Reducing greenhouse gas emissions from deforestation: No hope without forests - Environmental Audit Committee Contents


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 100-119)

MR DUNCAN BRACK AND MS ALISON HOARE

16 DECEMBER 2008

  Q100  Martin Horwood: You made the point very strongly that there are millions of people at the moment who are living from forests for whom some kind of alternative employment or economic benefit would have to be found. The previous witness suggested that the pure market mechanism that in a sense bypasses all these governance issues and feeds money directly to those with an interest in the forest is the best way of doing that. Can you imagine that that efficient operation of markets at international level will feed down to individual land use decisions by people who are marginal farmers or involved in land use in different ways?

  Mr Brack: In theory you could as long as you have sorted out all the problems I outlined in my previous answer, as long as forest law is clear and consistent and fairly applied, as long as land ownership tenure rights are clear, which in many countries they are not, and as long as there is redress to a fair system of dispute resolution and legal mechanisms for enforcing rights and so on. In theory I think it could happen, but again the practical problems in most countries are very, very substantial.

  Q101  Mark Lazarowicz: Given what you have just said, how far should the financial laws which would come about from various avoided deforestation mechanisms be directed, not just at land use and their management, but at encouraging political will to come about in the countries concerned, and how much is that essential to any programme?

  Ms Hoare: At the moment that is the area that has to be focussed on. Until those fundamental questions are addressed I do not think any type of market mechanism could work.

  Q102  Mark Lazarowicz: Do you agree that the international negotiations have seriously begun to address how that process could be encouraged?

  Ms Hoare: I think that in the international negotiations they have rushed ahead and there has been too much emphasis on looking at the market mechanisms and how they could be set up without looking at those other issues that need to be set in place beforehand.

  Mr Brack: I think there is a recognition that governance is a problem but not that it is a really major problem, I think you got that from the previous witnesses and the Eliash Review; it is something to be addressed but it is just another thing to be tackled. I think in most countries you cannot really put any kind of functioning REDD mechanism in place, apart from a few pilot projects in protected areas, without a pretty thorough overhaul of forestry governance. Again that is a lesson that could be learned from the FLEGT system and the way it has started to be implemented. I think it is essential that in the next year up to Copenhagen the people negotiating REDD pay attention to the lessons from the FLEGT system.

  Q103  Mark Lazarowicz: Is there any danger that the push towards a carbon market-based system could undermine some of the work that has already been done in addressing governance issues and forest management issues? If so, could you give us some examples?

  Ms Hoare: There is possibly a risk of that. Certainly with discussion of the markets and particularly with an emphasis on the potential high financial gains that in theory tropical forest countries could achieve from such markets there has been a shift in focus to that and away from looking at governance questions. It has been suggested—just returning to the question of FLEGT—that it has been a factor in the reduction in political momentum in negotiating FLEGT agreements because governments have shifted their focus to discussions about REDD and climate change.

  Q104  Mr Caton: Eliash went for a national baseline approach to minimise the risk of leakage but, as you have pointed out, this would require significant governance changes to work. Is there a danger that this would lead to a number of developing countries being unable to participate in an avoided deforestation mechanism and therefore massive increases in deforestation carrying on in those countries?

  Ms Hoare: I think there is a danger of that, yes. If you look at the case of the Clean Development Mechanism, I think it is something like 70% of CDM projects have been established in China and I think there may be one project in Africa. So this is a clear indication that the market goes where it is easiest to implement projects and to operate and the same will be true in any REDD mechanism. In relation to setting up a national system, clearly the African countries in particular are furthest behind and would need to make the most progress if any national system could be put in place. So there is a severe risk that they would be excluded from any such system.

  Q105  Mr Caton: You have told us that a project-based system would require less governance changes. Was Eliash wrong to reject that?

