Sustainable Development in a Changing Climate - International Development Committee Contents


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 80-99)

MS VICTORIA JOHNSON, MR JONATHAN MITCHELL, DR MURRAY SIMPSON AND MS GILLIAN COOPER

10 FEBRUARY 2009

  Q80 Chairman: Good morning, thank you very much, all of you, for coming in to help us with this inquiry. I wonder if you could introduce yourselves for the benefit of the shorthand writer; if we could start with Mr Mitchell.

  Mr Mitchell: Good morning; my name is Jonathan Mitchell, I work for the Overseas Development Institute, just across the river, a development policy think-tank. I head the tourism programme and the rural livelihoods programme.

  Ms Johnson: I am Victoria Johnson, I work for the New Economics Foundation, Climate Change and Energy Team. It is a think-tank based in Vauxhall and is an economic think-tank looking at environmental issues, social justice and well-being.

  Dr Simpson: I am Dr Murray Simpson, a senior research fellow at Oxford University, working in the School of Geography on tourism, climate change and development.

  Ms Cooper: I am Gillian Cooper and I work for Tourism Concern which is a non-profit organisation looking at maximising the benefits of tourism to developing countries and communities.

  Q81  Chairman: Thank you very much for that. As you will appreciate, the title of our inquiry is Sustainable Development in a Changing Climate and we mean the physical climate and the financial climate; we are looking at both aspects of how these things impact developing countries and, in particular for this session, the role of aviation and tourism and fresh produce and so forth. I wonder if I could start with you, Victoria Johnson, as you take a rather different perspective. In your report Plane Truths you are in favour of a carbon tax, focused at a sufficiently high level to discourage demand for air travel, which is a perfectly understandable concept. But first of all could you actually explain what level you are thinking of, what impact you believe would be necessary to have an effect on discouraging air travel. Also, are you talking about a distinction between long and short haul flights, because clearly they are different options?

  Ms Johnson: First of all in the report we did not set an actual level for a carbon tax, although we did look at some economic analyses that had looked at the Air Passenger Duty as it was in 2001 and a doubling of that, which has happened now, and another Conservative Party-proposed green tax, all of which we set at a level of €15 per tonne of carbon. The analysis showed that that would have a very small effect on air travel, one of the reasons being that the elasticities for air travel vary, but we did make a distinction between short haul and long haul flights for two reasons, mainly that it is much easier to substitute the mode of transport for short haul flights. In the Plane Truths report we looked at tourism flows from the UK to tourist destinations and found that around three in every four flights are short haul flights, a large proportion of which are under 500 kilometres and it is actually perfectly reasonable to assume that you can use other modes of transport for that distance. A lot of the travel is also short breaks, and in terms of the Committee meeting today and the impact of the tax on developing countries and the tourism industry there we found that only 9% of all the flights leaving the UK actually go to what are classed as global south countries. Other than that if you reduce short haul flights significantly and have a higher tax for short haul flights there will be less impact on long haul flights, in particular those to developing countries.

  Q82  Chairman: We might explore that also with the other witnesses in terms of how much of an impact that would have, but in terms of the money raised, do you have a view as to how it should be applied? One suggestion is that it should be allocated to developing countries to cope with climate change adaptation; is that something that you would support or that you have a view on? Is it just a tax to discourage aviation which disappears into the general coffers, or do you believe it is a tax that should be specifically applied in a particular way and perhaps do you think it could be applied in ways that would be directly beneficial to developing countries who are suffering from climate change rather than causing it?

  Ms Johnson: In the report we suggested that the tax be used for investment into low carbon modes of transport such as rail links and also contributing to adaptation aid for developing countries.

  Q83  Chairman: You mentioned statistics about the number of flights and the percentage of flights going to developing countries, but do you accept that there could be an implication either now or in terms of future development for countries which have either developed niche markets to supply fresh produce to Europe or to America, or who have developed a tourism industry to encourage long haul tourists? Do you accept that for some countries that could be a significant disincentive or deterrent to the development of these sectors?

