Reducing greenhouse gas emissions from deforestation: No hope without forests - Environmental Audit Committee Contents


Memorandum submitted by WWF-UK

1.  SUMMARY

  WWF has focussed primarily on the following:

1.1  The environmental and social risks and benefits of using financial mechanisms to address emissions from land use change

  WWF believes that REDD mechanisms should:

    —  Recognise that forests provide a wide range of values and services;

    —  Contribute to development goals and poverty reduction strategies;

    —  Actively involve all stakeholders in policy formulation and planning; and

    —  Ensure that benefits, including funds, are equitably distributed.

1.2  The use of land use change credits in carbon markets and in meeting emissions targets

  WWF believes it is important to consider the full range of options further and to understand the implications of different funding mechanisms in order to assess which are most appropriate, based on:

    —  Environmental integrity and the overall ambition of emissions reductions.

    —  Carbon market effect: eg compliance costs, effect on net global emissions.

    —  Scale and flexibility of funding.

2.  THE ROLE FINANCIAL MECHANISMS MIGHT HAVE IN HELPING TO ADDRESS EMISSIONS FROM LAND USE CHANGE

  2.1  The economic incentives for unsustainable forest management or to convert forest into agriculture land are often greater (at least in the short-term) than the incentives to conserve or responsibly manage forests. In part this is due to a failure to value the long-term economic goods and services that forests provide. Therefore, WWF recognises that providing financial incentives for forest-carbon has the potential to make forest conservation more economically viable and, therefore, to address emissions from land use change.

  2.2  An international regime to reduce emissions from deforestation will need developed countries to provide support to cover the costs of REDD over the long-term. One area for further discussion is whether funding should cover the full associated costs or whether some developing countries should be partially-compensated consistent with the principle of common but differentiated responsibilities. Support for capacity building and readiness is an immediate priority, to enable countries to prepare for a REDD mechanism in post-2012.

  2.3  In addition to the funding for REDD, it is vital to consider how funds will be managed and distributed, including the governance and flow of funding.

3.  THE ENVIRONMENTAL AND SOCIAL RISKS AND BENEFITS OF USING SUCH FINANCIAL MECHANISMS

  3.1  Forests provide a range of values and services, such as protecting water catchments, improving air quality, protecting soil and biodiversity and providing resources which support the livelihoods of people. Measures to reduce emissions from deforestation and forest degradation can provide "co-benefits" as conserving natural forests helps maintain wider environmental and social values and services. However, preventing access to these resources would create potential conflict and increased pressure on forest resources in other areas. Therefore, policies for REDD must recognise the multiple values and uses of forests and accommodate the food and resources requirements of the human population.

  3.2  Activities aimed at maintaining forest carbon could result in local communities and indigenous people losing access to land. For example, there are concerns that REDD funds might be used by countries to reinforce state and private sector control over forests. Also with potentially high rates of return from carbon offset projects, opportunities may be seized by the most powerful. Local communities often lack the secure tenure and resource rights to stake their claim. Similarly REDD funds might fuel land speculation and the appropriation of community land—either by external actors or by more powerful individuals or groups within a community.[3]

  3.3  These issues raise institutional and policy challenges to ensure the benefits and costs are fairly distributed. The issues require policies to be developed which address administration of the forest, tenure rights etc, which should be liked to national and local strategies such as poverty reduction strategies. It is important to see poverty reduction strategies as a means of tackling deforestation and unsustainable land use. Rights and livelihoods of indigenous peoples and local communities must be integral to any REDD policies and programmes. This can only be achieved through involving all local stakeholders in the development of REDD. The Stern Review[4] recognises that this requires a participatory approach to policy formulation and planning, involving stakeholders at local, sub-national and national levels.

  3.4  Policies for REDD must be consistent with other international conventions and agreements (including the Convention on Biological Diversity). To protect the rights of indigenous people and local communities, REDD mechanisms must respect, build upon and integrate the rights and needs of these people and communities.

  3.5  REDD mechanisms need to contribute to development goals and ensure that benefits, including funds, are equitably distributed, for example, by:

    —  Clarifying or enforcing land tenure and developing clear "carbon tenure".

    —  Improving governance and enforcement, eg through similar processes to those employed for the Voluntary Partnership Agreements under the EU Forest Law Enforcement, Governance & Trade Action Plan.

