Bank of England August 2009 Inflation Report - Treasury Contents


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 20-39)

MR MERVYN KING, MR CHARLIE BEAN, MR SPENCER DALE, MS KATE BARKER AND PROFESSOR DAVID MILES

15 SEPTEMBER 2009

  Q20  Chairman: So there was a slow start then?

  Ms Barker: To some extent; but if you said to me, "Did it make any difference to the meetings?" No. Around the meetings I always had the information that was wanted when it felt appropriate to ask the questions. I did not feel it appropriate to ask people a lot of questions when they were in the middle of dealing with what was, after all, a pretty intense financial crisis.

  Q21  Mr Fallon: Charlie Bean, let us look at quantitative easing. You have purchased, by my calculation, around £143 billion worth of gilts and during that period the Government has issued, through the Debt Management Office, about £95 billion of gilts in the same period. How can we be sure that all this money is not actually going round in circles without touching the sides of the real economy and affecting final demand?

  Mr Bean: Ultimately it takes time for quantitative easing to work; I think that is one point I would really like to stress. The mechanisms whereby quantitative easing work through into nominal spending are varied. Essentially what happens, when we buy gilts from the private sector that means that people in the private sector now have monetary deposits that they can do something with; typically they will go and buy other assets. The effect is to drive up the prices of those assets, so this will include corporate assets, equities, a whole range of things. That reduces the cost of capital to firms, the cost of borrowing for businesses, and ultimately that should feed through to nominal spending. But I would expect the lags here to be of the same order of magnitude, or possibly longer, than we see with respect to normal interest rate cuts. Obviously what we are doing at the Bank is monitoring things as they unfold. We are moderately encouraged by, if you like, the near-term indicators in the transmission chain that it is having an effect. Some channels are perhaps not working particularly strongly. There is quite a lot of attention that has been paid to the fact that the counterpart to our purchases, the increase in central bank money, appears to be being hoarded by the banks. That is pretty much what we expected on the basis of Japanese experience. In our assessment of how much we needed to do, we assumed that that pretty much would happen. But it may well be that at some stage the banks may well start using the extra reserves they hold to go out and buy other assets, and that would add an extra kick to the process that is already working.

  Q22  Mr Fallon: David Miles, if we cannot be absolutely sure of the current impact of quantitative easing on final demand, how can we be sure we need more of it?

  Professor Miles: I think the honest answer is that one cannot be sure, but one has to make a judgment on what is most likely to be the right quantity. My own judgment in the August meeting was that, given the downside risks to demand and output in the UK, given the amount of spare capacity, then in order to keep inflation on average, on balance, near to the target, it was probably warranted to carry on buying assets at the same pace—on the same trajectory as we had before. But there is an awful amount of uncertainty about whether that is exactly the right strategy or not. I think it is important though that any decision that you make is not a final irrevocable decision. One can revisit the decision; and obviously there will be a period some way down the line at which the process will be reversed.

  Q23  Mr Fallon: Governor, what are the milestones that you want to see in place before you should start to reverse the process, and start selling assets and raising rates again?

  Mr King: Finally it is the judgment on the inflation outlook; that is the cornerstone of our framework and it is the criterion by which we make our judgments; it was the criterion which I used when deciding to vote for the level of asset purchases I voted for in August. I think that many things go into that, but one of them is that we felt that the benefit of asset purchases would be that it would help to offset what would otherwise have been a very sharp monetary squeeze with the growth rate of the supply of broad money falling rapidly. We did manage to offset some of that, I think; so I feel that my judgment is (although one can never prove it because you cannot ever prove what the counterfactual would have been) that the growth rate of the supply of broad money would have fallen very sharply had we not engaged in our policy of buying £147 billion (it is now) of assets. I think it is very hard to believe that that scale of purchase has not actually fed through to broad money in one way or another. I think we are beginning now, after six months, to see some signs that perhaps the growth of broad money is picking up. I shall look at that, as well as what is happening to nominal spending, and put that together with all the other judgments we make about what is happening to demand and output and the supply potential of the economy to form a judgment about the outlook for inflation and the risks to that.

  Q24  Mr Fallon: Is there a level of supply of broad money that you are looking at looking to reach?