  Ms Johnson: One of the key analyses that we did in the report was looking at the impact of curbing aviation growth or halting aviation growth from 2009 and we forecast the impact on total GDP from 2009 to 2025. In that analysis we looked at four countries which were Kenya, Dominican Republic, Thailand and the Maldives, so they were four very different countries. The Dominican Republic has a very high level of all-inclusive resorts and Kenya, Thailand and the Maldives are developing countries, with the Maldives being a small island state, all of which have quite a high dependence on tourism, particularly tourists from the UK. In that analysis we compared the halt in growth with the forecast provided by the UN World Tourism Organisation and we found that from the UK only—and I should make it clear this was specifically halting growth in aviation from the UK—the impacts on GDP were not as high as we had expected. If I can just read out some figures and I will then explain them in some more detail, for Kenya by halting growth the real revenue lost between 2009 and 2025 was 0.07%; for the Maldives it was 3.42%; for Thailand 0.17% and the Dominican Republic 0.39%. In that figure we did include something called leakage which I am sure you are familiar with but includes the money that basically leaves the national economy. We looked at a number of different leakage rates from 30% to 60% and we also looked at linkages as well which means the money that actually stays within the economy. Whilst there is a loss and you cannot deny that there would be a loss—it is only logical to assume that there would be a loss to the economy—it is less than we would have expected. Our conclusion from that was that because such a large amount of money was repatriated to international tour operators and spending on imports, tighter regulation of the tourism industry, which is one of the most unregulated industries, would actually be one solution to dealing with such a loss so you would not necessarily have to grow tourism in order to increase the real revenue to developing countries, based on the examples that we used in the report.

  Q84  Chairman: If I have understood that correctly what you are saying is that the same amount of business could grow the economy if it was more fairly shared. Is that the implication of what you are saying?

  Ms Johnson: Yes, in the sense that if more money was spent in the local economy and used to support the local economy rather than leaving the country that would be the case.

  Q85  Chairman: I have to say that some of your figures for those countries, particularly for somewhere like the Maldives, seem surprisingly small but I accept that is your evidence. Perhaps I could bring in the other witnesses, not necessarily to comment on that, although you are welcome to do so if you want to, but given that that is a proposal on aviation tax, to try and discourage aviation, and obviously we try to evaluate how that is going to affect poorer countries, what is the likelihood of there actually being either a global carbon tax or any other form of tax on aviation, perhaps in time for the summit in Copenhagen this year? Is there a realistic prospect of that happening?

  Dr Simpson: In terms of a direct answer to your question there are a number of countries looking at aviation tax and obviously the EU Emissions Trading Scheme is one of those elements that may put pressure on for an aviation tax to come in, but it is not as simple as just an aviation tax, there are other issues surrounding the price structure of aviation, not least oil prices of course, but we know from experience that that fluctuates dramatically. Also, there is carbon offsetting, which is a voluntary scheme that at the moment is completely unregulated, which certainly should be regulated as soon as possible because at the moment it is pretty free and footloose out there with the internet and people setting up companies to try and charge money for carbon emissions on flights. I would certainly agree that tax or offset payments should be directed towards the developing countries or regions to which travellers are going, but I would have to contest a couple of the remarks by my colleague here, particularly on the impacts on GDP, not just the fact that those figures are probably too small, but also the benefits derived from tourism to communities and the economy of developing countries and regions such as the Caribbean are far, far wider than just figures on a Gross Domestic Product scale. The livelihoods of the communities in, for example, the Caribbean region are highly dependent on tourism, including secondary sectors, and the economies of those nations as well as other developing countries would be severely affected by a drop in travel to those destinations. Having said that, as you said Mr Bruce at the beginning it is very vague as to what the price would have to be as a tax to actually restrict either people's ability or inclination to travel. Work that we carried out at Oxford and with other colleagues last year at the time of the extremely high oil prices indicated that basically there would be little or no effect on travel to long haul destinations by an increase of, say, £60 on a flight per person. I would like to make that point as well. The complexities involved in the tourism and travel distribution chain are perhaps one of the key issues here, and the reason I raise that is because an aviation tax on its own to try to deliver adaptation finance or the ability for developing countries to mitigate their carbon emissions is not going to be sufficient on its own to address the problems and complexities of climate change in those countries. Tourism is, as I said, a complex distribution chain and interventions would need to be made at every stage of that chain, including on the ground and in hotels, prior to travel and also activities that are conducted by travellers when they are there in the destinations as well.

  Q86  Chairman: Can I just ask the other witnesses about Copenhagen? It seems to me that there are proposals coming from the developed countries and proposals coming from the developing countries; which one is more likely to gain ground; is anything likely to be agreed particularly on aviation? What is the prospect, for example, of a levy, taking your point that probably it would not actually have much effect on travel but would raise some income to be applied specifically to developing countries? Do any of the other witnesses want to comment on that?

