Mergers, acquisitions and takeovers: the takeover of Cadbury by Kraft - Business, Innovation and Skills Committee Contents


Examination of Witness (Questions 1-36)

PROFESSOR CHRISTOPHER BONES

12 JANUARY 2010

  Q1  Chairman: Professor Bones, welcome to this one-off evidence session which has the title "Company takeovers, mergers and acquisitions" but whose context is Kraft's bid for Cadbury which has prompted our interest in a subject to which politicians have given much attention over the years. We are very grateful to you for coming before us at our request. You are an academic who takes an interest in these issues but you also have a close personal interest in the affairs of Cadbury. It may be helpful if we first invite you to explain your involvement with and interest in Cadbury.

Professor Bones: Clearly, I am a former employee of Cadbury Schweppes, as it then was. I stepped down in 2004 to take my current job as head of the business school. I am still a shareholder in Cadbury Schweppes. I have 5,000 shares and I am a deferred pensioner so I have an interest in this.

  Q2  Chairman: When I invited you to participate in this session I did not know that, but I think it will help rather than hinder the Committee. It gives them a perspective which they will find very valuable. Perhaps I may say how grateful I am for your thoughtful and helpful written evidence. As a West Midlands MP myself I look at the specifics of Cadbury and ultimately the general underlying principles which may also be important in the future. In your paper you argue that the closure of Cadbury's plants in Birmingham and Sheffield would have a wide and damaging effect on manufacturing in those areas and, I might add, to some of the agricultural interests in that locality. Can you expand on the specific concerns for the wider manufacturing base?

  Professor Bones: Manufacturing for any international business is now a matter of cost and management control. Inevitably, particularly for those companies that can manufacture in different countries decisions are made that offset cost alongside the skill and expertise. Cadbury's strategy has been to maintain skill bases in Birmingham and Sheffield, the former around its chocolate production and the latter around its sugar activity, and it has built a need for critical skills in engineering, manufacturing, planning, procurement and so on in both areas. They took the strategic decision to step away from production in the Bath factory because of the scale of investment required to bring it up to modern standards and felt that that production could be done elsewhere—Poland—for cost reasons whilst protecting the expertise base in the West Midlands and South Yorkshire. Cadbury is not in the top 25 employers in the West Midlands but probably about 1% of the workforce is engaged in Cadbury and its related activities such as tourism. They are mainly in production/manufacturing and the global head office where procurement and so on take place. One is looking at a sizeable strategic investment. They have probably put a few hundred million pounds into Bournville over the past 10 to 15 years, so it is a substantial investment site. My concern is two-fold. If in fairness perhaps a lower performing, some might say a nil growth, conglomerate is to come in and through a leveraged acquisition buy a successful British business clearly for that conglomerate the solution will be about taking out cost, not growing the business better and faster. It is quite obvious from Cadbury's figures this morning that their own efforts are quite substantial. I cannot see the growth claimed for the acquisition. If it is about cost then the manufacturing, research and skills base in the UK comes under threat again because it is easier to take cost out in a foreign market than in a domestic market. Kraft would understand that just as much as anybody else. I have fears for manufacturing generally. I have said in my written evidence that whilst all good intentions are spoken about in the process of an acquisition the track record intriguingly for Kraft was to shut the Terry's of York factory and move production—surprise, surprise—to Poland. Therefore, I do not look at the acquisition commitments perhaps with a great deal of credibility in terms of the comments made for the long term, but I appreciate that this time the circumstances may be different.

  Q3  Chairman: The existing legislative framework under which the Department, Competition Commission and OFT act is laid down very clearly and defines some strategic interests that can be taken into account when mergers are being considered in specific sectors, for example defence and the media. Those provisions have been used in the defence sector on a number of occasions. Is it possible to take any kind of formal legislative account of strategic manufacturing and skills when major companies are subject to takeovers? Is that a sensible approach?

