Documents considered by the Committee on 21 October 2009, including the following recommendations for debate: International climate finance, EU aid effectiveness - European Scrutiny Committee Contents


1  INTERNATIONAL CLIMATE FINANCE


(30910)
13183/09
+ ADD 1
COM(09) 475
Commission Communication: Stepping up international climate finance: A European blueprint for the Copenhagen deal


Legal base
Document originated10 September 2009
Deposited in Parliament17 September 2009
DepartmentEnergy and Climate Change
Basis of considerationEM of 8 October 2009
Previous Committee ReportNone, but see footnotes 1 and 4
To be discussed in Council See para 1.22 below
Committee's assessmentPolitically important
Committee's decisionFor debate in European Committee A

Background

1.1 In our Report of 4 March 2009, we drew to the attention of the House a Communication[1] relating to the international climate change negotiations to be held in Copenhagen at the end of this year. We noted that the Commission regards a successful conclusion to those negotiations as a key Community priority if its agreed objective of limiting the average global temperature increase to less than 2°C compared with pre-industrial levels is to be achieved, and that it had reiterated that the Community should be willing to agree to a reduction by 2020 of 30% in its greenhouse gas emissions in 1990 in the context of a comprehensive international agreement, involving comparable reductions by other developed countries and appropriate contributions by the economically more advanced developing countries. The Commission also said that any agreement must be underpinned by adequate financial resources for its implementation, and it has now sought in this further Communication to suggest ways in which this might be achieved, though it stresses that the figures quoted should be seen, not as formal proposals, but as indications of the order of magnitude of the finance likely to be required if the Copenhagen conference achieves an ambitious outcome.

The current document

1.2 The Commission says that the aim of the paper is to break the current impasse where developed countries expect developing countries, especially those most economically advanced, to contribute to the overall effort to reduce emissions, whilst developing countries want to see a clear position from developed countries on finance for mitigation and adaptation. It looks in turn at ways of generating adequate flows of finance, the contribution which the Community might make, and the ways in which decentralised, bottom-up finance might be organised.

GENERATING ADEQUATE FINANCIAL FLOWS

1.3 The Commission suggests that around €100 billion a year will be needed by 2020 for adaptation and mitigation, but points out that this is very often wrongly equated to the contribution needed from the public budgets of developed countries, whereas contributions can be expected from a variety of different sources, with public and private domestic finance, and flows leveraged by the carbon market, perhaps contributing between them some 60-80% of the overall amount required. In particular, it says that the further development and expansion of the carbon market should be the main means whereby private-sector carbon finance supports mitigation activities in developing countries, leaving public finance to focus in the short and medium term (and beyond) on adaptation, capacity building, and technology research, development and demonstration.

Mobilising domestic private finance

1.4 The Commission believes that domestic private finance will constitute a large part of the necessary investment in both developed and developing countries, and that the major part of what is needed for developing countries as a whole to limit their emissions growth by 2020 to roughly 15-20% below "business as usual" is already commercially viable, with additional investment being recouped by reduced energy bills. It points out that private investment can be stimulated through the right policy framework, including emissions trading schemes covering key sectors, national regulations, and financial incentives, and that developing countries are already introducing energy efficiency standards in excess of old carbon intensive technologies, with many of the more economically advanced, such as Brazil, having sufficient resources at their disposal, and the potential for a large contribution from private households for whom adaptation is in their own interest. That said, it recognises that the poorest countries, together with the poorest segments of the population in developing countries, will not have sufficient means for the investment needed, and will depend largely on both domestic and international public finance.

Making full use of the carbon market

1.5 The Commission says that the international carbon market has been an effective means of leveraging private sector investment in developing countries, whilst allowing developed countries to achieve their emission reduction targets cost-effectively. However, it observes that the project-based Clean Development Mechanism (CDM)[2] provided for under the Kyoto Protocol needs to be substantially reformed, crediting only those projects which produce real additional reductions and focussing on the least developed countries (LDCs). In addition, a new sectoral carbon market crediting mechanism for more economically developed countries (and highly competitive economic sectors) should be phased in after 2012, as an interim step towards the introduction of cap and trade systems in developing countries.

