatory framework is flexible enough to cope with uncertainty over the future generation mix?
A useful starting point for
a discussion of the future of GB's electricity networks is
Another important starting point is the idea that when it comes to electricity policy we should be thinking in terms of the efficient delivery of energy services (heating, lighting, power etc) rather than in terms of vertical structure of the current electricity supply industry (generation, transmission, distribution and supply). The question is not how best to configure the electricity network, but how best to ensure reasonable demands for energy services are met most efficiently. This encourages to think in terms of appropriate organizational forms for such delivery and to be open to potentially radically different combinations of assets which might best deliver services (e.g. heat networks, local generation etc.).
It is worthwhile starting with a number of basic principles for the future regulation of networks.[2]
First,
there should be a presumption that regulation in the future will involve more
deliberate engagement between buyers and sellers of network services (or their
representatives). Stephen Littlechild has discussed the success of such
policies in the electricity systems in North and
Second, regulation should remain committed to making good use of competitive mechanisms wherever possible and to facilitating innovative entry into the sector. In electricity generation and supply we expect large amounts of innovation to help us to meet our ambitious climate change targets. Electricity networks involve substantial investments by themselves, but even more importantly can influence (via their flexibility/inflexibility) the generation/supply investments that they support. They need to be incentivised to encourage new entrants and be open to the possibility that the current natural monopoly model of networks may not be optimal by 2050.
Third, the academic literature and practical experience has already established that differentiated pricing has a key role to play. The arrival of smart metering throughout the distribution system will offer significant potential for demand response both in the short and long run at the household and commercial levels. Such demand response requires the use of differentiated pricing in space and through time for all electricity customers. Customers may, of course, choose not to be exposed to such variations directly (by choosing time invariant contracts) but the incentives for energy service providers to match load to intermittent (or indeed inflexible) generation should exist.
Fourth, keeping technological options (and hence all the scenarios) open has a lot of value initially. We just don't know at this stage what the best network configuration is for 2020 or 2050, not least because of price, policy and technological uncertainty. Different configurations have strengths and weaknesses. However to begin with we can achieve demand reduction and increases in renewable generation without radical changes to energy networks. This gives us space to experiment with different technological options and organisational forms. We should take this opportunity because it has a high initial option value.
Fifth, the climate change agenda needs to be consistently pursued through all aspects of regulation. It is important to stress that rational consistency of policy is key to delivering energy services at least cost. This requires a single price of carbon and a consistent subsidy framework delivered with commitment over the life of investments. We are some way from achieving this difficult policy aim. At the moment planned network investment is being made in an environment of high uncertainty about the future financial incentives that will be available. As with generation investments it is important that network investments face a more consistent policy framework going forward than at present.
An additional starting point, is to point out that it is possible imagine linear combinations of the scenarios (this is different from the Multi-purpose networks scenario in LENS). Thus different distribution network areas might follow different paths towards achieving our overall climate targets and this might be a desirable outcome given their different electricity generation and demand characteristics.
· What are the technical, commercial and regulatory barriers that need to be overcome to ensure sufficient network capacity is in place to connect a large increase in onshore renewables, particularly wind power, as well as new nuclear build in the future? For example issues may include the use of locational pricing, or the availability of skills.
An increase in large scale inflexible central generation (over the current level) would mean a need for either more flexible demand or more storage. Flexible demand is helped by clear price signals to loads. It seems clear that nodal pricing throughout the transmission system (like in the PJM market in the US) and additionally nodal pricing within the distribution system (as is being partially implemented in the South West (WPD)) would seem to be important to provide finely differentiated incentives which could help manage demand and incentivise least system cost location of distributed and micro-generation.
Consideration might also
need to be given to storage technology which might complement extra wind on the
system. It would be possible to invest in a significant amount more pumped
storage hydro. Careful evaluation of the value of such water (which may not be privately
economic if it reduces the price differentials across time and hence the
arbitrage opportunity) would need to be made. David MacKay[4]
notes that several good sites are already identified for this capacity.
Similarly there are possibilities for dumping excess wind power into heat (via
electrical elements in hot water tanks) which are being investigated in
· What are the issues the Government and regulator must address to establish a cost-effective offshore transmission regime?
· What are the benefits and risks associated with greater interconnection with other countries, and the proposed 'supergrid'?