  Professor Bones: I respond in two ways. This is not an anti-market rant. Ultimately, the market, imperfect as it is, is the best mechanism we have for allocating resources efficiently, so this is not about "You shouldn't" or "You can't". But where a bid is made for a successful unit, as opposed to a failing one—in this case it is intriguing that we see a successful company under pressure—if that company has assets that are of critical importance to the future growth of the United Kingdom, which this one does particularly in research and development, for example my own university campus at Reading and in engineering critical mass certainly in the West Midlands, there should be provision for the Government to impose conditions on such an acquisition should it go through. I do not believe it should intervene on whether or not the company is acquired because that is a decision for shareholders, subject to them having a say, but we could ask for conditions to be placed on the investment to protect skills and the long-term requirements of the UK economy.

  Q4  Chairman: Would that require new legislation?

  Professor Bones: As I said in my written evidence, it depends on how you define the national interest. I suspect it would require some interpretation of the current regulations. It may well require legislation but I am not an expert on the law.

  Q5  Chairman: You do not believe that the possible disadvantages of what will be seen by some as a protectionist move would outweigh the advantages of the protection of the R&D and manufacturing base?

  Professor Bones: Perhaps you could argue that it is a more sophisticated way of thinking about national champions. I do not believe that national champions as a strategy is a particularly good one; it is protectionist, but there are national skill requirements and a critical mass of skills and capabilities particularly in the knowledge economy where we wish to compete successfully and where the Government could say to a particular company that it is happy for it to acquire another company but it will impose some conditions. It may be that if you want cost savings you will not get them from that bid; you will continue to protect and invest. I do not believe that is an unfair intervention in the market, and perhaps it would make an acquiring company think carefully about the sort of offers and pricing it is prepared to put in front of owners.

  Q6  Mr Hoyle: I am in favour of that if it protects jobs and investment. What happens if the company then says that the liabilities are so great that it cannot make a profit and wants to close it down? What do you do? Presumably, that is the end of the story. For all the best written words in the world, it is meaningless.

  Professor Bones: It could be. I suspect that you would have to impose some kind of time constraint or limit and say that over a certain period you would expect x or y. Inevitably, all regulation has difficulty. If we are saying that in the national interest we want to invest in the future of the schools base of this country, for which government and opposition parties argue strongly, then in terms of public policy to have platforms to protect that investment is a worthwhile ambition.

  Q7  Lembit Öpik: Turning to research and development, you have already touched on the fact that Kraft's formal documentation regards that as a potential area for cost reduction. You also highlight concerns about the damage this could do to the national interest. You appear to argue strongly that certain requirements should be put in place for takeovers of companies listed on the London Stock Exchange where strategic interests are to be taken into consideration. How could that be done in practice without destroying the freedom of the market?

  Professor Bones: You can probably think of doing three things. The first is to make sure that in any acquisition or bid there is far greater specificity of the intentions of potential acquirer regarding strategic assets of national importance. What is left unsaid in these documents is always far more interesting than what is said, and a lot is left unsaid. For a start, they should tell us more. Second, one could look at what commitments the acquirer would be prepared to make in terms of identified strategic assets. Third, maybe one could impose some sort of time requirement. One could say that from the UK's perspective this is so important that they would be expected to maintain it under the current plans assuming performance continues at the same level, to go back to Mr Hoyle's point. I understand that if a business starts to fail you have to do something about it. That is not what I am arguing. What is intriguing about this acquisition is that it is about acquiring a profitable business, so it is not a fire sale. It is performing well, so why would an acquirer want it?

  Q8  Lembit Öpik: There is the specific example and the strategic macro point. What you say sounds good if you have great negotiators but government is not very good at doing that, which is why we end up wasting a lot of money quite frequently. How can you have a reliable mechanism to achieve that? Sooner or later even the best strategy has to be translated into action?

  Professor Bones: Ultimately, you have to leave it to the market to decide. It is very difficult for any bureaucracy to intervene in the transaction. It really must be of monumental importance to the state. What you do is change the way bids are made and the requirement for detailed information and put far more of your intention into the decision process. I think that allows a far greater degree of transparency in decision-making by share owners than currently exists. It is very difficult to make a decision at the minute apart from just price, but there are many other levers for making those decisions.

  Q9  Lembit Öpik: First, would that not make it less attractive to be in the London Stock Exchange? Second, would it not also reduce the value of companies because of the extra restrictions compared with what might be happening in Hong Kong or Singapore?

