[back to previous text]

Mr. Breed: I agree entirely with what the hon. Gentleman says. Is it not a matter not only of regulation, but of proportionate regulation? To encourage new entrants in, they ought not to be sometimes subjected to the sort of regulation that is required for a highly sophisticated, complex, huge operation. Proportionate regulation would recognises the relative size and allow entrants in at the bottom end in a much more reasonable way.
2.45 pm
Mr. Tyrie: I absolutely agree with that but, best of all, is competition. It will always act as a counterweight to excessive regulation. Competition should, in principle, provide us with the optimum level of regulation. If we have no regulation, we will have no industry to regulate. The size of the industry will be very small. People do not want to deal in a jungle. They will move into a market where they can receive some protection. However, too much protection can have the deleterious effect, as I have described, of killing off activity. In between lies the optimum level of regulation, normally the level that provides for the maximum level of legally conducted business activity. That is not the level at which we will get zero regulatory risk and we will therefore always have regulatory failure. It is the pressure that builds up on any regulator to clamp down excessively that is the great danger in regulation and financial services.
Mr. Love: Does the hon. Gentleman recognise any limitation on the role of competition, and an enhanced role for regulation? I take the example of home credit of which the Office of Fair Trading carried out a study. It wished to introduce greater competition into the marketplace, but found it difficult to find market participants who were willing to enter that market. Therefore, there is a continuing role for regulation—I agree with the hon. Gentleman, at an optimum level—but we cannot always depend on competition.
Mr. Tyrie: I completely agree with the hon. Gentleman that a level of regulation is required to arrive at an optimum level of business activity and benefit to the consumer. I hope that I just said that, but if I did not, I confirm it now. Home credit is a fascinating case of a market distortion. We have both looked into it. It is difficult to see an easy method of eliminating it wholly. However, I will not be drawn down that road into such a specific and detailed example now, even though it is deeply relevant to the new clause.
I want to make one more general point about the importance of competition in assisting consumers. I did an economics degree of sorts and, on a good day—quietly, usually in a Committee Room upstairs where no one notices—I might even be prepared to admit it. I did at least learn a lesson of Schumpeter, whose contribution was decisive on the issue. He showed that the greatest source of competition generally comes not directly from price, but from the invention of new products or product improvement that displaces inferior products in the market on a dynamic and constantly evolving basis. That is as true in services as it is in goods. It is what he called the process of creative destruction, and it is what we must maintain in financial services. We need more of it there, but our central difficulty is that there is a strong case for saying that that Schumpeterian power of creative destruction has been compromised in some respects by a distorted regulatory regime.
Mr. Breed: Does the hon. Gentleman consider the introduction of the innovative product of a 125 per cent. mortgage to be a good way of providing competition in the market?
Mr. Tyrie: The hon. Gentleman makes a very good point. If the consumer can be brought to understand clearly and transparently what he is really taking on, we must ultimately let the market decide the level of activity that will take place in that area. In the case of those mortgages, we know from survey evidence that people did not know what they were taking on. They were misinformed. That is the central weakness in what happened.
It is impossible to protect people entirely from mistakes that they themselves will make. However careful the preparation, there will always be people who do not take advantage of the information provided to them to make good decisions, just as there will be people who open a can of soup, pollute it with salmonella or something before they drink it, and then blame the producer of the soup.
I agree that producing 125 per cent. mortgages was highly irresponsible. They should have had powerful health warnings on them. There might have been a case for going further and curbing them—indeed, that is the road that we have gone down. There might have been a case for doing so much earlier than we did. However, we cannot live in a world where, every time a product is produced, we must rely on the FSA to put it through a detailed vetting system before it can be allowed on to the market as something that has been duly approved and sanitised. Such products are not like new pharmaceuticals. The level of innovation takes place at a much faster speed.
Mr. Hoban: Will my hon. Friend give way?
Mr. Tyrie: Yes, at the risk of being diverted.
Mr. Hoban: I have followed my hon. Friend’s argument. He talked about the creative destruction that emerges from new products appearing on the market. It is helpful for a consumer to be able to judge the characteristics of different products so that they can decide whether a new, innovative product is better than the old, stale product. Part of the challenge in financial services is that it can be difficult for consumers to see through the products and understand their characteristics. It is often hard to see the consequences of buying one product compared with another until many years have passed since the original decision to purchase was made. There are, therefore, challenges around simply relying on competition to generate the best deal for consumers.
