Pre-Budget Report 2008: Green fiscal policy in a recession - Environmental Audit Committee Contents


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 1-19)

PROFESSOR TIM JACKSON

27 JANUARY 2009

  Q1 Chairman: Good morning. I am sorry we have kept you waiting. We had rather more future business to go through than we anticipated. We will run to about 11.15 with you. Thank you very much for coming in. We have obviously seen your response to the Pre-Budget Report on behalf of the SDC, which was pretty forthright and all the more welcome from our point of view for that. Would you just like to run through the headlines, the main points in it for us?

  Professor Jackson: I guess our headline message was that there were bits of the right signal in the sense that the words "green stimulus" were used, and there were some components that could be characterised as green stimulus, but that the scale was entirely wrong, really, when you look at what constitutes that green stimulus, which was pitched at about £535 million in the Pre-Budget Report; it actually amounts to something like £200 million of spend upon anything other than adaptation and rail; and of that £200 million, some of it was spending brought forward; so you are really talking about a minuscule spend in relation to certainly the average financial rescue package, and indeed the scale of the Pre-Budget Report as a whole. So we felt that there was a good signal there in the sense that some of those things were mentioned, but that it could and should have gone an awful lot further. We were encouraged by signals in relation to reducing income inequality—that is an important element of sustainability, and the evidence suggests that the UK is at this point in time more unequal than it was 20 years ago, so moves in that direction in terms of fiscal recovery are sensible. We were less encouraged by the attack on employment through higher national income contributions, and that seems to be, again, a move in the wrong direction in environmental terms and in contradiction to the Government's own statement on environmental taxation in 1997, which is just a shift from labour taxes to environmental taxes. Finally, like many other people, we felt that the £12.5 billion spend on VAT reduction was misplaced, not only from the perspective that it may not work in terms of providing the stimulus—there is too much leakage possibility—but also that it was problematic to encourage households into higher levels of consumer spending when they are already exposed to financial risk, when consumer debt is at an all-time high, and household saving has plummeted. It looks like too dilute a measure that is going in the wrong direction to us.

  Q2  Chairman: Have you any idea what the Treasury thought of all these comments of yours?

  Professor Jackson: We have not had a direct engagement with Treasury on this. They do not seem to trawl our website and respond to it as perhaps we might wish they would! We have had some engagement with Treasury on some of the issues, and, to be honest, I think it would be fair to say that there is a recognition of some of those issues, certainly around environmental taxation and the green investment; and some of that is coming through in some of the work that is going on, for example, in the Low Carbon Industrial Strategy. However, in terms of the direct positive acknowledgment of our undoubted wisdom in this area, we have not quite had what we might have hoped for!

  Chairman: We sometimes have the same feeling ourselves!

  Q3  Mr Caton: Going back to your comments on the inadequacy of the green stimulus package, how much do you think the Chancellor should have given?

  Professor Jackson: There are different ways of putting this into context, I think. One of them is obviously to go to the Stern review and to look at the bottom-line numbers in the Stern review. Stern was suggesting at that time, nearly three years ago, a 1% annual spend on climate reduction, climate mitigation, carbon reduction. That would have amounted to about £15 billion of spend just in the area of carbon reduction. As I say, that was 2006. Stern's target was 550 parts per million in the atmosphere. The perceived wisdom is that it should be considerably lower. There are some estimates that put the spend needed to achieve a low carbon society in the region of 3% of GDP per annum. That is a £45 billion spend, considerably higher than the fiscal package in the Pre-Budget Report, and clearly subject to all sorts of difficulties in relation to financial prudence and the national debt and so on. Our suggestion is that a spend of this magnitude, of at least £15 billion, of the same order of magnitude as the fiscal package in the Pre-Budget Report, is entirely in order. We have done some preliminary costing of the kinds of things that you might wish to see in that package, and they fit, I think, with a sort of emerging consensus about what is needed. That consensus suggests a rapid ramp-up of retrofitting the present building stock for energy efficiency; investment in the Grid perhaps to develop the smart grid; investment in public transport, for example rolling out the Department for Transport's Smarter Choices Programme, which is being piloted in three English towns; and perhaps making some movement in relation to greener businesses and the greening of the Government estate—carbon neutrality in the Government estate. Just taking one of those options, there is a really, really obvious case for a quite considerable spend. If you think about the housing stock and say we have got 20 years perhaps to get the housing stock in the UK to a decent level, that is 24 million households; assume that you could do it at a million households a year, at an average cost of £10,000-11,000 a year, which might be conservative, that is a £10 billion a year spending package that ramps up very fast into something that suddenly begins to look like a real green stimulus. It is spending of that order! We did some estimates in relation to the transport spend, which could easily absorb a half billion pound spend a year, but could generate returns, in terms of carbon savings, which the DfT estimates could be 10 times that amount of spend. We are saying that there is plenty of room to spend £15 billion if you wanted a fiscal stimulus package in the green measures that we know we need in order to achieve the carbon targets that we are facing, that are now in legislation; and, most importantly perhaps, we also know that that kind of spending generates carbon savings, financial returns and jobs.