  Ms Cooper: I do not necessarily have a comment on the cost of the levy, but to support my colleague here in some of the comments that he has made in terms of the dependence of a lot of communities, particularly Caribbean communities—and I come from the Caribbean—on tourism. The impact of a reduction in long haul flights would be extremely damaging, looking again at the many levels of the economy that are dependent on tourism. One of the things I can say is that if the cost of that levy was put towards assistance to adaptation, to changes, certainly some of the policies would suggest that there needs to be a lot more emphasis placed on incentives and concessions for small and medium enterprises within destinations so that they can take better advantage of the tourism industry—because at the moment a lot of the concessions and incentives are focused on large and multinational businesses—and so that they can have more of the linkages that are needed to ensure that other sectors of the economy can benefit from tourism. At the moment very few of those concessions and incentives are applied locally and nationally within the economy so I think a levy that would help those kinds of adaptations as well, so that they can get more impact from tourism, would be very important. At the moment we are already seeing a real impact on the economy because of the economic climate. There has been a huge loss of jobs and those may translate into very small GDP figures but actually the impact nationally is extremely significant in terms of loss of jobs. There are very few other comparative economies and small countries have very little opportunity to compete otherwise within the global economy.

  Dr Simpson: If I might jump back to the aviation tax, you were asking about the likelihood and I can see you would like an answer to that question. Probably the short answer is that it is unlikely and if any aviation tax was applied it would have to be structured very, very quickly to make sure that the benefits are derived by the developing countries because the last thing that would be most beneficial to the communities and to the global warming situation is for funds to simply go into government coffers. There is a proposal that is in process at the moment with the Inter-American Development Bank from our partners, the Caribbean Community Climate Change Centre—Oxford University is working with the five Cs on projects in the Caribbean—that we would try to establish some carbon neutral destinations which would involve a trust being set up, and the World Bank and the Inter-American Development Bank and probably the Caribbean Development Bank would be administering that trust. It is not in place at the moment and the project is not yet funded, although we are anticipating that it will be, but that would be a framework within which to operate such a tax.

  Q87  Chairman: Thank you, that is helpful. Mr Mitchell.

  Mr Mitchell: If I could just make a few comments. One would be the caveat that I have not read the report—I will read it and we would be quite happy to make a submission on that. My other comments would be that I agree with you, I think the GDP impacts for highly tourist-dependent poor countries are likely to be higher than the figures I have heard. As I say, I have not looked at the analysis but I will do so before confirming that. The work that we do in ODI is basically in the low-income, long haul tourist destinations that Victoria was speaking of, and my feeling is that they would be very seriously impacted if a tax was implemented on long haul flights that was sufficient to reduce or indeed halt the increase in demand. If I could just paint the scenario as an economist: in the destinations we are talking about often the contribution of tourism to the economy is between 10 and 20% of the economy. Quite often the contribution of tourism to exports is between a quarter and a third of the exports, so these are very significant economic sectors within the kinds of countries that we have been talking about. The work that we have been doing at ODI though is not to just focus on the macroeconomic figures from an office in London—we have gone out and we have traced the tourism dollar. We have now done that in about 10 countries across South East Asia and Africa. What we find is that the official statistics do not tell you the whole story, exactly as a number of my colleagues have related, because what the official statistics tell you is what the spending is in hotels, the transport sector and in restaurants. What they do not count are people in the craft sector, they do not count the thousands of very poor people working in the agricultural sector and they also do not tell you about the spending of tourist workers through induced impacts elsewhere in the economy. What we have found is that actually the benefits of tourism to fragile, poor economies vary but they are nearly always very much larger than the official statistics will tell you, if you roll your sleeves up, actually go into a destination and look where the money is spread around. Generally between the low level of about 10% and the higher level of about a quarter of in-country spending is going to the very poor, so the stereotype that tourism only benefits the elite within countries—they do benefit disproportionately but the idea that the benefits do not trickle down to the poor fortunately is only the case in a small number of countries such as Cambodia, where there are very poor linkages between tourism and the local community. The benefits, particularly for the poor, are much larger than the official figures would suggest. The very short paper that we wrote on leakages has also been circulated to the Committee and there we found some of the more hysterical figures that actually have remarkable impact in the literature, such as that 75% of the benefits of tourism leak out of developing countries, generally are wrong; the arithmetic is just wrong and the paper explains why. I am quite happy to go into that if you are interested. Generally the leakages at the very worst from developing countries are about a third. If you have a country like Cape Verde, which is essentially the tourist destination of sandy islands in the middle of the Atlantic Ocean, they import almost everything and the leakages are about one-third of the in-country tourism spending, much lower than the figures of half or 75% which, unfortunately, are bouncing around in the literature. The way I would look at the analysis is to go beyond the official figures and I would certainly question leakage figures if they were higher than that because that is the worst case scenario that we found. In, frankly, weak economies—we are doing a lot of work in Ethiopia at the moment—the leakage rate there is actually miniscule; it is extraordinary that in countries like Tanzania and Ethiopia, some of the poorest countries in the world—

