Reducing greenhouse gas emissions from deforestation: No hope without forests - Environmental Audit Committee Contents


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 20-38)

MR JOHAN ELIASCH, MR JONATHAN BREARLEY AND MR GRAHAM FLOATER

9 DECEMBER 2008

  Q20  Martin Horwood: Can I ask you about another governance issue, which is about the land rights of indigenous tribal peoples? They do not receive an awful lot of mention in the Review. Would you first of all acknowledge that there are rights there to be recognised as in a sense we are commodifying their living environment, but, secondly, that it is a potentially quite neglected part of the possible solution in that if you firm up land rights you will improve the importance of land rights and encourage more governments to sign up for things like ILO169 and that could be quite an effective tool in helping to protect the forests themselves? Would you agree with that?

  Mr Floater: It is fundamental that there is full participation from forest communities and that includes indigenous peoples. Forests are home to about 350 million people and about 60 million indigenous people, and one thing that we wanted to get across in this Review is that all of those people, many of them very poor, are important in this process. Over 90% of those living on less than one dollar a day depend on forests for their livelihood. In terms of addressing specifically the rights of indigenous peoples, on page 195 of the Review we talk about Articles 18 and 19 of the UN Declaration on the Rights of Indigenous Peoples, and, as I say, it does need to be fundamental, but we also have to recognise that there are many other forest communities who need to be taken into account as well.

  Q21  Martin Horwood: Forgive me, I missed that on page 195 but it is quite a slight reference. The issue about poverty reduction as part of this package and the number of people living on one dollar day is a slightly misleading one, is it not, when you are dealing with indigenous tribal peoples who are living in the forest because in a sense they do not live on anything a day in monetary terms? They often have quite a sustainable lifestyle as it is without needing to be part of the money economy, so the protection of their rights is a much more important thing than incentivising poverty reduction because in that sense they are not really poor in the same way as a community on the margins of the forest. You do not talk a lot about their land rights as part of the solution, do you?

  Mr Eliasch: Of course their land rights are as important as everybody else's land rights, and we do emphasise that in the Review. If you take a country like Brazil, they have an institute called FUNAI which is dedicated to looking after indigenous people. This is a formula which, if that is managed properly, is highly recommendable and also for the rest of the rainforest nations to adopt a similar type of system to protect their rights.

  Q22  Chairman: Can we go back to the issue of credits? You argue in the report that if you allow credits into the EU ETS, provided you have got the right supplementarity limit and the right emissions reduction targets, which I think might be a fairly big assumption but I imagine you can do that, then it does not have the effect of reducing the carbon price. However, a high carbon price is regarded as essential to drive all sorts of investment in low carbon technologies crucial to what is going on in the energy sector, the transport sector and so on. There is still nevertheless a risk, is there not, that if forestry credits came in they would have a depressing effect on the carbon price?

  Mr Eliasch: In our opinion, with supplementarity limits of 50% and a gradual smooth transition, and this is based on evidence from modelling, we do not think it would have an impact. I would say that the underlying thesis here is that in any market there will always be investors into that. It will always attract capital flows if you have an attractive proposition. As part of that we need a currency, a security that is robust and stable pricing mechanisms—like in any economic system that is based on open market principles that will prevail. It is not a question of flooding; it is a supply and demand situation.

  Mr Brearley: Can I just add that this is not unique to the forestry debate actually, there is lot of cheap abatement in countries outside of Europe and the same issues apply. Essentially what we say is that by setting supplementarity limits you can make a judgment between that and your targets about where you think your EUA price might end up. The trade-offs you make in forestry are exactly the same as the trade-offs you make in other low carbon technologies across the developed and developing world.

  Q23  Chairman: Yes, it is just potentially that they are rather big. That is why it is so important that the scope is so enormous?

  Mr Brearley: Absolutely. That is why we describe a transition where essentially you have a slow transition into the market and therefore you have a slow supply of credit. That is not unique. If you look at the potential of other sectors, for example, I believe with the associated costs there you will find we did have a similar scale of issues.

  Mr Floater: Could I come back to your specific question about the price impact. The modelling that we did showed that if you allow forestry credits into the international market, if the supplementarity limit in the EU ETS is already set and that level is below 50% then there will be no impact on the EUA price. The reason is, that although the average cost would go down, the carbon price is set by the marginal cost—the most expensive part of the abatement—and for that reason it would have no impact on the price. There would be implications for the international credit market, and we looked at that again. I think there is an assumption that forest credits are extremely cheap and much cheaper than credits in other sectors. We found that the reality is more complicated than that. If you allow forest credits into the international market it could make up about 34% of that market; but with stronger developed country targets and supplementarity limits in place you would be able to keep your price at a level that would be a strong incentive for investment in new technologies; it would support a high level of technology transfer to developing countries; and it would also fund the significant forestry abatement that we need.

  Q24  Chairman: A 50% limit which you suggest, do you think that is the right one?

  Mr Floater: We have not suggested what would be an appropriate level; that would have to be based on a number of different decisions for other sectors, because that is a decision on the level for international credits as a whole. The only thing that we did was to ask ourselves, at whatever level it is already set at if you then included forestry credits what would happen? Anything below about 70% would have very little impact.