  Mr King: There is no indicator, because if there were that would mean that we would have a broad money target; but I think the growth rates of broad money that were consistent in the past 15 years with broadly steady growth and low inflation were in the 6-9% range. Now that is not a magic number, but I think I would be looking for a further pick up in the growth of broad money. That may well happen as a lagged response, as Charlie said, to the actions we have taken. These are the difficult judgments we have to make, as to whether what we have done already will come through to providing a stimulus to broad money and spending growth in the future, or whether in fact we need to do more. These are difficult judgments; they are not easy. To those people who are deeply concerned about the policy of asset purchases I would say to them, "Look, I understand why in an abstract sense you may be worried, but the mechanism by which that worry should appear would be if we started to see excessively rapid growth of money and spending in the economy and we are a long way from that at present; and if we did see signs of that we would rapidly take action in order to slow that down". I would hope that the framework and our clear intentions would give people comfort that we are a very long way away from being in a situation where this is going to create dramatically high inflation. We have got a symmetric inflation target of 2%. It is a symmetric target. When the judgment is (which is perhaps not very often) that we think the risk is that inflation will be below the target, then it is our duty to bring it back to the target; and that is what the policy of asset purchases is designed to achieve.

  Q25  Mr Fallon: Is not the framework complicated by the uncertainty on the fiscal side? Would not your task be easier if the markets were clearer about how the structural deficit is to be reduced, as well as when?

  Mr King: Yes, I think it is clear any monetary policy is going to face difficulties when there is a fiscal position such as the present one where, because of the shock to the financial sector, we have now got at present a very large deficit, which everyone accepts needs to come down. The timing of the measures needed to bring it down I think must depend on the state of the economy, but clearly we need a very credible overall plan to ensure that the public finances are put on a sound footing; and that is part and parcel of macroeconomic policy, for which we are not responsible. But a failure to have a fiscal framework which gives comfort to everyone, that the public finances will be on a sound footing, does make life more difficult and it can push up inflation expectations, and in that way require us to take action. I think everyone accepts that. I am pleased there is now a consensus on that issue. As I said, now we have a long hard road over the next few years to put every aspect of our framework, macroeconomic and regulatory, in the right place. It is important we do not do it all at once. We do need to phase this in as the economy recovers; but we have got to be very clear where we want to get to at the end of that period.

  Q26  Mr Fallon: You are still waiting for a credible fiscal plan?

  Mr King: I am sure there is plenty of time for that to be announced. I gather there is quite an active debate amongst those of you who are responsible for it in Parliament about what fiscal policy will look like, and I look forward to seeing the outcome of that.

  Mr Fallon: So do I!

  Q27  Mr Todd: Could I just briefly turn back to the article by Danny Blanchflower. I think you are right in not engaging in a debate, but there was one process issue which struck me when he referred to a criticism that he made of one of the decisions; there is a reference to you calling him in to "admonish" him. That would not seem to me an appropriate relationship between the Chair of the MPC and an independent member. I assume that is one of the inaccuracies you were thinking of?

  Mr King: He participated in the discussions on the August Inflation Report and signed up to the Report; and I think I was asked by other members of the Committee to explain that it did not seem very sensible, having agreed privately and gone along with a view that was discussed and signed up to the process, then publicly to dissent from it. I think it was reasonable for me to point out that this was a view which other members of the Committee had been upset by—by his speaking out in public and describing a Report which he had signed up to as "wishful thinking". It was not wise behaviour; I was asked to make that clear to him by other members of the Committee; and as Chairman I think it is reasonable to do that.

  Q28  Mr Todd: But there is a balance to be struck, is there not, between the role of members of the MPC to make public—

  Mr King: Absolutely. I think at every point, as he says in his article, that the discussions we had were always polite and good mannered, even where people had different views about the state of the economy—

  Q29  Mr Todd: I appreciate that.

  Mr King: —and people have never been shy of speaking out—that is one thing you could not say about the Monetary Policy Committee!

  Q30  Mr Todd: I am making a slightly different point. There is a balance between the concept of collective responsibility which one has some obligation to if you take part in any decision-making process, and the freedom to comment?