  Chairman: Can I bring Richard Burden in here because I think you are moving into an area that he has questions touching on so it might be appropriate to bring him in at this moment.

  Q88  Richard Burden: You may have been moving on to it generally, not simply in relation to leakage, but a lot of the discussion so far seems to be about what the impact may be in the event of levies, taxes and so on. I suppose I would just like to explore a bit more things from the other way round, about what contribution tourism does make to developing countries as far as trying to look at the potential of tourism for poverty reduction is concerned, what the benefits are but, perhaps more particularly, how they could be increased. What are the areas that we do need to be looking at?

  Mr Mitchell: That is exactly the area that we have been focusing on. Our interest is to reduce poverty in developing countries—we are not actually interested in tourism per se, it is how it can be used as a tool for achieving that, so where it does not work, like Cambodia, we say so. The reason, just to give you an example: Cambodia and Vietnam are neighbours—about 7% of the money spent in Cambodia goes to poor people but in Vietnam, next door, about 25% of tourist spending in the country goes to poor people, so why the difference. There is a whole range of issues, but at the higher level the regulatory and enabling environment are extremely important. Quite often when you are dealing with tourism as a private sector-led activity people forget the importance of actually having an educated population that can mobilise the opportunities offered by tourism, of having infrastructure which allows tourists to get into the poorer areas. For instance, in Cambodia, where there is an extremely high level of corruption, a lot of the benefits of tourism are sifted off by a very markedly small number of people within the elite rather than being spread around the population, but what we have found is that the indirect linkages between tourism and the non-tourist economy are where the majority of the poverty reduction takes place. Within tourism, working in hotels and restaurants, poor people do disproportionately get jobs in those sectors because they are unskilled or semi-skilled, so you do have a bit of poverty reduction there, but where it really works is ethnic minority women selling silk goods in the highland areas of Vietnam, for instance, or in Laos. There are 1500 fishermen in Lake Chamo in Ethiopia and the majority of the tilapia and Nile perch that they catch are being sold at two or three large hotels in Addis Ababa. It is those indirect linkages, therefore, where you can get tourist spending to move out of the tourist sector and into the agricultural and craft sectors for instance that are important. They can have a dramatic influence but again it does not count for much on the national accounts because these people are earning, perhaps, one or two dollars a day, so you can have thousands of people earning that amount of money and it hardly registers, but it has a colossal impact in terms of people and the socio-economic impact.

  Dr Simpson: Work by the Department for International Development and other agencies is important to highlight the knock-on positive effects that Jonathan has just described there to raise awareness of travellers from developed countries like the UK as to how benefits can best be derived, to make choices to travel to destinations, stay in hotels and conduct activities that are going to have a positive effect on the secondary industries and on the livelihoods of individuals who are involved in providing things like fish and foodstuffs to hotels that they are staying at. At the same time, as Jonathan says, it is also important to strengthen the regulatory frameworks within individual countries so that that process is enabled. Things like micro-finance, where we have seen good examples in India and other countries where poor people, people living on below $2 a day, are able to access finance to start very small businesses to be able to provide services to hotels and activities that are being used by tourists. I would just re-emphasise that factor of benefits going to the poor through livelihood activities such as money from tourism encouraging the development of communications, the installation of fresh water supplies, roads, increased food security, all of these are very hard to measure and it is important to be able to go down into rural communities and establish what is happening there, how it has happened and what sort of strategies can be employed to encourage it. It is not a perfect world, certainly research that we have conducted and colleagues of mine have conducted shows that often it is the case that a small minority of a real community are the people who benefit, not the vast community, and that can be a problem, but the point is that there are benefits to be achieved and we need strategies to try and maximise those benefits as much as possible.

