Reducing greenhouse gas emissions from deforestation: No hope without forests - Environmental Audit Committee Contents



Memorandum submitted by Ben Caldecott, Head of the Environment & Energy Unit, Policy Exchange, Dominick Spracklen, Institute for Climate and Atmospheric Science, University of Leeds, Renton Righelato, World Land Trust

SUMMARY

    —  Stopping climate change in a deforesting world is virtually impossible.

    —  Avoided deforestation and peatland destruction can be dramatically cheaper than the other carbon abatement options available, with costs ranging from US$0.1-US$30 per tonne of CO2 equivalent.

    —  Despite their significance in terms of GHG emission reductions, avoided deforestation and peatland loss are not rewarded under the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) created under the 1997 Kyoto Protocol. Afforestation and reforestation projects are covered, but have been discouraged by the complex rules and high costs involved under the CDM and to date account for only one of a thousand CDM projects.

    —  36-45% of credits in the voluntary market are generated through forest management and this market is an important financing mechanism for avoided deforestation.

    —  The backbone of anti-deforestation financing should come from the carbon market but an international fund should also be set up specifically to correct market failures.

    —  There is a legitimate concern that REDD credits could flood the market and destabilise the carbon price in existing markets. To prevent this, stricter overall emission reduction targets are required to ensure REDD credits are additional to fossil fuel reductions.

    —  Adequately protecting biodiversity will require finance streams in addition to those that are available from the carbon market. To achieve this forestry carbon finance mechanisms can be coupled with Payments for Environmental Services (PES).

    —  Mechanisms must be in place to ensure that forest communities and indigenous groups are consulted and compensated.

    —  Accurately quantifying the GHG emission reductions from avoided deforestation is vital for a proposed market in REDD credits to function. Over the past ten years there have been substantial technological advances in remote sensing techniques which now allow for an accurate quantitative analysis of deforestation at the national level.

MAIN TEXT

  1.  Every year 12 million hectares of tropical forest are cleared by human activity. This accounts for approximately 20% of total anthropogenic greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions. If we cannot stop deforestation, it will "use up" one third of the GHG emissions that humanity can emit during the 21st century, while still avoiding dangerous anthropogenic climate change (ie CO2 equivalent kept below 450 parts per million). Stopping climate change in a deforesting world is therefore virtually impossible.

  2.  By placing a value on the carbon stored in forests, deforestation can be stopped. In contrast to most other climate change mitigation options, deforestation can be slowed with little new technological innovation and comparatively small amounts of financial support. Avoided deforestation and peatland destruction can be dramatically cheaper than the other carbon abatement options available, with costs ranging from US$0.1-US$30 per tonne of CO2 equivalent (see Figure 1 in Caldecott et al, 2008). In contrast, climate change mitigation through biofuel subsidies can be expensive, with the 5% biofuel target under the Renewable Transport Fuel Obligation (RTFO) costing from US$133-US$292 per tonne of CO2 equivalent. Biofuel targets and subsidies can also create incentive mechanisms that encourage the destruction of carbon and species rich ecosystems (Righelato and Spracklen, 2007).

  3.  Efforts to conserve tropical forests have been aptly described as a "long defeat". Isolated fragments have been set aside as protected areas, but these are vulnerable to regional desiccation and climate change and elsewhere destruction proceeds unabated. Despite their significance in terms of GHG emission reductions, avoided deforestation and peatland loss are not rewarded under the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) created under the 1997 Kyoto Protocol. Afforestation and reforestation projects are covered, but have been discouraged by the complex rules and high costs involved under the CDM and to date account for only one of a thousand CDM projects (UNFCCC, 2008).

  4.  In June 2001, the Parties to the Kyoto Protocol decided to exclude avoided deforestation—meaning a rate of deforestation below the "business as usual" baseline—from the first Commitment Period (2008-12). There were several reasons for this. First, there was concern that the so called "flexible mechanisms" of the Kyoto Protocol (ie CDM and Joint Implementation) would allow developed countries to reach their targets without stringent controls on domestic fossil fuel use. Avoided deforestation was expected to yield large reductions in emissions at relatively low cost, potentially providing all the reductions required under Kyoto with no need for countries to control domestic emissions. There was also concern that avoided deforestation would distract attention from what was seen as the real business of reducing emissions from fossil fuel use. Second, there was strong opposition from some developing nations worried about the potential loss of sovereignty and constraints on their future development. For example, Brazil was in favour of carbon credits being earned for reforestation but not avoided deforestation. The sub-text was that Amazonian deforestation was out of government control so targets to reduce deforestation would be difficult or impossible to meet. Third, methodological and technical issues made accurate accounting for emission reductions from forest lands very difficult. Many developing countries had little or no capacity to monitor deforestation or ensure that forests were protected permanently.