  Q4  Mr Challen: Following up this point about the overall spend, the Government in the Pre-Budget Report said it would be spending £50 billion over the next CSR period, starting in this financial year. I have a breakdown of this figure, which I thought was perhaps slightly on the high side, and they include things like Cross Rail, spending on rail and the National Grid infrastructure investment, which might be simply replacing, in the case of National Grid, existing transmission lines and so on. Is it correct to include things like Cross Rail in something described as "driving a low-carbon economy" when it was already in the pipeline? It seems to me that the key question is if Nick Stern, for example, is saying you only need to spend an extra 2% of GDP, can you really transfer projects already in our system as extra, or should we have two Cross Rails rather than one Cross Rail, if you get my point?

  Professor Jackson: I would not want to say you should not be spending on Cross Rail—of course you should be spending on public transit, and on approved public transit, and to the extent that that is going to be brought forward, accelerated, fantastic—but it is essentially already in the baseline. You cannot claim it, I would argue, as an additional fiscal stimulus or green stimulus over and above what is already in that baseline. That is the criterion against what was set out in the green stimulus, should be judged. All of these programmes, the Community Energy Savings Programme, the Cross Rail public transport stuff, Ofgem looking at the Grid—all of these are incredibly important programmes; but the question that the stimulus package was asking is where now should Government address additional investment and additional spend in order to achieve what we intend to do, both in terms of jobs in the economy and in terms of meeting carbon targets. We would argue quite strongly that the criterion should be additional spend over and above baseline commitments.

  Q5  Mr Chaytor: You have a particular concern about debt levels in the United Kingdom, having huge personal debt levels and public sector debt and national debt, at the same time as the economic downturn, and clearly you think this places us in a particularly vulnerable position. Can you expand on that a little bit?

  Professor Jackson: There are three areas of debt where one should be concerned. The first is national level, what the public sector owes to the private sector, which, as we know, at the moment is about 40% of GDP and predicted to rise to something like 60%. That might be conservative once financial rescue packages, re-capitalisation of the banks, is taken into account. Actually, that area of debt, although it has broken the Treasury's own rules and is rising fast, is still lower than several other advanced countries. It is a cause for concern, and particularly the rate at which it is rising is a cause for concern; but in a sense it is less of a concern than perhaps the consumer debt position, where we stand at one of the highest consumer debts in the world. Household saving has plummeted so that the position that households find themselves in, going into a recession, is incredibly precarious—borrowing against declining assets, the value of their houses going down, and their exposure to economic risk going up, their savings having declined over a decade. This is a position of financial imprudence at the household level that households are now being encouraged into in order to escape from the economic downturn. That, I think, is a deep concern. It is particularly a concern that our economic stability rests on encouraging financial imprudence at the household level over quite a long period of time. We believe that that is something that needs to be addressed both in terms of the signals that are sent to consumers, the options that are available to consumers and indeed the model of economic stability that relies on pushing people into high levels of debt in order to maintain high-street spending to keep the economy going. That is a structural concern. The third level of concern is what is called the external debt. The UK has the highest level of external debt at around 40 to 50% of GDP, other than the US, at absolute levels in the economy—although that is balanced by a similar level of overseas assets. That precarious position of having a high level of overseas assets and a very high level of overseas debt is exacerbated in volatile markets with the fall of the pound and really does put the economy, as a whole, in the very precarious position of having lent a little too much, engaged in financial risk in the financial markets a little too heavily, and will make it difficult to maintain and to find economic stability in the future. We are concerned about all three levels of indebtedness in the UK. Perhaps the least of those is the one that has had the most attention, which is the national debt, but it is still a concern because it is rising so fast.