  Ms Hoare: The fundamental problem with a project-based approach is the question of leakage, which is a severe concern. In the long term you cannot have just a pure project-based approach, it will not be effective in reducing global emissions. As we heard previously, with a growing world population, an increasing demand for resources and commodities and so forth pressure on forests is only going to increase, so that decreases the chances of a project-based approach working. I think a project-based approach could be effective for a short period of time and can be a means of building capacity, and then scaling up from that to a national approach is the only way it would work.

  Q106  Mr Caton: Would a sort of hybrid system where you had both national and project level crediting running at the same time work or would that just have exactly the same problems with leakage?

  Ms Hoare: This is not an area I have looked at in detail. I know there are various different proposals for a hybrid approach and indeed for national and project-based approaches. The risk with a hybrid approach is that you get the worst of both worlds. If it is more towards a project-based approach you still have the question of leakage. Some proposals are that you have national level accounting plus projects which I think would still be so complicated that certain countries would be excluded.

  Q107  Mr Caton: It is a balance of risk, is it not? If the hybrid approach could bring in countries that would otherwise be excluded early on then you have averted the risk that you acknowledged in my first question, but you have taken on the risk of leakage, I take your point.

  Ms Hoare: Yes indeed.

  Q108  Dr Turner: How do you think carbon markets are going to affect indigenous people? Do you think standards could be developed to ensure that indigenous people are protected?

  Ms Hoare: It will depend on what kind of system is in place and it will depend on the particular country as well, but I think as things stand at the moment there is a high risk that they will be negatively affected. It is difficult at international level to set in place adequate safeguards to address indigenous peoples' concerns. Within most countries, as has already been highlighted, indigenous peoples do not have secure land rights or rights to forest resources and they also tend to be marginalised within society. So there are real concerns as to whether they would be able to participate effectively in consultations in defining a strategy of how to reduce deforestation.

  Mr Brack: I think there is another lesson from the FLEGT system there. In the countries which are negotiating partnership agreements you have had mostly a fairly broad stakeholder engagement within the country to varying levels of success. That kind of mechanism can be a route to involving indigenous peoples in decisions over national forestry governance, but I think you would need to see that kind of system developing if their rights can be protected under any REDD system.

  Q109  Dr Turner: There is clearly a special difficulty with some indigenous peoples who are practically back at the Stone Age in terms of cultural development and do not participate in any monetary system or any political system. How do you account for their needs?

  Ms Hoare: It is very difficult. That is a real problem that remains to be addressed. It basically highlights the fact that if you are tackling deforestation then it is not just about money and the economic value of forests, you also need to look at other aspects.

  Mr Brack: It does raise a slightly broader question about what kind of REDD projects will be put in place because you can guarantee absorbing carbon or not releasing carbon without necessarily worrying about protecting indigenous peoples' rights or biodiversity or habitats and so on, so there is the possibility of maybe trying to introduce different levels of REDD standards. I think we suggested a "gold standard" REDD credit which has co-benefits like protecting biodiversity and indigenous peoples' rights, since they will not automatically be protected just by reducing deforestation. There are so many ways of managing forests.

  Q110  Dr Turner: It is probably fair to say that there can be a conflict between forest preservation for carbon and land use by indigenous people.

  Mr Brack: Yes, that is quite right.

  Q111  Dr Turner: Do you think that the UNFCCC negotiations adequately take the forest people's needs into account?

  Ms Hoare: I think there has been growing awareness of the need to address these issues. It is starting to be, certainly, yes. There does remain the problem of what mechanism can be used to ensure that those concerns are taken into account. There are concerns from national governments about infringement on their sovereignty as to the decisions they make within country regarding their own forests and their own people and so forth. That is a very difficult balance to make.

  Q112  Dr Turner: It sounds like an unresolved situation at the moment.

  Ms Hoare: It is, yes.

  Q113  Martin Horwood: Are there any particularly good examples either from the FLEGT process and potentially also from those countries which have ratified things like ILO169 of good practice in terms of involvement and recognising the rights of tribal peoples that you can think of and any particular problem countries?