  5.  An underlying constraint was the notion—already embedded in the thinking of the Global Environment Facility (GEF), which finances only the "incremental costs" of actions to yield global rather than national benefits—that avoided deforestation was already in the interests of forested nations (because of national benefits received from ecosystem services). Simply transferring wealth to countries to pay for things that those countries should be doing anyway was unattractive to many potential donor governments.

  6.  The failure of Kyoto mechanisms to stimulate a market in carbon credits from protection of forests and peatlands has not prevented a voluntary carbon market from making significant progress, in financial terms and in driving innovation and the development of best practices. Thus 36-45% of credits in the voluntary market are generated through forest management and this market is an important financing mechanism for avoided deforestation (Harris, 2006). Verified Emission Reduction (VER) prices from forestry activities (US$0.5-45/tCO2e) compare favourably with the costs of projects from the energy sector (US$0.5-20/tCO2e).

  7.  Important early actors in the voluntary carbon market were non-profit NGOs, which introduced many forest protection and restoration projects. Most such projects are aimed at conserving biodiversity, but they also mitigate climate change by preventing deforestation and encouraging reforestation. These are supported by private and corporate donations, and from the sale of voluntary carbon offsets. Examples include: projects financed by the Royal Society for the Protection of Birds in Indonesia (100,000 hectares) and Sierra Leone (75,000 hectares); projects supported by the World Land Trust in South America and Asia (around 150,000 hectares), plus a joint initiative with the government of Paraguay to protect a million hectares of dry Chaco forest; a million-hectare forest restoration project supported by The Nature Conservancy in Brazil; and a project involving Fauna and Flora International, local government and private companies which aims to reduce deforestation by 85% in 750,000 hectares of Indonesia to avoid the emission of 3.3 million tonnes of CO2 annually. Numerous private trusts have also bought land for conservation.

  8.  The voluntary market is also driving interest and investment in ecosystem services. In March 2008, Canopy Capital, a private equity firm, announced a deal with Guyana's Iwokrama International Centre for Rainforest Conservation and Development, to fund conservation and research in Iwokrama's 370,000 hectares of forest in exchange for the right to market the forest's ecosystem services. In the absence of detailed figures for all such activities worldwide, it is estimated that charities and their for-profit allies have protected at least 100 million hectares and are responsible for restoring up to a million hectares per year.

  9.  The IPCC estimates that deforestation could be cut by 50% with a carbon price of US$20/tCO2 equivalent. This would reduce emissions by about 2 billion tonnes of CO2 equivalent per year (Gullison et al., 2007). Financing a significant reduction in deforestation is estimated to require at least US$10-15 billion annually and there is some controversy over the best funding mechanism to raise this finance. The key difference between a carbon market with Reduced Emissions from Deforestation and Degradation (REDD) credits and an international non-market fund is that the former aims to harness the power of the carbon market to oppose deforestation, whereas the other relies on donations to a fund from which grants will go to countries that make a convincing show of reducing deforestation. Market failures cannot be ruled out and may undermine the impact of the REDD system, while the other scheme is vulnerable to parsimony (ie will donors be willing to give enough?), moral hazard (ie will developing countries misrepresent their levels of success?) and inefficiency (ie can international technobureaucratic mechanisms spend money wisely and well enough to achieve good results?). Given the nature of the risk that is being addressed, getting the answer right is not unimportant.

  10.  The poor record of intergovernmental non-market funding mechanisms such as the GEF is hardly reassuring, and donor governments may not see another such fund as the best use of tax-payers' money. On the other hand, the carbon market can mobilise abundant financing at low political cost, with more than US$30 billion traded in the carbon market in 2006 alone under the Kyoto Protocol and the EU ETS (Hasselknippe H & Rine K, 2007). One disadvantage of a market-based system is that it may allow some countries, with efficient institutions and lower marginal costs, to dominate the REDD market. Another is that market failures under REDD may well prove to be just as significant as they are in other market-based systems. An obvious conclusion is that the backbone of anti-deforestation financing should come from the carbon market but an international fund should also be set up specifically to correct market failures. Such a fund should be designed to synergise with other governmental and non-governmental technical assistance and financing flows in areas that also oppose deforestation.