1.6 It adds that, in moving beyond a project-based approach, any new sectoral mechanism should deliver a significant scaling up of investment in low-carbon technologies in developing countries, with the driving force being a robust medium-term carbon price in OECD countries. It also believes that the international carbon market delivers a number of benefits, by cutting global mitigation costs by about a quarter by 2020, by generating financial flows to developing countries of around €38 billion a year, and by leveraging substantially more finance into low carbon development investments. However, it warns that the potential scale of these financial flows will depend upon the structure of the Copenhagen agreement, and that the parties will need a high level of ambition for emission reduction targets from developed countries and for the starting levels of emission reduction paths for the period 2013-20 if the requisite supply-demand balance is to be achieved across all countries listed in Annex I of the UNFCCC,[3] noting that the carbon price and financial flows to developing countries in the period 2008-2012 are largely the result of the action taken by the Community.

The scale of international public funding

1.7 The Commission observes that, the less delivered by the carbon market, the greater will be the demand for public finance for mitigation, but that the scale cannot be predicted with certainty at this stage, requiring a regular review via a proposed High Level Forum on International Climate Finance (see below). In the meantime, it suggests that the amount of public finance required is likely to rise gradually, and will be linked to the level of ambition in developing countries. It also says that the emphasis immediately after the Copenhagen agreement should be mainly on capacity building, since the demand for public finance is likely to rise with the implementation of mitigation action plans, and it will also be needed to stimulate private sector investment into research, development and demonstration.

1.8 In particular, it suggests that:

  • the additional costs for developing countries which cannot be covered by the carbon market will be around €33 billion a year in 2020, though most of these would be long-term, low-cost efficiency measures which should be financed domestically, mainly from private sources, leaving only about 10-20% of these additional costs (€3-6 billion), mainly in the poorer developing countries, to be funded by international public support;
  • the additional costs of reducing non-carbon dioxide emissions from agriculture, and carbon dioxide emissions from deforestation and forest degradation, would be around €23 billion a year, with public finance being the predominant incentive in the two latter cases until 2020: as most of the mitigation potential is in the poorer developing countries, a larger share of the additional costs (from 30% to 60%), equivalent to €7-14 billion, will probably have to be covered by international public finance, and the Commission draws attention to its earlier Communication[4] on a Global Forest Carbon Mechanism, which would be supported by revenues from the auctioning of allowances under the revised Emissions Trading Scheme, raising between €1.5 and 2.5 billion in 2020;
  • taking these elements together, global public transfers in 2020 for mitigation could be between €10 and €20 billion in 2020, with about one third of that amount in 2013, but the actual flows will depend critically upon the availability and quality of low-carbon growth plans of developing countries (and proposals for mitigation action);
  • the current emission reduction pledges of developed countries do however imply much lower flows of carbon finance, and those countries will come under pressure to finance additional reductions in developing countries;[5]
  • international public funding for capacity building and cooperation for research and technology demonstration has been estimated at an additional €2 to 6 billion in 2020;
  • public funding, both domestic and international, will be an important source of finance for adaptation in the poorer developing countries, with the UNFCCC Secretariat having estimated that the adaptation costs for all developing countries could range from €23 — 54 billion a year in 2030, implying global public transfers of €10-24 billion a year in 2020.

The Commission also suggests that adaptation financing will probably originate primarily from the public sector as a combination of direct budgetary outlays from contributing partners and as a share of carbon market revenues, with a need for a strategic integration of climate change adaptation concerns in all sectors of national development strategies.

Fast-start international public funding 2010—12

1.9 The Commission suggests that, if there is an overall deal in Copenhagen which implies fast-start international funding, initial contributions should concentrate on (i) financing the process and capacity building required, and (ii) estimating the likely impact of climate change, integrating adaptation into national development strategies and financing priority investments. It also considers that additional finance should be mobilised in the short term to respond to urgent and identified needs for the most vulnerable developing countries, small island developing states and African countries, including a further strengthening of disaster risk reduction capacity, with the initial contribution being progressively scaled up after 2012 as needs are quantified, capacity for implementation is built up, and an agreement is reached in Copenhagen on a scale of contributions. It believes that this would imply a public contribution from the developed world of €5-7 billion between 2010 and 2012.