  Mr Brack: I do not know offhand. It is not an area I have particularly focussed on, but we could perhaps get back to you. Most of the examples that are cited are bad examples, but I am sure there must be a good one somewhere!

  Q114  Mark Lazarowicz: You have mentioned the FLEGT plan a few times and I get the impression you are fairly positive towards it. Given it was formally agreed more than five years ago now, how far do you really think it can be said to have made steps in terms of improving governance and also stopping the import of illegal timber into Europe?

  Mr Brack: Fairly limited steps so far, which underlines how difficult the governance issue is to address and I think that reinforces the comments we made earlier about the slow progress with tackling governance and the possibility of that slowing down the REDD negotiations. There is an issue about incentives which I will come back to. You need to bear in mind that there has only been one voluntary partnership agreement agreed so far with Ghana and that was this year; hopefully there will be another two or three quite soon. The optimistic sign is that in the countries that have been negotiating partnership agreements they have all set up this kind of stakeholder engagement system that I talked about earlier. In countries like Ghana that has given NGOs a voice in discussions about forestry governance that they have not had before and in Malaysia the same kind of thing, and the European Commission has been reasonably firm about insisting that there is the opportunity for participation from civil society. So that is opening up routes to discussions that were not there before. Capacity building is beginning to make a difference. There has been a process of reaching a consistent definition of what you mean by legality in Indonesia and in Cameroon. All of the countries that are intending to agree such agreements are deciding to license their timber exports regardless of destination. One of the problems with FLEGT is that it was restricted to timber trade between the EU and the partner company, but all of them for practical reasons are going to license all their exports, which makes it much easier to see the FLEGT licensing system developing worldwide, which is a desirable end point. In general I think it has added to the awareness of the problem of illegal and unsustainable logging and contributed to things like the fairly rapid growth of certification. Having said that, these are all early signs, there is no functioning licensing system in place yet, there will not be for another year or two until Ghana and the other countries put the practical issues in place. I think there is a problem with incentives. It is not terribly clear why countries should want to join partnership agreements. There is capacity building assistance available which is valuable, but in countries like Malaysia, where they do not have major problems in forestry governance, the incentives for them to join the system are quite limited. You are getting quite mixed messages coming from EU countries where the EU is encouraging the developing country to sign partnership agreements, but many procurement policies of EU member state governments do not accept FLEGT licensed timber or will not accept FLEGT licensed timber as allowable. That is a mixed message. I think we could be better at providing incentives for countries to join partnership agreements.

  Q115  Mark Lazarowicz: Is there any possibility of a FLEGT-type arrangement leading towards a global-type of licensing scheme for product sustainability as well as lawfulness in timber?

  Mr Brack: People are beginning to talk about the possibility of the system going global. It is very, very early days yet, but the change of administration in the US hopefully will relax some of their nervousness about joining international systems. Japan has indicated some interest in placing requirements for FLEGT licensed timber for their imports. They import a lot from Indonesia and Malaysia which are potential partnership countries. So there are optimistic signs, but any international system like that will take a while to develop. I think people should not be too concerned about the fact that FLEGT will promote legality rather than sustainability. In many forest countries if the laws are enforced properly you will get pretty close to sustainable forestry anyway. Most of their laws are written with the aim of sustainable forestry. I think to put a requirement within the FLEGT system for sustainability rather than legality now would be premature; I think it would just slow down the adoption of partnership agreements and the implementation of the system and will seem to developing countries like the EU just changing the rules yet again and putting another barrier in the way. That is a fairly widely held perception. I think it would be better seen as a very big step on the road towards sustainability. I do not think we should be too concerned about building sustainability in.

  Q116  Mark Lazarowicz: The Commission is currently looking at developing proposals to require "due diligence" to be applied regarding timber exports. I understand you have been directly involved in assessing those proposals. How far do you think those will make a difference? You will be aware that some people have suggested introducing legislation along the lines of the US Lacey Act as opposed to the current Commission proposals. How do you assess the proposals?