    —  Developing legal and institutional frameworks to address distribution of funding, including in particular an appropriate and effective administration to implement these frameworks.

    —  Ensuring active stakeholder involvement in the development of policies and programmes for REDD, eg through multi-stakeholder roundtables.

  3.6  Ensuring governance, administration and local community involvement is integral to developing effective and appropriate REDD mechanisms. This will ensure any activities to maintain forest carbon avoid negative impacts on other goals, such as poverty reduction and biodiversity conservation.

4.  THE USE OF LAND USE CHANGE CREDITS IN CARBON MARKETS AND IN MEETING EMISSION TARGETS

  4.1  The post-2012 UN climate agreement should provide a framework that ensures sufficient and sustainable incentives are provided for REDD as an integral component of the agreement. At this point, WWF believes it is important to consider the full range of options for finance further.

  4.2  A range of financial mechanisms have been proposed, which fall into the following categories:

    (a) Inclusion in carbon markets / fungibility (either with unlimited or limited access), as an offset mechanism for Annex I emissions reduction targets.

    (b) Market-linked mechanisms, such as (i) auctioning of allowances, for all allowances or specific sectors; (ii) dedicated auction revenues from national, regional or international emissions trading systems; and (iii) a levy on all or some emissions.

    (c) Voluntary funding, such as public funds additional to development aid, eg the Norwegian forest fund.

Environmental integrity

  4.3  One concern voiced with fungibility of REDD credits (and other land use and land use change and forestry (LULUCF) credits) is the risk associated if either leakage occurs (ie deforestation is displaced to other locations) or emissions reductions are non-additional (ie emissions reductions would have been delivered without additional action) or non-permanent (ie the possibility that carbon stored/sequestered will be released into the atmosphere in the future due to forest clearance, fire or disease).

  4.4  Concerns over environmental integrity of credits is not specific to REDD—eg a report by the Öko-Institut concluded that approximately 20% of Clean Development Mechanism credits are likely not to be additional.[5] Potential ways of addressing concerns with fungibility of REDD include:

    —  Excluding REDD credits from carbon markets and using only market-linked or voluntary mechanisms to fund REDD.

    —  If REDD credits are included within the carbon markets; putting conditions or restrictions in place, by limiting the amount of REDD credits, discounting, or not including activities from countries which currently have low emissions from forests within carbon markets, unless there is demonstrable additionality.

Ambition

  4.5  In addition to the environmental integrity of any emissions reductions, the ambition of the overall emissions reductions is vital. To prevent catastrophic climate change we must keep the global average temperature rise as far below 2 degrees centigrade as possible. The IPCC 4th Assessment report suggests that Annex I parties should take on greenhouse gas reduction targets of between 25% and 40% below 1990 levels by 2020.[6] In addition to this reduction in Annex I countries, some major non-Annex I parties need to "substantially deviate" from their projected future emissions.

  4.6  Therefore, to achieve the ambition of the reductions in emissions which are needed to stay below 2 degrees rise, emissions reductions from REDD (and other mitigation activities in non-Annex I countries) must be additional to action in Annex I countries. To achieve this through inclusion in the carbon market, Annex I countries must commit additional targets, on top of the 25-40% range agreed for the second phase of the Kyoto Protocol in Bali. Market-linked mechanisms and voluntary funding are not an alternative to emissions reductions from Annex I countries, as such emissions reductions from REDD would be additional.

  4.7  A number of additional elements should be applied if REDD credits are fungible:

    —  National approaches (eg national-level accounting, regulatory frameworks, reference levels, monitoring and enforcement systems) need to be in place in order to reduce transaction costs, address domestic leakage and ensure the integrity of baselines.

    —  Measures must be put in place to minimise and account for leakage, the risk of non-permanence, and to ensure the integrity of baselines.

    —  Activities in countries with low emissions from forests should not be included within carbon markets, unless there is demonstrable additionality, for example, in countries with increasing deforestation rates.

Carbon market effect

  4.8  REDD is often cited as a relatively low cost mitigation option, and therefore, integrating REDD into emissions trading is predicted to decrease costs of achieving emissions reductions.[7] While this can be beneficial in bringing down the overall costs of emissions reductions (which is one objective of the carbon markets), it may also reduce the carbon price and consequently diminish incentives for investment in potentially more costly industrial emissions reductions, such as replacing coal with renewables. However, in the long-term REDD is not likely to be less expensive than industrial emission credits, as land is a fixed good, and any REDD mechanism must ensure that a long-term incentive is provided to prevent forest conversion and degradation.