Financing from international aviation and maritime transport

1.10 The Commission notes that the Council has highlighted the benefits from global instruments which address emissions in international aviation and maritime transport, and that this would have the potential to provide a significant source of finance to support the mitigation and adaptation efforts of developing countries, either through cap-and-trade systems or through a levy on emissions. At the same time, however, it says that the challenges involved in establishing such a framework should be recognised, but that, given the need to develop this at a global level if the sectors in question are to make a meaningful contribution, a workable compromise might be to make all subject to the same overall cap with full auctioning, whilst redistributing some auction revenue to developing countries, depending on their respective emissions and economic capabilities.

Determining contributions to international public finance

1.11 The Commission says that the substantial public resources needed will come in different forms and via different channels, and that the Copenhagen agreement should include a common scale based on agreed principles to determine the financial contributions of different countries, taking into account their overall effort (including effort reduction commitments). It notes that the European Council in June 2009 expressed a preference for contributions based upon ability to pay (GDP) and responsibility for greenhouse gas emissions, with the need for any distribution key to be "universal", extending beyond developed countries (but excluding LDCs), bearing in mind that some of the more economically advanced developing countries have significant levels of emissions and GDP.

1.12 It suggests that, although the actual contribution would depend upon the relative weight given to the two criteria, the Community's share could range from around 10% if the only criterion is emission levels to 30% if GDP is used (which, on the various estimates above, implies a contribution of €0.9-3.9 billion in 2013, rising to €2-15 billion in 2020). It also points out that giving relatively more weight to emissions would provide an additional incentive to cut these, but lead to relatively higher contributions from major emitting developing countries. However, in the case of fast-funding, it suggests that, in view of the importance of early capacity building and adaptation, the Community should consider whether to increase its contribution above the 10-30% range.

1.13 The Commission has summarised these various figures in the following table, showing the estimated international annual public finance requirements over the period 2010-2020 (in €billion):

  
2010-2012
(fast start)
2013
2020
Mitigation
 Energy and industry
 Agriculture and forestry
1
3-7
10-20
3-6
7-14
Adaptation
2-3
3
10-24
Capacity building
1-2
2
1-3
Technology, research etc
1
1
1-3
Total
5-7
9-13
22-50


THE COMMUNITY CONTRIBUTION TO PUBLIC FINANCE

1.14 The Commission first considers how the Community can make an ambitious and fair contribution, and says that there are strong arguments for it making a single global offer, which would ensure coherence and visibility, allow for a fair and transparent distribution between Member States, permit economies of scale in the management of disbursements, and strengthen the Community's voice in ensuring proper implementation. It adds that the Community will also need to consider three options for channelling such funding — direct funding through the Community budget (which would take advantage of existing procedures, offer rigorous financial control and a standard funding key, and involve the European Parliament), establishing a new common Climate Fund through bilateral contributions from each Member State (though this would require its own inter-governmental agreement and legal basis, be outside the Financial Framework and Own Resources ceiling, and not involve the European Parliament), and direct financial contributions from Member States (provided this was clearly presented as part of the Community's single global offer).

1.15 The Commission next considers how the Community budget can be mobilised up to 2012. It says that, whiles the main financial implications of an agreement in Copenhagen would come into effect from 2013 at the earliest, such an agreement would be accompanied by a swift increase in support to developing countries, which should be partly financed through the Community budget, subject to the availability of resources. It points out that it has already proposed an additional €50 million for fast-start activities in 2010, and that comparable figures would be needed for subsequent years: and it adds that identifying appropriate sources will not be easy, since the remaining margins are extremely limited and existing programmes already under pressure, requiring creative solutions and a need to assess the optimal mix of funding sources.