Mr. Tyrie: I agree with every single word of that. The next paragraph of what I have in front of me alludes to that, as a qualification to my earlier remarks about the primacy of competition. I fully endorse what my hon. Friend has just said.
May I go back to the main theme, which is that we need to put competition up the scale of importance for the FSA? I referred to the number of people who have supported, and continue to support, that idea. I said a moment ago that practitioners liked the idea in theory, until they realised the benefits of the protection that comes with economies of scale and the growth of barriers to entry. However, other people who have looked at the issue have been very clearly in favour of adding competition as an objective.
Don Cruickshank, who did the original work at the time of the first Bill, said:
“Getting the regulator’s primary statutory duties right is essential...A competition objective that is weak relative to the regulator’s other objectives is unlikely to be delivered effectively”.
He was supported in all that by the British Bankers Association, the Association of British Insurers, the National Consumer Council, the Treasury Committee, the Conservative party, the Liberal party—I think—and so on. They are the only bodies that I have taken the trouble to look up recently. A good number of them have carried on saying that sort of thing, to a greater or lesser degree. In the US, the Securities and Exchange Commission has a duty to consider whether any regulation or other action will promote competition, so the United States has exactly what I am asking for in its statute book.
The Government’s only substantive argument against the proposal over the years—I expect we will hear a variation of it from the Minister—is that it could lead the FSA into conflict with other parts of competition policy, in this case with the OFT. However, as I have repeatedly said, that need not be the case. My contention is not that the FSA should take on new powers to supervise competition, but that in the exercise of its powers it should not damage competition in the marketplace. The inclusion of a balancing objective, such as that in new clause 9, would not turn the FSA into another competition regulator. It would merely mean that, in carrying out its distinct remit, it should seek to facilitate competition.
New clause 9 should arm the OFT a little, not get in its way. One thing that it certainly cannot do is weaken it. To ensure that, I withdrew new clause 8—that may have been noticed by Ministers—because I wanted to add a rider at the end of subsection (4) to make it clear that my proposed provisions are
“without prejudice to the statutory powers of the Office of Fair Trading and the Competition Commission.”
So this can only benefit rather than damage the OFT and competition more widely.
The fact that other regulators have competition as a central objective makes its omission from FSMA particularly curious. We now have an opportunity to put that right. My new clause would have three or four big effects. First, competition would act as a counterweight to the inevitable urge to over-regulate. It would be a counter-balancing force for the FSA to consider in discharging its statutory responsibilities. There is a provision in the Act for cost-benefit analysis, but it is well understood and agreed that doing that kind of analysis is complicated, extremely expensive and give, at best, patchy results. The analysis is an expensive surrogate for what should be included, namely the balance between competition and consumer protection, which should be built into the legislation’s objectives for the benefit of the consumer.
On the conduct of business side, when the FSA found that it did not have competition as an objective 10 years ago, even though it wanted it, it tried, to its credit, to make the best of it by ensuring that it did not regulate excessively. I will not go into detail about how it achieved that, but it did it through a number of interesting consultation documents during the first half of the last decade. They were not all perfect, but they largely addressed in an ad hoc way the issue that I am trying to address directly through new clause 9.
The problem for the FSA is that it remains vulnerable to public pressure. Such pressure on a particular case has a ratchet effect on regulation, which leads to an erosion of competition and leads eventually to higher prices, often without any benefit to the consumer. I hope that what I am proposing will address that.
3 pm
The second effect, which I want to mention briefly, touching on something that I mentioned earlier, is that the measure will change the terms of trade between the OFT and the FSA, just a little. Again, to the credit of both institutions, they know that they have to work together, and at the moment they are co-operating extremely well, through early and direct engagement.
The two organisations have produced an interesting document on exactly that subject—a memorandum of understanding. I hope that the Committee will understand my scepticism about such documents. We have been there before, have we not, with the MOU on the tripartite committee? Relying upon what is effectively an informal document is not enough. We should go further, working out ourselves how they should co-operate. We should not have to rely on a memorandum of understanding, as it makes us very dependent on the quality and personal relationships of the people whom we are appointing at the top of those institutions.
We have had a first-rate group of people running the FSA from the beginning. That has not always been the view of the press, however, nor is it the prevailing mantra. None the less, I believe that we have been lucky in those who have been appointed to the FSA. I congratulate the Government on having made a big effort to get good people to run it. I also congratulate the Government —I do not often do so—on their appointment of the current head of the OFT. We have very good people in place, and they are sensibly working closely together, but we should not be entirely dependent on that always being the case. We need something that has some statutory underpinning.