  11.  Under a market based system, forestry carbon credits could either be fully fungible with existing carbon markets, that is freely tradable with fossil fuel emission reductions, or could operate through a separate system. Fungible avoided deforestation or REDD credits could limit the incentive to reduce emissions from fossil fuels. There is a legitimate concern that REDD credits could flood the market and destabilise the carbon price in existing markets. To prevent this, stricter overall emission reduction targets are required to ensure REDD credits are additional to fossil fuel reductions.

  12.  Correctly designed, forest and peatland carbon credits and markets could be powerful tools to protect important ecosystem services and biodiversity, in addition to reducing greenhouse gas emissions. In particular, avoided deforestation mechanisms offer an unparalleled opportunity to support large areas of tropical forest. However, adequately protecting biodiversity will still require finance streams in addition to those that are available from the carbon market. To achieve this forestry carbon finance mechanisms can be coupled with Payments for Environmental Services (PES). PES is a mechanism where the providers of ecosystem services are financially compensated by those that benefit from the service. Such schemes already exist, for example in Costa Rica.

  13.  Forest carbon markets will provide a significant financial resource to developing countries with forest resources. There are potential problems, particularly where there is danger of corruption and mismanagement of funds. In addition, where there is no clear land ownership and where forest communities have limited representation there is a risk of local people becoming sidelined. Mechanisms must be in place to ensure that forest communities and indigenous groups are consulted and compensated.

  14.  Accurately quantifying the GHG emission reductions from avoided deforestation is vital for a proposed market in REDD credits to function. Over the past ten years there have been substantial technological advances in remote sensing techniques which now allow for an accurate quantitative analysis of deforestation at the national level. For example, in Brazil (INPE, 2005) and India (FSI, 2004) remote sensing of forest cover is operational on a routine basis. There is a wide range of satellite sensors that are now available and operate at a variety of resolutions and coverage (Achrad et al., 2007). Coarse resolution (300m—1 km) imagery can be used to survey global forest cover trends ensuring consistent reporting across national borders and allow monitoring for potential leakage between forested regions. Higher resolution images (10-50 m) can be used for detailed monitoring in regions with active deforestation. A recent study using a probability-based sampling approach employing low and high resolution satellite data, quantified the error in global deforestation rate at less than 6% (Hansen et al., 2008). In addition to monitoring forest area, calculating GHG gas emissions also requires the change in carbon stocks to be known. Forest inventory measurements can be extrapolated using regression-based models to give forest biomass carbon maps (Gibbs et al, 2007). Above-ground carbon stocks can also be estimated from aerial imagery.

REFERENCES

Achrad, et al. 2007. Pan-tropical monitoring of deforestation. Environmental Research Letters, doi:10.1088/1748-9326/2/4/045022.

Caldecott, B L (editor, 2008) The Root of the Matter: Carbon Sequestration in Forests and Peatlands. Policy Exchange, UK.

FSI 2004 State of Forest Report 2003 (Dehra Dun: Forest Survey of India, Ministry of Environment and Forest).

Gardner, T A, and J Jones. 2008. An unprecedented opportunity for biodiversity conservation: Hopes and fears surrounding international payments for ecosystem services. Oryx. In press.

Gibbs, H K et al, Monitoring and estimating tropical forest carbon stocks: making REDD a reality. Environmental Research Letters, 2, 2007.

Gullison, R E, et al, Tropical forests and climate policy, Science 316: 985-6, 2007.

Harris E, The Voluntary Carbon Market: Current & Future Market Status, and Implications for Development Benefits, International Institute for Environment and Development, Working Paper, 26 October 2006.

Hasselknippe H & R'ine K (editors, 2007) Carbon 2007—A new climate for carbon trading. (Copenhagen: Point Carbon)

Hansen, M C; Stehman, S V; Potapov, P V, et al (2008) Humid tropical forest clearing from 2000 to 2005 quantified by using multitemporal and multiresolution remotely sensed data, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 105, 27, 9439-9444.

INPE 2005 Monitoramento da Floresta Amazonica Brasileira por Satelite, Projeto PRODES available online at http://www.obt.inpe.br/prodes/index.html

Olander, L P; Gibbs, H K; Steininger, M, et al (2008) Reference scenarios for deforestation and forest degradation in support of REDD: a review of data and methods, Environmental Research Letters, 3, 2, 025011.

Righelato, R and Spracklen, D (2007), Carbon Mitigation by biofuels or by saving and restoring forests? Science, 317 (5840), 902-902.

UNFCCC (2008), see: http://cdm.unfccc.int/Statistics/Registration/RegisteredProjByScopePieChart.html

October 2008





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2009
Prepared 29 June 2009