  4.9  One possible option for reducing this effect would be to apply a discount factor to credits that enter the market—eg a 3:1 ratio, where 3 REDD credits would equate to 1 tCO2 emitted by the purchaser. This approach would also help in addressing concerns around leakage and non-permanence; and would increase the overall emissions reductions achieved through the market. If applied, it would be important to ensure the discount factor still makes REDD an attractive option in developing countries (based on the revenue generated as compared with the costs).

  4.10  A related concern is the scale of potential credits from REDD and the risk of large volumes of credits "flooding the market". This could reduce the incentive for addressing industrial emissions in general, because a substantial proportion of emissions reduction targets could be achieved by purchasing REDD credits. In addition to increased targets for Annex I countries, potential mechanisms for reducing the risk of flooding the market include applying a discount factor and limiting access to REDD credits—either as part of the overall limit on the effort that can be achieved through non-domestic efforts or as a specific limit on REDD credits.

A phased approach

  4.11  If fungibility of forest-carbon credits is considered, a phased approach might be preferable, where initially REDD has limited fungibility (eg through a discount factor or firewall). As countries meet conditions demonstrating their ability to deliver monitored and verified REDD credits, the fungibility coefficients for their credits could increase, depending also on broader elements of the overall architecture, including the emissions reduction commitments by Annex I countries.

Permanence and liability

  4.12  If inclusion of REDD in the carbon market is considered, the approach used to address permanence in REDD credits is crucial in influencing "market interest" for these credits and to achieve a sufficient price for these credits. In addition, it is vital that there is a mechanism to address the risk of non-permanence and, therefore, the issue of liability for any non-permanence needs to be considered. Permanence and liability are also important elements for consideration with market-linked mechanisms and voluntary funding if we are to achieve sustainable emissions reductions.

Scale of funding

  4.13  One of the main advantages frequently cited for including REDD in the carbon market is the fact that large amounts of reliable funding can be provided. The carbon market is generating $30 billion/year and is projected to reach $100s of billion or more (these figures refer to the value of the whole carbon market, not specifically support to developing countries through CDM).[8] This indicates that there is the potential for sufficient and sustainable funding to be generated for REDD by including it within the carbon markets.

  4.14  Market-linked approaches, such as auctioning allowances or setting aside a proportion of allowances, offer the potential for achieving the scale of funding required. As one example, Norway has proposed that a portion of allowances from national emissions trading systems should be withheld. The equivalent value would be provided for international activities. With 20% of emissions reductions below 1990 levels for all Annex I countries and just 10% of the allowances set aside (and a carbon price of $30/t), this has been estimated to raise $63 billion annually (though recognising that this would not all go towards reducing deforestation).

  4.15  Indeed, within the EU ETS the current proposal is for all allowances to be auctioned by 2020 by which time the European Commission estimates that revenues could amount to around €50 billion per year across the EU.[9] The Carbon Trust estimates that the revenues from auctioning to the UK Government could be between €4 billion and €6 billion per year during the third phase (2013 to 2020).[10] These are new funds which could not have previously been anticipated before the inception of the EU ETS. The UK already plans to auction a minimum of 7% of the allowances under phase II (2008 to 2012) which could bring in around €2 billion between now and 2012.

Flexibility of funding

  4.16  While inclusion in the carbon market might be considered appropriate in certain conditions, there are likely to be a number of scenarios/circumstances where carbon markets will not provide the required financial support or incentive. Inclusion in the carbon market would only be appropriate for activities and countries where there are verified emissions reductions, and therefore, for example, this source of funding would not be appropriate for capacity building and support for readiness which will require alternative funding sources.

  4.17  Given that only two countries (Brazil and Malaysia) are predicted to be ready for early entry to a REDD mechanism based on emissions, capacity and interest,[11] this indicates a need for funding options outside the carbon market over the short-medium term. Support will be needed for countries who are building capacity for REDD or do not have sufficient capacity for monitoring, reporting and verifying emissions reductions under a national baseline.