Of course, it should be borne in mind that the relationship between the FSA and the OFT already has a statutory basis, so the principle that legislation should act in this area has been conceded. Section 160 of the Financial Services and Markets Act 2000 gives the OFT the power to review the FSA rules for competition purposes. Sections 303 and 304 require the OFT to give the Treasury advice before bodies such as clearing houses can be approved by the FSA.
The OFT has also been given a specific statutory role to keep an eye on the competition aspects of access to payment services. So the principle is conceded; it is only a question of whether we make it a more broad-based power. New clause 9 would do exactly that. It would give wider effect to the responsibilities of the FSA in the field of competition, and it would give the FSA a wider interest in working closely with the OFT to ensure that it is accomplished.
I said that there were three or four effects. The third flows from the first two. The first was that it would act as a counterweight to the ratchet; the second was that it would strengthen the relationship with the OFT. The third effect would be that consumers will benefit. In the long run, I have no doubt that we would have nudged regulation in the direction of enabling more competition, better products, and hopefully lower costs than would otherwise be the case.
We must never forget that in creating these institutions we are creating big, powerful vested interests. Firms like certainty from the FSA; and, of course, they dislike competitors. If it could, the FSA would want to avoid any regulatory failure. There is always the risk that its efforts in that direction would be at the expense of the consumer. It is only by exercising considerable restraint that have we not found ourselves in that position. Under the new clause, there would be a counterweight, at least, a little more of one than we have had so far.
They have been touched upon today, but I shall draw out a little more what the effects would be in practice. Let us take a lively, specific case—bank charges, which have been discussed. Until recently, they have been self-regulated under the banking standards code, but we all know that that has not worked very well, and we have just heard from members of the Committee some descriptions of how it has not been working well. The FSA tells us, and I believe it, that it will now be more assertive in this area. It has limited power to deal with complaints, and I hope it will be more responsive to those complaints, but, of course, most bank charges relate to overdrafts—a form of consumer credit that is self-regulated under the Consumer Credit Act 2006, rather than FSMA.
The new clause would not provide a direct regulatory solution to those problems of bank charges. That said, the operation of the non-borrowing aspects of current accounts and complaint handling by banks in relation to overdrafts is subject to FSA oversight and acquiring the competition objectives would be a powerful spur to the FSA to work closely with the Office of Fair Trading to address those problems.
A solution to much of the abuse in relation to bank charges is probably available, at least in principle. I believe that transparency would do a lot of the heavy lifting, but so far none of the existing regulators has been able to force the banks to provide it. As the hon. Member for South-East Cornwall said a moment ago, those reams of terms and conditions often make things even more opaque and difficult for consumers, rather than simpler.
In an intervention on the hon. Gentleman, I mentioned a proposal, which I published some time ago through the Centre for Policy Studies, that bank charges should be identified on regular statements as the difference between base rates and the interest being earned by the consumer on that account, and that that should score as a charge. If that proposal were implemented, the consumer would see very clearly that there is no such thing as free banking. The market for short rates is heavily distorted at the moment and the proposal would not work so effectively in this extremely unusual climate, but it would most of the time.
Why have those regulators been unable to provide any real pressure on transparency? Because so much of what is required in bank regulation falls between the cracks of various legislation. I am not suggesting that what I am proposing today will fill every crack, but I do suggest that a competition objective on the FSA would give it the incentive to engage directly and thoroughly with the OFT to try to address and solve the problem.
I ought to say a little about the other main aspect of the interaction of the objectives that I discussed at the start of my speech. I said that there were two main areas: systemic risk and conduct of business regulation. I have been discussing conduct of business regulation. Now I want to say a few words about the systemic risk aspects.
A central issue since the Government’s HBOS intervention is the creation and establishment of a powerful precedent whereby the financial stability objective —it is now in the Bill—could trump the competition objective, or indeed any of the other objectives. I should refer for now to the competition principles, because there will not be a competition objective until the Government accept my measure, which I am sure they will eventually.
The interesting aspect of this is that, when one thinks it through carefully, one has to agree that, in extreme circumstances, one must accept that there should be such an override. There must be circumstances in which the systemic risk is so fundamental that all other objectives become secondary, but we should not forget, when we allow that to take place, that the consumer will always pay for any loss of competition as a result, and he needs to be given protection from exploitation down the line by others. In the HBOS example, exploitation can all too easily occur as a consequence of Government action—indeed, effectively by the Government—albeit, quite reasonably, during their efforts to address a systemic problem.