  Mr Brack: The principle of the due diligence regulation is already very important. It puts in place some of the incentives I was talking about before for developing countries to sign partnership agreements because if it works there will be a universal requirement effectively for proof of legality at least for all imports entering the EU. Having said that, with the state the draft regulation on due diligence is in at the moment I think it is fairly clear that the system will not work, although it is a very early draft and it is quite possible that a lot of the loopholes and the defects and the lack of clarity about many issues will be sorted out in the negotiation process about it. It is quite unclear at the moment by several things what it means, definitions, products and operators, how you can reasonably ensure legality. They talk about timber operators being able to use monitoring organisations like certification schemes or timber federations, but in reality none of the schemes or the federations at the moment could operate as a monitoring organisation under the terms of the regulation. There are quite a lot of potential loopholes including timber coming in for energy products. All of those things could be sorted out given the political will within the EU, but I think there is a major design flaw—and it is quite difficult to see how it can it be sorted out—in that implementation and enforcement is largely left to the member states rather than the Commission. In the accompanying documentation to the regulation the Commission admits that there is a problem in some of the EU member states with illegal logging already and they cite Bulgaria and Estonia as examples. They are admitting that Bulgaria and Estonia and maybe other countries are already unable to guarantee that legal timber from their own production enters the market, so it is really not clear how they can simultaneously guarantee that imports from high risk countries will also not be illegal. The regulation leaves the enforcement and the inspection of the timber operators and the monitoring organisations to member states. So you could have a number of EU member states developing as very vulnerable entry points and people wanting to ship illegal timber into the Community could just use those entry points. Unlike something like the Lacey Act, there is no subsequent check on the legality of timber anywhere in the EU. Under the due diligence regulation, once timber has entered the EU at the first point of entry into the market there is no subsequent check. It is difficult to see how the regulations as currently drafted could really deal with that; it has too many loopholes.

  Q117  Martin Horwood: Do you imagine a certification scheme working all the way down the supply chain for all paper products? Would that be your ideal?

  Mr Brack: That is what certification schemes do at the moment anyway.

  Q118  Martin Horwood: Do you see them implementing a Lacey-style Act to get over your problems you have just been talking about?

  Mr Brack: The thing about the Lacey Act is it allows the authorities to take action against people who are handling illegal timber wherever they find them. So even if, as in our example, Bulgaria has lax implementation and illegal timber enters there, if it is then shipped into the UK and the authorities have reasonable suspicions to think that the products are illegal, they can take action against it. In the UK under the due diligence regulation it cannot do that. It is only the first point of entry into the EU that is subject to any requirements.

  Q119  Mr Caton: This Committee last looked at the procurement of sustainable timber back in 2005. What is your perception of progress since that time?

  Mr Brack: There has certainly been some progress but perhaps a bit limited. On the good side, you are seeing a pretty steady increase in the volume of certified timber on the UK market and the anecdotal evidence from timber importers and retailers would suggest that it is the requirements for certified timber from government procurement policy that has had the main impact on that. The figures are not terribly good, but the evidence suggests that about 50% of imports, perhaps higher, into the UK are now certified under one of the main certification schemes and that compares to 8% of total global forests certified so that is much higher. There is no question that awareness of the requirements for legal and sustainable timber is higher amongst government agencies, but on the more negative side, CPET has carried out a study on the construction sector, which is the area of timber use that is most relevant to government procurement, and they found that implementation of the requirements was quite variable. A number of agencies were implementing their own policies which were not like the government policy at all, they were more strict and just requiring certified timber, not sustainable or legal. Very few of them were monitoring the implementation of the policy systematically. It was difficult to collect data. We think we are seeing some impact from the procurement policy, but it is clearly not being implemented as well as perhaps it could be.



 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2009
Prepared 29 June 2009