  4.18  A further group of countries that may not be eligible for inclusion in the carbon market are those countries with high forest cover but currently low rates of deforestation or forest degradation (such as Guyana). This is due to questions about the additionality of any actions to maintain these low deforestation rates. While there may be a number of potential approaches for developing baselines for these countries, market-linked mechanisms provide a valuable alternative which might generate greater scales of funding and avoid risks of undermining the integrity of the carbon markets.

5.  THE INTERACTION OF CARBON FINANCE MECHANISMS WITH THE TIMBER TRADE

  5.1  Given the risk of non-permanence and the economic factors that often drive deforestation and forest degradation, it is vital that carbon finance mechanisms support sustainable measures to reduce emissions from forests. Therefore, carbon finance mechanisms must be underpinned by commitments to sustainable forest management. Tackling illegal logging and encouraging sustainable forest management are essential in ensuring forest resources are used in a way that allows us to meet current needs while retaining the integrity of the forest's resources and production capacity for the future. Carbon finance is a potential tool to aid those nations which suffer from deforestation to generate income to tackle poor forest security, inappropriate forest management, and over-harvesting or clearance of forests. If implemented in this way, there is the possibility for carbon finance to encourage sustainable forest management within the timber trade.

  5.2  In addition, REDD mechanisms in the post-2012 UN climate agreement should be considered as one approach to address deforestation and forest degradation, alongside further initiatives outside the UNFCCC, for example to deal with demand-side issues and to outlaw trade in illegal timber.

6.  GOVERNMENT PROGRESS ON TACKLING ILLEGAL TIMBER SINCE THE EAC 2006 REPORT ON SUSTAINABLE TIMBER

  6.1  The UK government is pro-active in supporting European legislation and providing support including funding, for other elements of the FLEGT Action Plan, such as the VPA in Indonesia. However, there has been no tangible progress on tackling illegal timber since the EAC report, as implementation of the FLEGT Action Plan has been insufficient.

7.  GOVERNMENT SUSTAINABLE PROCUREMENT OF FOREST PRODUCTS

  7.1  There has been no tangible progress on sustainable procurement of forest products by UK government departments as a whole. Once again, this is down to lack of practical action to address the problem and inadequate resourcing to meet sustainable procurement policy commitments. There is a gap between administrative and political agendas, and apart from the CPET (Central Point of Expertise on Timber Procurement) mechanism, which has struggled to deliver change or appropriate engagement; no specific efforts have been made to bridge this gap. It is not a government priority at an operational level and does not specifically figure in local authority goals for action on sustainability.

8.  THE SUCCESS OR OTHERWISE OF THE EU FOREST LAW ENFORCEMENT, GOVERNANCE AND TRADE (FLEGT) ACTION PLAN, AND GOVERNMENT SUPPORT FOR IT

  8.1  The UK government has been active in support for the FLEGT programme, and the provision of specific resources to drive FLEGT has been important to its progress. However, this needs to be supported by Europe wide legislation on illegal trade in forest goods to have any real meaning. Standards agreed in the VPAs are critical to success, and to ensure that FLEGT does not lead to more confusion in the market over the comparability of legal standards and assurances.

13 October 2008









http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=IP/08/80&format=HTML&aged=1&language=EN&guiLanguage=en




3   Griffiths (2007) Seeing "RED"?: "Avoided deforestation" and the rights of Indigenous Peoples and local communities Back

4   Stern Review, 2006, The Economics of Climate Change Back

5   O²ko-Institut, 2007, Is the CDM fulfilling its environmental and sustainable development objectives? Back

6   IPCC, 2007, Full working group III report, chapter 13, Page 776, http://www.ipcc.ch/pdf/assessment-report/ar4/wg3/ar4-wg3-chapter13.pdf Back

7   Strassburg et al, 2008, An Empirically-Derived Mechanism of Combined Incentives to Reduce Emissions from Deforestation Back

8   Schwartzman et al, 2007, Getting REDD Right Back

9   "Boosting growth and jobs by meeting our climate change commitments" European Commission press release announcing the release of the climate and energy package, January 2008 Back

10   "Cutting carbon in Europe-the 2020 plans and the future of the EU ETS" Carbon Trust, 2008 Back

11   Boucher, in press Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2009
Prepared 29 June 2009