  Ms Cooper: If I can add, it is important to remember as well that often the fishermen and the women craft-makers and so forth are eking an existence out of what is already there and those regulatory frameworks are extremely important for strengthening those linkages. At the moment they are making an existence and living from what is there without those kinds of policies that strengthen the linkages that they can have so there is not an exclusive but an agreed system where they can sell their craft products to particular locations, within the hotels, that can then be used within a local network. Often there is an emphasis placed on creating tours with tour guides and so forth, but often that does only benefit a small number of people within a community and there needs to be a lot more creative analysis as to how those benefits can be spread and how to spread those linkages. If I can also say, the whole policy development process needs to be looked at in a much more holistic way. For many countries tourism affects the entire national development but the decision-making about how tourism is developed is done in isolation of national development planning, and so many people in small and medium enterprises, in poor and marginalised communities, benefit from tourism but do not have an opportunity to participate in how those policy development processes take place. There needs to be a broadening of how many people can be involved in those development processes. Often cultural products as well which have a benefit for the national and local society can add value to tourism products and have a certain amount of resilience in times of economic decline, and those need to be developed a lot more. I just wanted to broaden it a little bit more, not just from looking at the destination at a local level but looking at the global value chain for tourism, and you can see often where the linkages happen in the global value chain, so there is the commission that is taken from the tour operator which then puts pressure on the price and often the wages at the destination. You then have situations often where tour operators have late payment for operators in the local destinations and often cancellation of those fees, so that those fees do not get paid in destination countries. There is a real vertical integration by the large-scale tour operators and they often compete with in-bound operators who are based locally, so there are all of these levels within the global value chain where money is lost and where the local destination does not often benefit from it. New enterprises that develop, even if they are new attractions or events or crafts and so forth that are developed, they need to kind of break into that market, which is often structurally determined and they find it difficult to then get themselves on the tourist route. There needs to be support for that as well so that new enterprises can be encouraged and benefits derived from that. One other thing to add as well is that a lot of foreign exchanges losses that you see are also absorbed within the destination and not by the tour operators and the big tour companies based here, so all of those things within that value chain also need to be assessed as to where those losses can be minimised.

  Q89  Richard Burden: One last question from me: is it possible or helpful to generalise about whether high end tourism or mass market tourism is going to actually be generally better from a development viewpoint? You have placed a lot of emphasis on the regulatory system in the countries concerned, on how far there is activism in developing linkages and the right kind of promotion to tourists from abroad about what kind of tourism is better from a development point of view. Is that really it or in general terms is high end tourism likely to be easier to develop than the lower end or mass market or is it just irrelevant and it could be either?

  Dr Simpson: There is not conclusive research to say that high end is better or mass is better for benefits to poor people. Very quickly, mass tourism is of course looked down on by a lot of researchers as perhaps detrimental to a destination, but in fact if the frameworks are in place for the provision of, for example, foodstuffs by local people to those all-inclusive hotels, it may well be that an all-inclusive hotel is much better for the local community or the regional community in the developing country than a small boutique, high end tourist facility which is supposedly more eco-friendly. I am using very broad, generalised terms here but it is very important to be careful not to generalise about mass tourism being bad and the supposedly small eco-tourism good; it is not as simple as that.

  Mr Mitchell: If I could just add very briefly on a more uplifting level perhaps, what we found is exactly what Murray is saying, there is not a good type of tourism and a bad type of tourism if your concern is poverty alleviation in destination. Package tourism is not bad, it can be very good, and independent tourism can be very bad. We have also found that there is no segment of tourism that is either good or bad. We have got excellent examples of cultural tourism that has a huge positive impact on the poor, but in other places not at all—there is game-viewing that is great in, for instance, Tanzania and not very good in Central Africa in terms of gorilla tourism as relates to benefits to the poor. I think those kind of easy handles where this is the good type of tourism do not actually hold up to empirical analysis, and that is a good thing because countries do not then tend to choose the type of tourism that they have, it tends to be given by God or a bit of clever marketing. The implications of what I am saying are that any country, whatever type of tourism it has, can make it more pro-poor through the kinds of measures that I and my colleagues have mentioned, which is a positive message.