  Professor Bones: I am no expert on European M&A legislation. If it were possible to apply this logic to assets owned within the United Kingdom then clearly you would not make it a listing issue; it would be a matter of deciding whether or not to operate here. I suspect that as long as you are non-discriminatory you might well be able to argue a case for it.

  Q10  Roger Berry: Obviously, other countries face similar problems from time to time. What is the experience of other countries in dealing with this? Is there good practice elsewhere that you would recommend? What lessons can we learn from looking at what others have done?

  Professor Bones: I am not sure there are great examples of success. If one looks at the United States companies can acquire for themselves huge amounts of protection from poison pill strategies through to protective administration. The laws of acquisition in many individual states are somewhat more stringent than they are in the United Kingdom. If you believe that inward investment is as important as outward investment you have to live with having one of the most open markets in the world, which we have. I do not argue for our market to be restricted somehow, but I think at the minute there are market failures in this country which mean that people can exploit a merger and acquisition for their own interests more so than in other places. I think it is about improving the transparency of the process in this country. I have not done any empirical research, but on a superficial level there is no reason to say it is better in France or Germany.

  Q11  Roger Berry: Is greater transparency enough?

  Professor Bones: It is transparency in the decision-making process. I deal with it in the last chunk of my written evidence. I believe that what gets in the way is the fact that the owners of the capital employed in any enterprise are not the people who make the decision as to whether or not it stays in their ownership. Since deregulation and Big Bang we have created a series of intermediating stakeholders. I believe that is where the issue of transparency lies.

  Q12  Lembit Öpik: Whilst it is a laudable ambition it is optimistic to expect a government or state bureaucracy to apply what you have said. The Secretary of State can intervene even now in public interest cases that are specifically defined as national security, media plurality and the interests of maintaining the stability of the UK's financial system. To test the specific example, is there any aspect of the Cadbury takeover which falls under any part of that definition?

  Professor Bones: It depends on how far you stretch national security and national interest. I believe that to maintain potentially for security a world-class food science institution within the United Kingdom is rather important to the long-term interests of the country. Therefore, if the Secretary of State chose to do so the Government might be able to argue for some degree or protection or ring-fencing of it from any synergy or cost-costing exercise done by the potential acquirer. I do not believe there is a reason for intervening to stop the deal going through; that is not really where I am. I am much more concerned about the consequences of changes of ownership to strategic assets which are still important but less obviously so as opposed to defence, if you like.

  Q13  Lembit Öpik: You do not believe that we need to amend the definition to include the Cadbury example in a more specific way?

  Professor Bones: I think there is an argument to amend that definition when it comes to strategic skills identified for the long-term economic and financial wellbeing of the country. Food and agricultural science is one of the things that could come within that.

  Q14  Lembit Öpik: To do what you describe means effectively introducing a small element of command economy into the free market. One can talk about it in a theoretical, hopeful sense but there must be some kind of mandate from the state to impose this in an explicit way which would alter what would otherwise happen. Do you believe that is feasible?

  Professor Bones: I certainly would not argue it as a general principle, but there are times when the State needs to set parameters and imperatives. We face three major crises in this country over the next 10 to 15 years one of which is food production and security and improving agricultural performance in the context of climate. Losing a world-class research centre from these shores in that area as a result of a commercial transaction strikes me as somewhat unfortunate.

  Q15  Lembit Öpik: It is either a principle, ie it is strategic, or it is not; if not, it is tactical. How can you do this in a tactical way without introducing this into the market in a random fashion?

  Professor Bones: One must take a strategic view of 10 to 15 years ahead and what is really critical for the UK's security. I believe there are not very many of those things above defence but food security strikes me as one that is pretty essential.

  Q16  Chairman: I looked at some press cuttings back in 2006 when we considered the takeover by various foreign companies of P&O, ports, Thames Water, BAA, BOC, Corus, the London Stock Exchange, Liverpool and West Ham Football Clubs and Scottish Power. For various reasons a lot of those were strategic. One could argue that the energy generation industry is even more strategic than food. What has changed? Have we already gone too far or are there still sufficient industries under British control that it is worth being concerned about them?