Let me discuss the HBOS case. HBOS was going bust and the Government were extremely worried about the implications of its failure for the financial system as a whole. The Prime Minister sidled up to Sir Victor Blank and said, “Would you please take HBOS off our hands?” I was not there but I can confidently assert that that must have been the sub-text. Secondly, he would have said, “If you do this, you will be doing a great public service.” Eric Daniels, who gave evidence to the Treasury Committee earlier this week, effectively confirmed that, when he said that the deal was partly motivated by public interest, which I find quite astonishing. I would certainly find that astonishing if I were a Lloyds shareholder.
The third thing that the Prime Minister might have said, but probably hinted, was, “You can buy it on the cheap and, if it turns out that the true value is negative—because you have picked up so much in toxic assets that the positive value of some of the assets is outweighed by the rubbish that has now ended up on your balance sheet—don’t worry too much, Sir Victor. We have a solution. The Government will give you a waiver to the provisions of competition law, enabling you to acquire disproportionately large stakes in several markets.” The implication, of course, was that Lloyds shareholders would have an opportunity to recoup losses by benefiting from the diminished competition for some of their key products in several markets. Among those, post the merger, are building society loans and retail bank accounts. That is exactly where we are now. Indeed, the merger gives the new bank between 30 and 40 per cent. of market share in certain areas, which I have absolutely no doubt the OFT would more than raise an eyebrow about.
The implications of this deal in the long run for competition in the financial sector are extremely worrying. The Government have now used their override, somewhat like the override provided to the Treasury in the legislation creating the independent Bank of England. Once one has fired the shot, one has changed things quite a bit. In the case of the interest rate override, one would have changed things fundamentally and destroyed the Bank of England—it is a nuclear weapon. In this case, it may be just short of a nuclear weapon but it is still very powerful. Whatever the Government’s protestations to the contrary, the effectiveness of competition policy and the OFT has been, at least for a time, prejudiced by the HBOS-Lloyds competition waiver.
Worse still, and this worries me a good deal—I do not think it is unique to Labour Ministers, although it may be the ideology, if there is one these days; the motivation of Labour Ministers tends to be stronger than Conservative ones in this field—once Ministers get an appetite for intervention, they tend to do more.
Only yesterday, Lord Mandelson took advantage of a meeting with institutional investors to meddle with the Kraft-Cadbury merger. What worries me is that those incidents are no longer isolated. In the Bradford & Bingley-Santander merger, a statutory instrument was used to disapply the merger control provisions of the Enterprise Act 2002 altogether. As it turned out, that did not make much difference because the merger met the EU merger regulations threshold and was therefore examined by the European Commission.
Another example is the stipulation by United Kingdom Financial Investments Ltd and the UK Government that any assets that may be sold by Lloyds and HBOS are not permitted to generate a post-acquisition combined market share with the purchaser of more than 15 per cent. Of course, the principle is right that those companies should not have a large market share, but I thought that that was what merger control policy had been put on to the statute book to address. That does not seem to be something that should be addressed, directly or indirectly, by the Government.
3.15 pm
This is why a final reason for giving the FSA oversight of competition at the level of its objectives, which is the effect of new clause 9, is that it could help the OFT to handle Government intervention in the field. The OFT would work more closely with the FSA on the issue, and the effect on the regulatory structure would be such that, if the Government tried to intervene, they would face not one but two quite powerful institutions.
One of the better aspects of the Government’s new competition policy was that they said that they would completely depoliticise the issue. I would find it very concerning if, as a consequence of this crisis, we found the reassertion of a form of what used to be called an industrial policy in the financial services sector by the back door.
I recognise that the Government will not agree to my new clause now—I can tell that just by looking at the Minister, who is a happy man and is smiling amiably at me as I speak—but I ask him at least to agree to think about it carefully between now and the debate on Report for this reason: I have talked politics for the last few paragraphs, and the truth is that, one way or another, the Conservatives will give greater emphasis to competition when we reform financial regulation. According to the polls, that will occur in a few months. Perhaps those polls are wrong, and it may happen in a few years, but either way, it will definitely happen, and I am confident that competition will be given greater emphasis.
If the Minister is prepared to give some further thought to the new clause now, to consult the OFT, FSA and others and to return with a proposal on Report, he will do the right thing not only for the financial sector, but for the cause of working together and forming a consensus on such an important issue.
 
Previous Continue
House of Commons 
home page Parliament home page House of 
Lords home page search page enquiries ordering index

©Parliamentary copyright 2010
Prepared 15 January 2010