  Dr Simpson: If I might just add to that it is useful to think more about sustainable tourism being the way all tourism should be and try to put aside ideas of eco-tourism—which is a very misused term anyway—and/or mass tourism. But if you look at issues of sustainability and sustainable development and try to apply those to all tourism then you are starting to go down the right path to delivering the benefits that we are talking about.

  Q90  Mr Singh: It has been a very interesting discussion so far but let us try and pin it down a little bit. What should the UK Government be doing; should it be encouraging long haul flights to developing countries or discouraging them?

  Ms Johnson: I agree with a lot of the points that my colleagues have been saying but I do still feel very concerned that some developing countries are specialising in a market which is extremely vulnerable to exogenous shocks from oil prices, to public health outbreaks or scares, to conflict, to climate policies as we are talking about today, to changing consumer tastes, recession and so on. I do think that is something that we ought to bear in mind but I do not think encouraging long haul flights is anything that I could possibly support. Bearing in mind again, as I mentioned earlier, that in terms of aviation the distribution between flights is very skewed towards short haul, that is something that I would encourage the Government to discourage by using the right financial instrument. Linked to the issue of vulnerability also is something I did not mention, that is vulnerability to geophysical events or extreme weather events which have the potential to have huge impacts on tourism destinations. Parallel to that are the changing global climate conditions, and if you link all those up together that to me does not seem like a sensible strategy. I would add also that in our report we made some reference to the bilateral trade agreements that the EU has made with a number of countries and one particular case that we made reference to is Mexico where regulations have effectively made it illegal for Mexico to regulate its own industry. The UK Government and other European governments have actually supported those bilateral trade agreements and I would say that one thing would be to address that immediately as a means of improving and also allowing some of the more pro-poor tourism strategies to develop.

  Dr Simpson: It is too complex to answer that question so simply. As I mentioned right at the very beginning the tourism supply chain is so complex interventions are required at every level regarding addressing climate change and, in particular, very briefly going back to Richard Burden's point about working in countries, DFID needs to be looking at the impacts of climate change on the livelihoods of the people in developing countries that are involved in tourism at every different sector that is linked with tourism. In many countries that are dependent on tourism to a great degree every sector is linked, so there is an inherent need to look at that on a macro level but also going into micro sectors. I suppose in summary, to try to answer your question if I can, again based on work that I and colleagues conducted last year, the general emphasis—in some ways supporting what Victoria is saying—is that less frequent travel over short distances is important. So if I can simplify that perhaps by saying if somebody is going on holiday six times a year for three days then it would be much better if they went on holiday three times a year for five days each, so less frequent travel over short distances and, by definition, you could extrapolate that to say longer holidays over longer distances. If we are trying to marry the complex problem of delivering benefits to developing countries which are by their nature long haul, then I suppose if pushed you would have to come down on the side of saying that it is better that somebody travels to developing countries for two or three weeks once in a year than travels five times to the south of Spain in that year because overall the damage to the planet will be less and the benefits to poverty reduction will be greater.

  Q91  Mr Singh: Trying to bring it to a very local level, I have a constituency where the ethnic minority population is largely made up of Kashmiris from Kashmir and Pakistan. They travel not as tourists but as family visitors, to keep family links. They also have an impact on the economy they travel to, a huge impact; if there was a carbon tax which the consumer was paying—and these constituents of mine are not advantaged, they are disadvantaged—would this not be an unfair tax on the poor people in society and would it not discourage the economic impact that they have?

  Dr Simpson: Absolutely. I have just one sentence on that and again it comes back to something we mentioned at the beginning of the session, which is that an increase in the cost of travel will not have a great impact on arrivals except on people of a medium to low income, you are absolutely right. If anything, therefore, you are actually affecting the human rights and freedom of movement of the people who actually should be able to do that, yes.