  Q25  Chairman: The Climate Change Committee reported last week and suggested that 73% of our 80% emission reduction target is likely to be most cost-effectively delivered domestically. What do you think that implies about the role of a carbon market for delivering funds for forestry?

  Mr Floater: It is important to make the distinction between the ETS and non-ETS. What the Committee on Climate Change is suggesting is that in the intended budget case—this is the case that they put forward in the eventuality of a global deal—up to 20% of the required emissions reductions could be achieved through offset credit purchase. That is outside of the EU ETS; and so the report is compatible with the findings in our report.

  Q26  Joan Walley: Just looking at offsetting, a large proportion of our emission reduction target places considerable faith in international credits; but it has been difficult verifying emission reductions from industrial sources. What we wondered is what evidence you have to show that forest credits will not be even harder to verify and easier to manipulate? Have you got evidence to show that it will not be even harder to verify the forest credits that there would be? If you actually look at what is happening at the moment, it is very difficult to verify and manipulate the credits that there are; and we just feel with the forestry situation you are embarking on something that would be even harder to verify.

  Mr Eliasch: With all types of credits you have similar types of challenges. The implementation period is not something we can switch on overnight; it will take some time here, and that is why we are saying that it is so incredibly important to start capacity-building now because it is a big task and it is going to take time.

  Mr Brearley: This was a surprise for me when we embarked on the Review, because one of the biggest questions I had when we started was: how are we going to understand what we are delivering here. Graham can give you the detail, but the surprise for me was, with the combination of satellite technology and with capacity on the ground, actually we feel we can be approaching measurements as accurate as we are in other sectors. If you look at what we do in Europe and our assessment of our own accuracy, then we are not that far off in forestry and we do not expect to be.

  Mr Eliasch: If you have the science right from the start the actual measuring and monitoring is very easy because you see it—it is right there in front of you from above and you can see progress.

  Mr Floater: This has been a concern, and understandably so. As I mentioned before, the IPCC guidelines are not that simple because you have to understand the type of forest you are working with, the amount of carbon stored and the land use change as well. Over recent years there has been a significant advance in techniques in order to quantify the carbon stored and the emissions that would be produced under different land use changes. Chapter 10 of the Review goes into some detail looking at the evidence, which concludes that the confidence for the estimates of emissions in the forest sector can be around about the same as other sectors. As Johan says, that requires capacity-building on the ground on a country by country basis, and that is why it is very urgent that we get this capacity-building up and running.

  Q27  Joan Walley: As well as having to do that capacity-building there is also going to be a cost to that as well, is there not, which is going to presumably be offset against whatever the cost for setting up the whole market process is?

  Mr Eliasch: Yes, obviously, but if you look in the big context here the capacity-building is small.

  Mr Floater: We estimated it would be about $50 million for a sample of 25 forest nations to set up national forest inventories, with a further $7-17 million needed for annual running costs. That is relatively small compared to the $4 billion we were talking about overall.

  Q28  Joan Walley: Let me just try and understand this a little bit more. Let us assume then that the UK is buying emission credits from the countries that themselves have not got binding carbon targets, and in those countries the overall emissions are actually growing. How can we justify our Government treating those credits, which are actually growing in another country because there are not binding targets, from actually reducing our net emissions? Is there not a contradiction somewhere at the heart of that? It is okay for us, but it is going to offset that growing elsewhere.

  Mr Eliasch: The starting proposition here is that everybody is part of an agreement—whatever the trade performance, that is number one. Number two, with forestry in particular this is a big opportunity to actually address developing nations' poverty, or need to reduce poverty, which goes hand in hand with forests—there is close linkage. That is the second part of this. The third part is that to effectively get the funding to these countries, and also for developed nations to fulfil their targets they are going to have to buy in carbon credits from other countries. Lastly, if you have a global scorecard for how this is going, where it is measured or just like we are here today, we are being audited, then this is something that can work.

  Mr Floater: Your specific question was, if emissions are increasing then why should we be buying credits? What we set out here is that you set a national baseline and it is important to be at the national level, and it is the reduction below that baseline that has to be measured and verified that results in the credits. You are only buying additional reductions in forest emissions.

  Q29  Joan Walley: Can I just clarify then that all of the arguments you are laying out in your report are dependant upon a new starting point, presumably through what is going on in Poznan at the moment and then in the future to Kyoto?

  Mr Floater: Yes.

  Mr Brearley: Just to look at that wider framework, essentially if you look at what we would hope for in the Review from Kyoto, it is basically a process by which countries make some form of commitment in exchange for some kind of funding mechanism. We focussed here on forestry and what we say is that the commitment that needs to be made, not a binding cap but a commitment, is to come in under your national baseline, under national business as usual emissions. Essentially that is what you get funding exchange for. Essentially if you can get into that framework—which is not about a cap and trade mechanism, the full cap or national cap for developing countries but does allow us to begin to pay for things which are additional—then I think you are in the right sort of space. Again, I would just point out that this is an issue for forestry, but it is an issue in every other sector as well. It is exactly the same question.