  Q6  Dr Turner: You also call for much greater public spending on low-carbon investments. How do you square that with the concern about the level of public debt, because we would all love to see massive investments in low-carbon infrastructure projects whether transport projects or electrical engineering—whichever; but how do you propose to finance them, given that you want to restrict the level of public debt?

  Professor Jackson: Everybody wants to restrict the level of public debt, even the Government, and there is a recognition at this point, and there is a recognition in the recession that public debt is likely to expand. I think that is almost inevitable. The question of financing that debt, as both a short-term and a long term aspect—in the short term it is about making prudent choices about what we invest in. To be honest, the debt is expanding at the moment not through anything remotely like green investment, but through financial rescue packages, and to some extent through a long programme of public spending. We are saying essentially that you have to target where you are spending that public money, and if you target that public money at things where you are simply throwing public revenues into something like a dilute incentive like the VAT measure, you really have no chance of clawing that back except through higher tax levels at some point in the future. It may be then that higher tax levels at some point in the future are going to be necessary, but the two things that promote the case for a green stimulus rather than simply a fiscal stimulus, is that many of these measures are cost-saving to the nation over a short time period, so that improving insulation in the housing stock, improving energy efficiency in business, improving the efficiency of appliances, improving the efficiency of cars, generating fuel savings, generating economic savings—these are real savings to the nation. They do not all necessarily come to Government—that depends on fiscal structure, but they are savings to the nation, and as savings to the nation they ease the constraints on households in terms of their indebtedness and spending and they also ease the possibility for getting money back into the public coffers and reducing the burden upon public debt.

  Q7  Dr Turner: Can you put rough numbers on the amount of public indebtedness you would like to see in -loosely—green infrastructure projects, and what sort of projects you would prioritise?

  Professor Jackson: I mentioned this very quickly before, but we believe that at least at this point in time it is appropriate to have a green stimulus package of a size comparable with the 15.5 that was in the Pre-Budget Report, and that that spending should be prioritised certainly on a retrofit programme for the domestic housing stock to bring it up to SAP80 to 85. SAP81 is the agreed rating that would improve fuel poverty and put us on track to achieve an 80% carbon emission reduction. The cost of that would be quite high, depending on how long you did it for. If you are going to hit the whole 25 million households in the UK, you would have to be spending around £10 billion a year, so there is a big potential spend there and it would need some time to ramp up and it would generate returns on some of that money quite quickly. Some of it would be longer over 20 years. We also think that there is a need to prioritise something like the Smarter Choices Programme, the DfT's programme, trialled in three English towns to reduce car travel and to improve public transport, access to walking, cycling and to develop personal travel plans, personal mobility plans, that reduce car use; and that estimated cost would be something less than half a billion pounds per year. The smart grid, which has been talked a lot about by various people in the US—the costs for the development of the smart grid in the UK is very difficult to get a clear handle on, but certainly rolling out the development of a grid that is able to take on distributed renewable energy projects and to allow for active management through smart metering, could reduce energy consumption by 10 to 15% per annum and begin to do that quite fast. That is a big investment. It is going to need substantial thought about how to work that through, but, again, the cost savings on that in terms of the total energy bill to the nation are very substantial. A fourth priority area that we have identified is in relation to bringing forward the Government's own ambitions for carbon neutrality in the public sector itself as well as in the Government's estate.

  Q8  Dr Turner: Your comments about the Grid do not seem to extend to remodelling the Grid to accommodate far-flung sources of renewable energy, which is a major problem, as you know.

  Professor Jackson: Absolutely, no. That idea of making the Grid accessible to distributed and far-flung renewable energy sources is absolutely key to this. That would be about strengthening, redesigning and smartening the capacity of the Grid to do the job.

  Q9  Dr Turner: To what extent would you want to see the green stimulus package applied at the household level, given that you want to encourage households to save?