  Mr Mitchell: Your point is an important one because there are lots of stereotypes in tourism about what a tourist is and quite often they are not who they are meant to be by the stereotypes. What we find generally is that diaspora tourism is hugely important in South Asia; in Cape Verde it is driving the whole economy, it is not just visiting friends and relations. Very often we find that when tourism begins to develop the economy, people actually go home, they can actually go home, and we have seen that in Cape Verde and in Ethiopia. A lot of the tourism investors are people that know the international market and so they are well-placed to open hotels; the same in Vietnam actually, so it is much more significant than going back to see mum once a year, sometimes it allows people actually to create a vibrant economy that allows them to make the choice to go back, maybe at retirement but increasingly at working age. Could I go back to your first question very briefly? There are several levels at which the British Government could think about intervening. One is a point that has been made very well already which is to make sure with the existing tourist flows that the maximum benefit is extracted for the destination countries, and there we are talking about things that actually fit in very well with DFID's development agenda about improving the business environment, empowering women and reducing crime. These are the things that stimulate linkages and stimulate development, so that is one level. Also there is a real window of opportunity with the private sector and we in a sense are blessed in Britain in that we have some of the largest and most powerful international tour operators. If you go along the panel we will all have different views on them, but it is a real asset because an incremental change in their business practice has a tremendous influence on the destinations and what you have at the moment with a couple of the very large tour operators is, probably for the first time, some very responsible practice coming in at board level within those organisations—for instance, with the travel life programmes they are rolling out for the hotels that they are working with in terms of both environmental and socio-economic improvements. I have seen it at destination level and it has a huge impact; if the British Government could work with that through UK companies that would be tremendously important. Finally, tourists are people so I would make sure that you prosecute sex tourists when they come back to Britain; I would help educate tourists that actually out-of-pocket expenditure is very important and that that is what benefits poor people. I would deal with the big stuff up here, therefore, but also at a very individual level as to how people should behave.

  Q92  Mr Singh: Why do we need to have this discussion about poor countries, developing countries, least developed countries given that their carbon footprint is so small? Why can we not just exempt them from taxes, levies, offsetting?

  Mr Mitchell: There are people much better qualified to answer but if I could make one very brief comment on this.

  Q93  Chairman: You are all going to have to be brief because it is a very interesting discussion but we have still got quite a lot of questions and we are going to run out of time. I do not want to constrain anybody, but could people be brief.

  Mr Mitchell: Very briefly, I share your bewilderment, to be quite honest. I understand the Committee is going to go to East Africa and, having spoken to our Climate Change Group, you will each generate under two tonnes of carbon which, at the current shadow price of carbon, will be £45. That will be the UK Government's view of the total cost to the environment of your trip. The benefit to East Africa of you being there, as business tourists in this case, will be 20 or 30 times that. Development is about trade-offs and it amazes me that we obsess about the £45 worth of damage and we fail to see the hundreds of pounds of benefit to the developing countries. I share your bewilderment.

  Ms Cooper: To be really brief, we need to look at this in the context of the fact that, for myself, coming from the Caribbean, this is after having had the removal of a preferential market for bananas, the loss of commodity prices for bananas as well as sugar, and so this is the only economic avenue that many countries have, and so now many people within the region see it really as a slap in the face. I agree that it is a real frustration.

  Dr Simpson: It is very hard to define where you are going to draw the line.

  Q94  Mr Singh: DFID has definitions of developing countries.

  Dr Simpson: Of developing countries, yes, but most of the Caribbean does not fall into that category so what you will do, for example, is that you will actually discriminate against the Caribbean. By applying such a line using the 32 Least Developed Countries you will actually create more of a problem in the Caribbean because they will be suffering to a greater extent because they are more dependent on tourism than perhaps one of those less developed countries.

  Q95  Mr Singh: You could refine the criteria.

  Dr Simpson: It would be pretty hard to do it in three minutes, but let us say, for example, one way of addressing it is to have a higher rate on short haul so we have a blanket tax, if that is the way the Government decides to go, with a higher rate on short haul, so then what you are doing is saying it is an even playing field apart from the areas that we do know are creating more emissions because of the frequency of travel to those short haul destinations.

  Q96  Chairman: With the proviso that short haul is quite often essential if you are talking about islands.

  Dr Simpson: That is right, and trying to encourage the trains to work better and things like that I suppose.

  Q97  Andrew Stunell: It has been a fascinating discussion with lots of stuff about linkages and leakages. The first is good and the second is bad and quite a lot of the figures that you have been talking about are clearly in dispute. We have had over the last decade a lot of discussion about fair trade products; how do we get fair trade tourism so that those leakages are actually much more positive linkages?

  Dr Simpson: There was a project which was launched two or three years ago on fair trade tourism by the fair trade organisation and my understanding, but I stand to be corrected, is that the project was not completed. It certainly has not been implemented widely enough if it was completed and I agree it should be done. I know Tourism Concern were involved in that; perhaps you can shed some light on what happened.