1.16 The Commission also looks at an equitable Community contribution beyond 2012, noting that the budgetary implications of an ambitious agreement at Copenhagen for the Community and Member States are likely to be substantial, running to several billion euros a year. It also notes that this would raise a particular issue for 2013 for which the financial framework has already been set, but will thereafter be an issue for the new financial framework. More specifically, it reiterates that, if contributions are based on the ability to pay and emission levels, the greater the emphasis on the first of these, the higher the Community contribution will be. In addition, it also considers the mechanisms which could be used to adjust the burden on specific Member States, noting that these have at their disposal significant revenues from auctioning, and that Directive 2009/29/EC requires at least 50% of these resources to be re-cycled for domestic and international climate change purposes — a figure which it suggests would be well in excess of the maximum amount of €3 billion which the Community would be required to finance in 2013.

DECENTRALISED, BOTTOM-UP CLIMATE CHANGE GOVERNANCE

1.17 The Commission says that there needs to be an efficient, effective and equitable governance structure, which builds on the principles of country ownership, subsidiarity, coherence, transparency, accountability, rewarding performance, additionality and complementarity. It adds that any blueprint should be based upon low-carbon growth plans by developing countries, which would be reviewed by an independent "co-ordinating mechanism"; that such strategies should be presented by all countries — including the Community — by 2011, and that, although this obligation should not apply to the LDCs, they should be encouraged to move in this direction over an appropriate time-scale; that a bottom-up approach should involve the gradual integration of climate resilience into national plans; that existing institutions and structures should be used wherever possible; and that a High Level Forum on International Climate finance should be created to identify gaps and imbalances for mitigation and adaptation actions, give political guidance, and ensure that funds are distributed equitably.

The Government's view

1.18 In his extremely detailed Explanatory Memorandum of 8 October 2009, the Secretary of State for Energy and Climate Change (Rt Hon Ed Miliband) sets out the Government's views on the various aspects of the Communication.

1.19 As regards the generation of adequate finance flows, he says that the Government:

  • welcomes the inclusion of a global figure for the finance needed (and its breakdown into public and private finance, and mitigation and adaptation components), and it hopes that the Community will use this to agree on an overall figure for the international community to work towards by 2020;
  • will continue to look further into the Commission's breakdown of international public financing needs, but notes that the UK has proposed $100 billion (€68 billion) as a working figure;
  • supports the Commission's call for fast-start funding for 2010-2012, and has already invested significant sums for pre-2013 financing through the newly established Climate Investment Funds, the Global Environment Facility and UN Funds, whilst continuing to support countries on a bilateral basis (including through the Department for International Development);
  • agrees with the Commission's recognition of the role of the carbon market and the need for reform of existing mechanisms, in order to facilitate the scaling up of financial flows for mitigation and technology transfer to developing countries;
  • supports Commission proposals for the phase-in of the sectoral carbon market crediting mechanism for economically more advanced developing countries and highly competitive economic sectors: and, although it believes that it is too early to set a phase in date, it welcomes 2012 as an ambitious starting point for discussion;
  • believes that agreement to a clear timetable for the phase-in is needed to reduce investment uncertainty, but considers that the CDM will continue to have a role during this period, and in countries and sectors not covered by the sector mechanism, and that agreement on its reform is therefore important in the shorter term;
  • emphasises that sector-based emissions trading in developing countries — an option not mentioned in the Communication — offers significant advantages over other mechanisms in terms of emissions certainty, upfront incentives and engaging private sector finance;
  • welcomes the Commission options for financing emissions reductions from reducing deforestation and degradation, and recognises a role for offsetting and sector-sector trading in the forest sector before 2020, noting that it is unlikely there will be full access of forest emissions reductions to the market before 2020, not least because of the need for capacity building in developing countries;
  • shares the Commission's view on offset credits;
  • welcomes the further analysis provided on innovative financing from international aviation and maritime transport, believing it is important that such emissions (which could also provide significant revenue for innovative climate financing) are brought into the Copenhagen agreement;
  • believes that ensuring financial flows are predictable will be key, and is willing to support an international mechanism for the setting aside and auctioning of a small percentage of national emissions allowances;
  • strongly agrees that a Copenhagen agreement should include a common international scale based on agreed principles to determine individual countries' contributions to international public finance, based on the 'ability to pay' and 'responsibility for emissions';
  • believes that, whilst the Commission's estimate that the Community's financial contribution would be between 10 and 30% are not final figures, it is important to put finance on the table, in order to help build trust with developing countries.