  Mr King: And that is particularly true of the Inflation Report which is a collective document.

  Q31  Mr Todd: Yes, but also there is a responsibility to members of the public outside to hear the broader views?

  Mr King: Absolutely, and that has always been made quite clear to the members of the Committee.

  Q32  Mr Todd: Are there some tools that could be used to accelerate the effects of quantitative easing through to the real economy? All of you have actually commented on the lags that are inevitably there. It has been certainly pointed out that one of the effects has been a very substantial increase in reserves help with the Bank of England by banks. Are there tools that you could use to accelerate the use of resources that have been pumped in for the purposes that they are intended for?

  Mr King: I think the big picture is that we have engaged in asset purchases: that does feed through directly to broad money held by the non-banking sector; and in various ways that will feed through into the transmission mechanism of higher nominal spending, and ultimately higher inflation to bring inflation closer to the 2% target. It is always tempting to try and speed up the transmission mechanism of policy actions that we take; and of course the same is true of interest rate changes, where again there is a lot of uncertainty surrounding interest rate changes. I think it is very important not to see asset purchases as in some sense completely different from the normal way we set policy. We describe the action we take in terms of Bank Rate normally, but the transmission mechanism through to the economy is very much the same transmission mechanism as follows from asset purchases. In terms of the reserves of the banking system, I think the most important thing to remember is that as we engage in asset purchases that automatically will increase the reserves of the banking system and you cannot stop that and you would not want to: the whole point is that asset purchases are going to have the impact of raising reserves of the banking system. What is true is that we do not want reserves to be unnecessarily high; and we have withdrawn other ways of injecting reserves that we would normally engage in through out short-term repo operations in the market in order to bring down the level of reserves. But I think there is a limit to how far we can go because of the scale of asset purchases; but we have reduced the other actions that were boosting reserves. Of course, people have talked about, and I was asked a question at the August Inflation Report press conference, whether it would be sensible to reduce the rate at which those reserves are remunerated, and it is something we are looking at, and we will reflect on it.

  Q33  Mr Todd: Or have a differential rate applied to those above a certain level?

  Mr King: Yes, exactly. I think you certainly would not want to reduce the rate of remuneration on a certain level of reserves—that is part of the framework; but above some normal level you could have a lower rate at which they are remunerated. But that would not change the overall level of reserves in the banking sector; that is determined by our asset purchases. What it would do is perhaps make the banks work a little bit harder to try individually to convert some of those reserves into other assets. If you reduced a bit the rate at which you remunerate reserves that will not convert it into lending to businesses, but it might mean that they would purchase more short-term gilts, for example, which would be adding to the effective size of the asset purchase scheme and so boost money growth a bit further; and that is something we will reflect on. But I do not think you should see this as a major change, a major instrument. In Sweden, for example, it has a tiny effect because they do draining of their reserves daily so that the scale of reserves on which the lower rate is charged is actually extremely small. This may be a useful supplement; we will think about it but it is not going to be a major change.

  Q34  Mr Todd: Part of the difficulty is that the speed with which quantitative easing has its effects depends on decision-making within institutions, with which the public do not have a huge amount of confidence at the moment. Therefore, the mechanisms you have described can be characterised in other ways, as banks quite deliberately rebuilding their balance sheets, holding in reserve resources that should be distributed back into the economy to generate growth. Does it trouble you that the fairly academic response that we have had—which has been to say "This is how it works. There are a variety of lags here, if you wait long enough it'll happen"—does not necessarily satisfy the person outside?

  Mr King: No, I can see that but I think the answer is I do not think this is so much a question of timing as of magnitude. One of the reasons we have engaged in the scale of asset purchases we have is the recognition that because of the state the banking sector is in, some of the increase in money that we have created has been used to pay down bank debt. In the long run that is also part of the recuperation process of banks, so that in a sense is also helping the economy but over a longer time period; but in the shorter run that would affect the judgment about the scale of asset purchasing.

  Q35  Mr Todd: Can I turn to the empirical data as to how quickly this is flowing through. What are your agents telling you about the difficulties firms have in borrowing money at the moment? Which categories of companies are struggling; or indeed you may be hearing that those with good plans are finding no difficulty in raising money at all?