  Ms Cooper: Yes, I can say it is something that Tourism Concern has been working on for about 10 years and trying to really decide what are the principles of fair trade tourism. We had a project which we tried to get some funding for last year, which unfortunately did not go through, which would have worked in partnership with many of the fair trade movement key players. The trouble with fair trade is that at the moment it has been applied to products and it is much more of a complex picture in terms of putting a fair trade stamp on a service, so which bit of that global value chain do you look at as being fair trade, where do you put the stamp on it? Is it the product, is it the tour operator that is selling the product, is it both of them? It is a much more complex analysis that needs to be taking place but we do feel that not only is it certainly very much needed but it is something that can be done, so it would need to have a real analysis as to where that links with the commitment of all of the different people within that value chain who can look at it. Certainly the key principles of a fair trade tourism product would be ensuring that the workers within the tourism sector are organised and able to influence decision-making policies, that they have very good linkages within communities that ensure that inputs and services are provided by the local community, that the tour operator who is selling the product also has fair trade principles and markets it in a way that ensures that people understand what we are trying to achieve by fair trade tourism. Certainly now is the time—in the sense that the movement has really grown, particularly in the UK which has the greatest amount of fair trade customers or purchasers—to try and talk about what would be a fair trade tourism product.

  Dr Simpson: There is a plethora of certification for tourism out there already. That is one of the problems, to be honest: there are so many certificates. We have got to the point now where the United Nations have even got together to provide a certificate for the certifications. Whilst there may be some merit in that, it is a pretty bizarre position to be in. As I have mentioned before, the principles of sustainable development are what need to be applied to tourism. There are examples that can be used, but it is very complex because of the complexity of the distribution chain.

  Q98  Andrew Stunell: I wish we had longer to explore this. You have defined leakages as bad things and linkages as good things. There has been an interesting contribution from Mr Mitchell about possibly tour operators developing their corporate social responsibility to be more effective. That is what has happened with Fairtrade goods, the voluntary movement has begun to influence the commercial sector. Do you see scope for that happening? Are there ways in which that can be supported by what the Government does, either by taxation or regulation or in some other way?

  Dr Simpson: Perhaps I could give you a practical example. In the Caribbean there is the Sustainable Tourism Zone of the Caribbean, a project which has been instigated by the Association of Caribbean States, which is an organisation that works at ministerial level across the whole of the Caribbean Basin—so 32 members, which includes the Central American states as well. They have established, with the assistance of my colleagues and I, a set of indicators for sustainable tourism which can be applied to address all of the different complexities. It is not perfect, but it is designed to do exactly what you have just said: to drive the demand for destinations under membership of the Sustainable Tourism Zone of the Caribbean. It works in the same way as Fairtrade, but more investment is required, more members are required, and so on and so forth.

  Mr Mitchell: I think there is a great opportunity here, because you have the corporate sector, in my view—I think there are different views, but this is my view—tackling this seriously for the first time. The thing about tourist corporates is that they do not know much about development. They know a lot about flying people around and running airfields, but they desperately need an official development of support for what they are doing. They are charging their own customers a levy, they are creating quite a lot of money through organisations like the Travel Foundation, and, to be frank, they need support from development practitioners and some official recognition of what they are doing so that those funds can be used more effectively. I think there is a real opportunity for the private sector, which sees its responsibility and is raising money, and the UK Government, which has in DFID a lot of development expertise and can recognise the efforts that are being made by the private sector. Finally, I do not think leakages are always bad. There is a leakage in Laos, where most of the rice is brought from Thailand. It is poor rice farmers producing that, so it is a loss to the economy of Laos but in terms of poverty I would not distinguish between a poor Laotian farmer and a poor rice farmer in Thailand. In terms of poverty, it is fine. Being able to distribute the benefits of tourist spending over a wider geographical area, so it is not focused just on destination, is a positive thing.

  Q99  Andrew Stunell: Would you pick out one single thing that DFID could do to help that process forward that you have been describing?

  Mr Mitchell: At the moment DFID has an interesting position because it invented a lot of the stuff we have been talking about today. In 1999 DFID funded a lot of the work that fed into the UN conference at that time that developed pro-poor tourism as an idea. It supported it for a couple of years after that and has now back-pedalled from it, to the point where there is quite a strong position that they will not support tourism.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2009
Prepared 3 June 2009