  Professor Jackson: It does apply at the household level. As we go into possibly quite a lengthy recession, the plight of households, particularly poorer households, is something that should be at the forefront of concerns. Again, this is one of the self-reinforcing aspects of the green stimulus, particularly if it is focused properly; it is mainly the poorer households that find themselves in fuel poverty and unable to maintain even basic living conditions under higher energy prices and threats to their income. So it is absolutely appropriate, we would argue, that you focus attention on easing that burden on households. That will put money into the pockets of householders, but some of that legitimately, they will want to spend on the high street, which could provide a stimulus effect to the economy. At this point in time, in the short term, with the economy declining, it is absolutely clear that there is a need to stabilise the economy as a whole, and that is probably going to mean a change in consumer confidence. That change in consumer confidence has to come through both the ability of households to spend and their confidence that they are spending in a financially prudent way. So although offering energy efficiency frees up funds to households and allows them to spend where they want, they will not begin to do that unless they are confident that it is financially prudent; so at this point in time I think that is both right in terms of financial prudence, and right in terms of a moral choice that people should be looking to their future financial and economic stability, and that the Government should be encouraging that kind of prudence. So along with the idea of stimulating household spending through improved energy efficiency, which has national savings, is the idea of encouraging financial prudence at the household level, doing something about the plummeting savings rates and reducing debt.

  Q10  Dr Turner: You have criticisms of conventional measures of economic growth.

  Professor Jackson: Yes.

  Q11  Dr Turner: Would you wish to see some refined measure of economic growth that took into account environmental considerations, so a green measure of economic growth, if you like, so that you can redirect the economy?

  Professor Jackson: That is something that personally I have worked on over a number of years, and I do believe that it has a role to play. The failings of GDP are well known. It does not account for changes in the asset base properly, whether that is financial assets, social assets or natural capital. There are some ways of improving those measures. There are a number of pilot measures that have been developed over 20 years or so. The Stiglitz Commission in France is looking at those measures and the idea of measuring social progress and environmental performance in a more accurate way. It is our position that a sensible long-term position going forward beyond recovery from recession is to address very firmly that relationship between economic growth and sustainability and take on board those criticisms of GDP as the simple single measure of economic progress; and indeed a green measure of some kind, some kind of programme that looks at those limitations of GDP and adjusts for the most obvious ones, at least, is very long overdue.

  Q12  Chairman: Given the external debt figure of 450% of GDP, external debt is defined as the borrowing by British individuals and corporations from overseas sources—is that right?

  Professor Jackson: Yes, indeed.

  Q13  Martin Horwood: Can I draw you on the subject of the banking sector, where obviously the British Government now has a surprisingly large interest and degree of control. Do you think the Government has been right to exercise that kind of control for the moment at reasonable arm's length; or do you think we should get involved in using environmental priorities to determine the policy of the banks we now control, for instance, either by disinvesting from the unmentionable Bank of Scotland's less than wonderful record of investing in fossil fuel projects, or lending to consumers for green mortgages and energy efficiency or lending to businesses that were in green industries? Do you think that would be an appropriate way to go?

  Professor Jackson: It is a really tough call in terms of politics and in terms of financial prudence. What I would say is absolutely clear is that we need mechanisms for investment in green infrastructure, and some of the things that have been talked about, for example, are a green infrastructure bank where everyone from Deutsche Bank to Greenpeace, or Greenpeace to Deutsche Bank, whichever way you go, has argued for something along those lines, and there is rather a strong case for something that would be a public infrastructure bank able to lend into the green sector and to stimulate that kind of investment. Another of the options that has been put on the table, which is an interesting one, is the idea of raising green bonds, essentially bond issues which were specifically dedicated to the idea of investment in green technologies, green businesses, renewable energy, energy efficiency and so on and so forth. As the bond market looks to have some signs of possibly saturating, actually the idea of a green bond attains a nice market distinction, which might make it something quite attractive as the years go by, and as this year goes by even. The question of what you should do with these now part-nationalised banks in terms of managing how they lend and where they lend is much more fraught than that general principle that we need this kind of green infrastructure. It is about the precise way in which the mechanisms of rescue, re-capitalisation, the housing market, lending into the housing market, separation of toxic assets—all of that plays out. It is enormously complicated and I would not pretend to sit here and offer you financial expertise at that level. What is really important is that there is an examination of the appropriate mechanisms for both protecting against the toxic debt and ensuring that lending is going into the appropriate places in households and businesses, and something which directs green investment towards the kinds of things we know we need in terms of carbon reduction.

  Q14  Martin Horwood: Would the kind of green infrastructure you are talking about be created out of existing banks or would it be an entirely new institution?