These need to be carefully
evaluated. The tentative evidence would seem to be that greater interconnection
between power control areas does increase the risk of large - multi-national -
blackouts[7].
There is also a problem of paying for international transmission links where
the costs are socialized within average tariffs. This can either lead to
incentives to oversize the grid (because the costs are shared among average
transmission charges) or to undersize because merchant transmission cannot be
justified. There is also an interaction between the gas and electricity markets
which suggests that it might be more efficient to trade the gas rather than the
electricity internationally. Therefore it may be more cost-effective at the
European level to work on improving the gas market in
· What challenges will higher
levels of embedded and distributed generation create for
This requires distribution
networks to become active rather than passive networks. Serious consideration
needs to be given to network regulation which encourages local generation.
It is possible that the creation of
a more active distribution network requires a significant reorganisation of the
electricity sector. In particular consideration should be given to ownership
unbundling distribution wire businesses from the rest of the electricity system
(similar to the position of
An important part of the mix is customer engagement. It will be increasingly important that individual customers respond to financial incentive to economise on carbon and energy. It is also important that they embrace new technology such as smart meters and the intensive use of data that they will eventually facilitate. Thus individual consumers will need to welcome own and local generation and to voluntarily submit to demand response measures either directly of via energy service companies. This will be key to the successful uptake of much more local generation. An important part of the policy to get right will be that towards the fuel poor. Customer engagement offers the prospect of initially targeting the fuel poor for energy efficiency measures and subsidy support. This has high potential as popular policy if implemented sensitively.
· What are the estimated costs of upgrading our electricity networks, and how will these be met?
Network costs cannot be separated from power costs and must be looked at in the round. It is very important to only upgrade networks when this is necessary. If we can reduce electricity demand it may be possible to slow the rate of replacement of electricity network assets and this may be a significant saving. Regulated companies need to be given strong incentives to prolong the life of assets where there is no technical reason to replace them.
· How can the regulatory framework ensure adequate network investment in light of the current credit crunch and recession?
In my view the existing system is capable of adjusting to the credit crunch. Revenue will adjust marginally in line with falls in demand which is appropriate. The calculation of the regulatory weighted average cost of capital - WACC - will also adjust at the time the prices are reset. Regulated network companies remain relatively attractive investments to the credit market. The credit crunch will offer strong incentives to regulators and government more generally to clarify the investment regime and reassure investors that the government is committed to a stable investment environment.
· How can the regulatory framework encourage network operators to innovate, and what is the potential of smart grid technologies?
The Innovation Funding
Incentive (IFI) run by
· Is there sufficient investment in R&D and innovation for transmission and distribution technologies?
Almost certainly there is not enough R&D being done given the scale of the future investments expected. The IFI scheme for electricity transmission and distribution currently only raises around £20m per year. This would not be sufficient to support a set of large scale demonstration projects suggested above.
· What can the
In
The
[1] See Ault, G., Frame, D. and Hughes,
N.(2008), Electricity Network Scenarios in [2] Here we draw on
Pollitt, M. (2008a), 'The Future of Electricity (and Gas) Regulation in a
Low-carbon Policy World', The Energy Journal, Special Issue on 'The Future of
Electricity: Papers in Honor of David Newbery', pp.63-94. and Grubb M., Jamasb,
T. and Pollitt, M. (2008) (Eds.), Delivering a Low-Carbon Electricity System,
[3] For a summary see Littlechild, S. (2008) "Some applied economics of electricity regulation." The Energy Journal, 29(S2): 43-62. [4] MacKay, D. (2008), Sustainable
Energy - Without the Hot Air,
[5] See Littlechild (2008) op cit. [6] See Pollitt, M.
(2004) "Electricity reform in [7] Yu, W. and
Pollitt, M. (2009) "Does liberalisation cause more electricity blackouts?
Evidence from a global study of newspaper reports." Electricity Policy
Research Group Working Papers, No.EPRG0902. [8] See Pollitt, M.
(2009, forthcoming), Does Electricity
(and Heat) Network Regulation have anything to learn from Fixed Line Telecoms
Regulation?, Mimeo. Referred to in [9] See Nillesen, P.
and Pollitt, M.G. (2008) "Ownership unbundling in electricity
distribution: empirical evidence from [10] For a review of
existing local authority ESCOs in the
[11] Pollitt, M. (2008b) "The arguments for and against ownership unbundling of energy transmission networks." Energy Policy, 36(2): 704-713
|