  Mr King: No, I would not agree with the latter. I will make one broad comment and then perhaps ask Spencer Dale to comment because it is his area that produces the credit conditions survey. I think the big picture is the good news (and I think it is not entirely unrelated to some of the activities that we have engaged in through our asset purchases) is that the conditions for big companies to raise equity finance and bond finance have improved significantly. There is quite a significant amount of finance being raised in that form. Of course, that does not really help the small and medium-sized companies, and they are still finding difficulties.

  Mr Dale: I think that is exactly right. The message we get from our agents, and it is also the message one can see from reading the business surveys, is that some of the larger companies are finding less difficulty accessing funds. As their ability to go to capital markets improves, so the competitiveness within the bank lending market is also improving. Where there are more difficulties is for the smaller and medium-sized companies, where we hear from the agents and we can see from the business surveys the difficulty of obtaining funds is still a pressing concern

  Q36  Mr Todd: What should be done to ease that? Are there any differences in the sorts of activity of businesses? For example, you mentioned small, but start-ups may have particular problems. What evidence is there of that? What measures would seem reasonable to improve that situation?

  Mr Dale: The focus of our asset purchases is to try to increase, as the Governor said, the flow of money in the economy and improve the functioning of corporate credit markets. I think, as the Governor was saying, one sees quite a degree of success in terms of what is happening to corporate bond markets—where corporate bond spreads have declined very dramatically—and corporate bond issuance is at record levels. Large companies are going out to access that. It is very difficult for us with a single instrument to try to start directing funds to particular sectors of the economy—be it particular sectors or small companies versus large companies.

  Q37  Mr Todd: I did not suggest the Bank should do that. I think I said what measures should be taken?

  Mr Dale: One would have to try and think about alternative measures which could try and encourage banks to direct their resources to small and medium-size companies. As you are well aware, there are some policies in place whose aim is trying to do that; but, as I said, from both our agents and from the business surveys, there seems to be further to go.

  Professor Miles: I think it is important to see that the effect of quantitative easing is not completely dependent on what the banks do. One of the reasons I view it as the right policy and an effective tool is that it can help credit conditions in the economy, even if the banks simply see reserves accumulate there and do not take second-round actions. One of the mechanisms is that those who sell gilts to the Bank of England—pension funds and life insurance companies—would then naturally look to buy other assets that might be close substitutes for gilts. A close substitute for longer dated gilts may well be corporate bonds, rather than simply seeing the money accumulate in a bank deposit. I think it is no accident that during a period when the Bank has been purchasing, on a very large scale, gilts, the issuance of corporate debt by non-financial companies has increased very sharply.

  Q38  Sir Peter Viggers: May I ask Spencer Dale to comment on the inflation projections which are shown on page 40 of the Inflation Report. The fan charts on page 40 show the comparative effect of quantitative easing of £125 and £175 billion, a difference of £50 billion. The central projection now sees inflation rise to target within a year. How much of that is due to the extra £50 billion, and how much via the change in the economic situation?

  Mr Dale: Comparing the two charts on page 40, there are a number of differences between Chart 5.4 and Chart 5.5, because they were taken at different points in time: one was from the May forecast and one was from the August forecast. In addition to the additional monetary stimulus underlying the August forecast, there is also a completely different set of other financial prices going on, and also differences in the economic judgment and the data which changed between May and August. You cannot read the differences between those fan charts purely in terms of representing the impact of the £50 billion. The more general question is clearly the decision to increase the scale of monetary purchases to raise the inflation projection, but the precise amount by which it did depended on all the other factors which were used to make up the economic forecast in August.

  Q39  Sir Peter Viggers: There has been seemingly limited impact on inflation further out than the charts project. Why is that?

  Mr Dale: In what ways "seemingly limited"? A number of factors were affecting the forecast for inflation further out between May and August. To one extent we had the additional monetary stimulus; and the other factor to bear in mind is that between May and August our view about the level of output in the past had been revised down quite substantially. We were starting our forecasts with a lower level of output and a greater degree of economic slack in August than we had thought was the case in May, and that acted to pull down on the inflation projection relative to that in May.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2009
Prepared 19 October 2009