  Q30  Joan Walley: How would you stop, for example, a developing country from spending any revenues that were raised through these avoided deforestation schemes; how would you stop a developing company spending the money that they would then get on energy-intensive industrialised investment?

  Mr Eliasch: They would have a problem with their targets that they would have to sign up with if they did that.

  Q31  Joan Walley: How have you actually considered how you would avoid that happening?

  Mr Brearley: I think we would have to look to the wider global agreements to begin to deal with other sectors. That is where you would expect them to be binding. That is where you would expect the international response to that action.

  Q32  Joan Walley: Assuming that developing countries agree to such a target in the negotiations, how much scope will there be for trading in forest credits given that they would need to reduce emissions themselves?

  Mr Floater: By that, do you mean that there is a difficulty in reducing industrial emissions at the same time?

  Q33  Joan Walley: Given that the developing countries will want to be going ahead and reducing their own emissions, what is the effect of buying the credits in going to be on their need to reduce?

  Mr Floater: The effect of a source of finance going to developing countries through forest credits will mean that they have more funding to reduce deforestation at a greater rate. It should have no effect on their ability to reduce industrial emissions.

  Q34  Jo Swinson: In your report you are quite clear that the measures to halt deforestation and reduce deforestation will be successful only if there is a global step change in the way land is used and commodities are produced. How do you think you would actually be able to take that forward with governments to achieve that step change? What is important to make sure that happens?

  Mr Eliasch: First of all, the whole deforestation issue revolves around one thing, and that is: how do you make the standing tree worth more than the cut down tree; and how do you implement that in a process such that it is acceptable to all the stakeholders? That leads on to the fact that forestry operations need to be sustainable. It needs to be in balance with a country's need for more agricultural lands, whatever the pressures are here for more land. It is taking into account all pressures on land and trying to achieve the right balance with the funding that is required in order, through what we propose here, through various funding mechanisms, to also have an economic balance that justifies not doing things in some areas, and doing the right things in other areas.

  Mr Brearley: What we did in the Review was focus on financial incentives, and I think that is fundamental to getting a change in production away from deforestation and to more sustainable practices. I do think there is a lot more work to do, to think about how we change agricultural methods and agricultural practices to become more productive. I do think that is fundamental to the answer and not something that we looked at in perhaps as much detail as we would have liked.

  Q35  Jo Swinson: You mentioned the financial incentives, do you think that the financial resources identified through your approach would actually be able to help to fund that change to more sustainable land use, or would money have to be found from some other kind of measures?

  Mr Brearley: I think the financial incentives that we set out help that because that changes the economic incentives on access, but it is not enough just to do that. I am not sure whether the answer on how we improve production in less productive land elsewhere is just about funding. It is also about increasing our understanding and use of technology, for example. I do think there is a lot more to be thought about and to be done in that area.

  Mr Floater: Also this is not just about sustainable land use; it is not just about more efficient and more sustainable production of agricultural commodities; it is also about more sustainable timber production; it is also about infrastructure policies at a regional and national level, which is why the national level approach is so important; and it is also about conservation of areas that include indigenous peoples and also include wildlife. All of these have to be a part of the solution. In terms of the costs, we commissioned work on the opportunity costs to update those from the Stern Review, to take account of higher commodity prices currently and projected, and found that the estimate was around about $7 billion per year to halve deforestation. We then commissioned two other pieces of work to look at the rents that you would get if you were to fund this with a single carbon price. What that means is that within those rents there is an added amount of funding that could be used to address a shift to more sustainable production.

  Q36  Jo Swinson: Do you think it should be up to countries that participate in this scheme to spend the money as they see fit; or do you think that part of the funds that they get through keeping a forest standing should be directed specifically towards a move to more sustainable land use?

  Mr Floater: First of all, we have to understand that there is a national sovereignty issue here, and that nations must take a lead in the policies that they have—partly because of the importance of reducing intra-national leakage, so that you address emissions at the national level; partly for additionality reasons; but also in terms of national sovereignty. At Poznan and at Copenhagen it is going to be nation states which are negotiating a deal. There are a number of different ways in which you can distribute finance and, as I say, some of those will need to be targeted at the national and regional levels to shift whole economies out of land use that results in deforestation into, for instance, new technology sectors or other sectors that do not impact so much on the forests.

  Q37  Jo Swinson: Finally, you mentioned the move towards increased production and so on is not hugely mentioned in your report. To what extent have the negotiations, at these climate change negotiations, realised that this is not just about avoiding deforestation but is about these other land use issues that go with it?

  Mr Floater: There is certainly a good understanding amongst the UK negotiators whom I have talked with. In terms of more generally I could not say, but I think there needs to be a realisation that these elements have to be taken into consideration, and I hope they will be.

  Q38  Chairman: Unfortunately, we are running out of time. There are various other issues we might have covered because your report does raise a lot of very interesting matters, but I think we are going to have to wind up here. Thank you very much for coming in this morning, it is much appreciated. We will be working on the subject now for a few weeks and I hope we will come up with something worthwhile ourselves in due course.

  Mr Eliasch: Thank you very much.





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2009
Prepared 29 June 2009