1.20 As regards the Community's contribution to public climate change finance, he:

  • says that the Government has a clear position on additionality, believing that public finance should be additional to Official Development Assistance targets, and that only a limited proportion (up to 10%) of that Assistance should be able to play a role in helping fight climate change at the same time as meeting poverty reduction objectives;
  • notes the Commission's proposals for the Community budget in 2010 and for the next financial perspective starting in 2014, adding that the UK supports fundamental reform, with a re-orientation of resources towards addressing climate change, and will continue to consider the suggestions for the use of the Community budget for international climate financing, as one of a number of options for meeting any commitments made at Copenhagen.
  • says that the Government agrees with the European Council that the Community should be willing to contribute its fair share of the global financial effort and that 'ability to pay' and 'responsibility for emissions' should be the preferred principles.

1.21 As regards as the blueprint for decentralised, bottom-up climate finance governance, the Minister says that the Communication puts forward some useful ideas, and that the Government particularly welcomes its views on a developing country-led approach to integrating both mitigation and adaptation into national plans and the planning process, regarding this as a crucial principle which should be reflected clearly in concrete proposals. He adds that the Government welcomes the suggestion of a new high level forum to ensure better coordination of financing flows, but would also like to see that body able to manage a portion of international climate finance, and allocate this to different spending themes, adding that there is a need for further substantial discussion with both developing and developed countries on the structure of this body, its exact functions and its relationship with the UNFCCC. However, the Government agrees with the Commission that the body should not be involved in country-level programmes or projects, with the emphasis being instead on national structures and donor coordination around country plans, which should help existing bilateral and multilateral institutions to scale up finance with a focus on recipient country priorities. Finally, he says that the establishment of a technical coordination mechanism for mitigation is consistent with Government thinking, though it would like to see that mechanism have some financial responsibility. It is also clear that the mechanism should be a technical not a political body, which should not have responsibility for assessing the level of mitigation ambition in national plans; that the review of the coordination mechanism should establish whether national plans will deliver this ambition, and that there is value in establishing a similar mechanism for adaptation.

1.22 As regards timing, the Minister says that, since this is not a legislative proposal, there is no formal timetable, but that the ideas in the Communication are being discussed in the run up to the ECOFIN Council on 20 October, the Environment Council on 21 October, and the European Council on 29-30 October.

Conclusion

1.23 As is evident, this is a complex document, containing a plethora of figures which makes it difficult in places to distinguish the wood from the trees. Having said that, it is clearly also an important document, in both its substance and timing, given the crucial role which finance will play in securing any climate change agreement at Copenhagen. Moreover, the amount of international finance which may be required is not only potentially very large, and linked to the outcome at Copenhagen, but also dependent upon a number of assumptions as to the likely contribution of private finance, the extent to which the carbon market, particularly in other developed countries, can play a greater part, and the way in which any figure is apportioned between the Community and other contributors.

1.24 For all these reasons, we believe that the document raises important issues which the House would wish to consider further, and we are therefore recommending it for debate in European Committee A.




1   (30412) 5892/09: see HC 19-ix (2008-09), chapter 1 (4 March 2009). Back

2   This is an offset mechanism under which developing countries can sell credits which represent emission reductions achieved by a specified project: these credits can then be bought by a developed country in order to comply with its national reduction target, and so provide finance for clean technology in the developing country concerned. Back

3   United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change. Back

4   (30047) 14473/08: see HC 19-x (2008-09), chapter 3 (11 March 2009). Back

5   For example, the Commission says that, if the emission reduction target for developed countries were to be reduced from 30% to 10% (the low end of current pledges), this would require the transfer of international public finance of around €120 billion a year in 2020. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2009
Prepared 30 October 2009