Ofwat price review 2009 - Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Committee Contents


Memorandum submitted by UNISON (Ofwat 16)

1  INTRODUCTION

  1.1  UNISON is the UK's leading public services union, representing 1.3 million people across local government, the health service, housing, the utilities, transport and the voluntary sector.

1.2  In the water industry our members include engineers, scientists, technicians, industrial workers and staff working in offices and call centres.

1.3  They deliver a safe and wholesome drinking water supply, maintain the sewerage system, provide a wide range of customer services and staff the phone lines for emergency calls from the public.

  1.4  In addition to being a key stakeholder on industrial and occupational issues, our members also actively engage in public debates about all our public services and utilities from a citizenship perspective.

  1.5  Although UNISON has not engaged with the OFWAT price review we do note that the Committee's current enquiry into the review overlaps with a number of wider issues that are of interest and concern to our members:

    —  how long-term planning for climate change and environmental improvements should be paid for;

    —  affordability of water services; and

    —  the Cave Review.

  1.6  With this in mind we are submitting this short note setting out our position on each of these areas.

2.  PAYING FOR CLIMATE CHANGE AND ENVIRONMENTAL IMPROVEMENTS

  2.1  We think there is a strong case for environmental costs to be stripped out of water charges and added to general taxation. This would help to reduce significant regional variations in water charges and reflect the wider public benefit of environmental goods.

2.2  We believe that water charges should be fair across customer groups, fair to water companies and encourage sustainable use of water and sewerage services. Expecting areas with vulnerable coast lines or susceptibility to flooding to pay more threatens to undermine these principles.

3.  AFFORDABILITY OF WATER SUPPLIES

  3.1  UNISON is concerned that the current system of water charging is leading to affordability issues. This is because the volunteristic, optional shift to metering is, in general terms, resulting in lower bills for those who switch and ever higher bills for those who do not. In many cases the former include households in high rateable value properties who previously paid most and the latter include larger families in low rateable value homes who would, in many cases, have previously paid less. This, we would argue, is leading to the worst of possible worlds:

    —  the social cross subsidy inherent under rateable value is breaking down and so far there is nothing to replace it;

    —  water companies have little option but to compensate for loss of income from high rateable customers by increasing the bills of those remaining on unmeasured tariffs; and

    —  absence of comprehensive means for encouraging sustainable use of water and sewerage services.

  3.2  In our view there is a strong case for moving to a fully metered system as soon as possible, underpinned by a fair and progressive rising block tariff system that provides lower average bills for modest users and creates an incentive for more efficient use. This should be based on volume usage, with the lower tariff payed for the essential use block (and more for subsequent blocks) but also recognise and compensate those on low incomes and essential users, such as large families with children and those with special needs, ie medical. Moreover, any fair charging system must be able to clearly identify the service provider (the water company) and the customer (the user). This requires a clearer, more formal link between the two parties concerned that will assist in the identification of households in need of special assistance.

  3.3  We note that water affordability will always have to be defined relative to income and that previous government analysis suggested that 40% of the lowest income households could be paying more than 3% of their disposable income on water and sewerage bills. There would, we believe, be value in establishing a water affordability standard. This should be defined as less than 3% of disposable income.

  3.4  When metering is introduced Government should simultaneously introduce a national scheme designed to incentivise the public to scrap their old and inefficient domestic equipment, including showers, washing machines and boilers. This could reduce water consumption by up to 50% with consequential benefits for the water environment and a reduction in the need for capital investment by water companies which in turn will help keep prices down.

4  THE CAVE REVIEW

  4.1  UNISON is concerned that there is an a priori assumption underpinning the Cave Review that unbundling or competition will lead to efficiency gains, improvements in service quality, or innovation. We note that the experience in the UK and the EU with sectors such as electricity and rail, as well as the international evidence from the water sector, suggests otherwise.

4.2  Internationally, vertical unbundling of the water sector is unusual, and the few examples involve public sector companies—not competing private suppliers.

  4.3  Unbundling would undermine the principle of integrated river basin management (IRBM), pioneered in England and Wales, which has since been emulated in a number of countries, and which has become an established principle eg in Agenda 21. The problems caused by the fragmentation of responsibility through outsourcing have been clearly seen in the railways industry both in the UK and also the USA, and were evident in a case of multiple deaths from water contamination in Canada 8 years ago. Moreover, in the electricity sector, the private companies have consistently pursued a policy of vertical reintegration.

  4.4  Experience with sectors liberalised under EU directives, such as electricity and gas, do not support the assumption that competition will follow, nor that there are benefits to consumers.

  4.5  Experience in electricity markets in the UK, EU and USA shows that the transaction costs of switching electricity suppliers are higher than any possible benefits from prices. Tacit collusion between companies is widespread, and, in the USA, prices are clearly higher in states that liberalised than in states which did not.

  4.6  There are weaknesses in the current regulated system. The private companies' records on investment and efficiency are not as good as asserted by OFWAT, which itself has a poor record of dealing with "gaming" by the companies, or dealing with leakage. However, there is no evidence at all that unbundling or competition would solve these problems. Nor does the experience of other sectors support the assertion that competition would generate innovation: in electricity, expenditure on R&D has clearly fallen, both in the UK and throughout the EU, since liberalisation. The complex social, health and environmental issues surrounding water are better addressed through stronger regulation driven by government initiatives. Other countries are seeing increased public participation as a way of developing democratic pressure for innovation.

  4.7  In a capital-intensive industry such as water, the cost of capital has a greater impact on prices than operating costs. This area is virtually ignored by OFWAT and does not feature in the Cave Review's TORs, despite the facts that controlling capital costs has been a major problem for OFWAT. In respect of "capital market competition", the review report should look at the private equity and infrastructure funds whose capital costs are both obscure and exacerbated by uncompetitive allocation of "management fees".

  4.8  Greater reliance on competition risks being a dangerous distraction from the business of delivering benefits to communities in a complex sector where the interface between social, environmental and technical dimensions have implications going beyond the tenets of traditional economic theory. Strengthening the current regulatory and institutional arrangements remains the most credible approach to containing the preponderant capital costs characterising the water industry.

  4.9  Finally, there has never been any "competition for the market"—the water supply and sewerage companies were given monopoly licences in 1989 without any competition. These licences expire in 2014, so there is an opportunity for the first time to conduct a comprehensive review of water services and their regulation by OFWAT.

UNISON

February 2009







 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2009
Prepared 24 July 2009