  Professor Jackson: It could be that that is the best way to do it, with all this other stuff parcelled up in the mix. It is really difficult to answer off the top of your head and you really do need to look at that incredibly carefully. There have, for example, been calls, largely from within the more mainstream financial sectors, that the only bit that should be nationalised is toxic debts; that you take that out and keep that and clean up the rest of it and take away the liabilities from the private sector and let it do its job. That is one way of addressing where the banks stand at the moment. It is not one, I think, that addresses the difficulties associated with getting investment flowing into the green areas that we know that it needs to go into. My point to you is that from that end of the spectrum, where you just take away the nasty liabilities and say to the financial sector "okay, boys, off you go", as it were before business as usual, to one where you say, "RBS is the target now to become a green infrastructure bank and that is what we are going to turn it into". That is a huge range of options in the banking sector, and to some extent it would be cleaner to say, let us start from scratch with a national infrastructure bank and build what we need out of that, rather than saddling it from the word "go" with the toxic liabilities that are associated with part nationalised banks.

  Q15  Martin Horwood: You are happy with the idea of the Government running banks, are you!

  Professor Jackson: Happier at this point of time than the way they have been run up into this crisis.

  Q16  Mr Challen: You have been critical of the Pre-Budget Report for not doing enough to reverse inequality in the UK. Can you explain the importance of tackling equality issues in the context of sustainable developments?

  Professor Jackson: It is really important to acknowledge that sustainable development is not just ecology, not just environmental limits. What environmental limits do in terms of social well-being is that they put a finite bound around the pie, what can be divided up between people. The distribution of that pie is incredibly important both in terms of its environmental components and environmental qualities divided up and environmental resources divided up and are deeply unequal across the world and even to some extent within the UK. Of course, they are the social goods that those resources are used to produce. As I mentioned before, inequality is higher now than it was 20 years ago. There is a need to address that inequality. What do we know about unequal households, or those at the lower end of the income distribution? We know that they have lower life expectancy, higher morbidity; they report lower satisfaction with life and typically live with lower environmental quality. These are real standards of living differences between huge sections of the population, and that cannot be characterised as a strong, healthy and just society—one of the principles of the UK sustainable development strategy. The important of inequality to us is absolutely central, and it is inequality now; it is intra-generational inequality that matters as a priority in sustainable development. We all know that inter-generational or cross-generational inequality also matters in the ability of future generations to achieve a decent standard of living and are also compromised by promiscuous resource use and breaching of environmental limits. Both of those, now today—inequality as we see it in the country at the moment, is unacceptable from the sustainable development point of view, as is the risk to future generations.

  Q17  Mr Challen: What sort of redistributed measures would you suggest to tackle this?

  Professor Jackson: There are various issues. The statement of intent on environmental taxation in 1997 does provide the basis for shifting taxation from income to taxes on environmental bads, from goods to bads. It is a fairly basic principle. We know that there are all kinds of difficulties with it, but we also know that in some cases it can have some progressive impact because typically higher income households use more energy and emit more carbon, so that in itself is a measure that hits both the needs of reduced environmental resource use and throughput, and to some extent addresses the inequality issue. It is not necessarily the only one—I have mentioned already that we have praised the idea of a shift in taxation to higher income earners, at least as a recovery measure and possibly as a way of achieving more income equality in the longer term. There is also a role for caps on executive remuneration, perhaps a range of income levels from not just minimum income level but maximum income level. These are measures that are deeply contentious and fiercely argued against by liberal market economists; but from a social welfare perspective something like this looks like it must be in order at this point in time, in order to achieve the social well-being goals that sustainable development has at its heart.

  Q18  Mr Challen: Do you think in this context the Government was right to downgrade its interests in personal account analysis?

  Professor Jackson: I am not sure I understand why that might be right.

  Q19  Mr Challen: They said it was an idea before its time but most people say it is redistributive.

  Professor Jackson: It could be redistributive. What we know about the evidence in relation to that kind of measure is that you have to look after the poorest households incredibly carefully because it is not typically—it is not always, across the board, exhaustive in terms of its progressive impact. It can be regressive on the most fuel poor. The only way really to address the impact of that is to target very strongly investment measures in the building—particularly the building fabric in the poorest houses. That comes out very clearly from all the analysis. In terms of, was it before its time—I do not think it can possibly be regarded as being before its time in the context of the carbon targets that we are now in legislation permitted to achieve.



 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2009
Prepared 16 March 2009