  Professor Bones: I do not think it is an issue of control. If at the end of the day the management of enterprise A believes that having access to foreign-owned capital is a way to develop, say, better energy supply in the United Kingdom I do not believe there is a problem in principle at all. The issue is: where these assets are strategically important in the United Kingdom can or should Government take a view about key decisions associated with those assets and apply conditions on ownership or some kind of review of ownership whenever it thinks these are important? We do this in energy through the regulatory authority. The Government regulates a lot of foreign capital through Ofgem so we have a mechanism in place, and the same goes for water. In manufacturing, services and so on very often we do not have regulators and we do not need them, but if with an unregulated industry there are strategic assets can or should the Government apply some conditions about how those assets are taken forward by the new owners? It is not about "You can't own it"; that is not the appropriate response.

  Q17  Mr Clapham: To turn to business practices, you make the point that Cadbury is a very successful business. You also highlight the ethical stance and responsibility in business that Cadbury brings to the market. How does that contrast with Kraft, for example? If we look at how they operate in the market what are the differences between Kraft and Cadbury? On the ethical side, one sees Cadbury's Cocoa Partnership in Ghana which was launched in 2008. Is there anything of that nature in the way that Kraft operates?

  Professor Bones: In fairness to Kraft, one looks at the Rainforest Alliance which is its coffee equivalent. Its cocoa-based business is smaller in comparison whereas coffee is one of its major products. Looking at Kraft's website, its decision to support the Rainforest Alliance is an example of being community-minded and working as a responsible organisation. It is a market-driven mechanism to try to build sustainable supplies, a sustainable supply chain and to invest in sustainable communities. That is very creditable and is very similar to the Cocoa Partnership that Cadbury has initiated. The difference between the two models that strikes me is that Cadbury has a social perspective so its adoption of Fair Trade for Dairy Milk has increased those product sales as a whole by 25% in this country. It has taken Fair Trade from being relatively on the margin to right at the centre; it has added a huge amount of Fair Trade turnover in any category. Fair Trade guarantees a minimum price; the Rainforest Alliance does not but tries to encourage sustainable markets. That is the difference. Both are very creditable approaches. If you look at Cadbury you see it going one step further in terms of its belief about responsibility but some would argue that it is not necessarily a huge step further. Kraft does some creditable things.

  Q18  Mr Clapham: That social perspective is enormously important. When we look at the Kraft takeover of Terry's and what happened following that it appears that Kraft gave certain undertakings but they were not adhered to. Is it fair to say that the way in which Kraft is likely to operate in the market is that it does not have the same kind of responsibility with which Cadbury operates; it does not appear to have the same ethical underpinning?

  Professor Bones: I would put it this way: the drivers for a business listed on a US stock exchange with quarterly reporting and a constant demand for revenue and margin improvement are much more short-term than the drivers for a business listed on a European stock exchange. One can see in the management and business practices of the different listings how much tolerance and acceptance there is of the longer-term and perhaps a more responsible viewpoint. If one operates under tighter constraints one finds it more difficult to justify a drift away from sustainability or investment in communities than perhaps other organisations. I do not think it would be fair to say it is a particular mindset in Kraft or Cadbury. One is a child of the system in which it operates and Kraft operates in a very different system and in its own way.

  Q19  Mr Clapham: But it brings the child of the system into the UK market. There lies the real problem because if it is to be short-term it means that possibly it will move on very quickly. We may well see the cost base move and consequently we shall lose that kind of research and development at the University of Reading.

  Professor Bones: In this session I am just as worried for the shareholders of Kraft as I am for the shareholders of Cadbury. One just has to look at Warren Buffett's intervention a couple of week's ago to understand that Kraft itself has growth problems. Its share owners are not convinced that feeding the executive ego, if you like, for a big acquisition is the right thing to do. The worrying thing is that these sorts of things quickly become about personalities rather than whether or not it is the right thing to do. One need look only at RBS's acquisition of ABN Amro and the battle of the titans as between various chief executives to realise how these things take root. I am with Buffett. I do not believe that it is in Kraft's interests to acquire this particular business for a price that is much more than it bid, and clearly if you look at the results this morning it is not in the interests of Cadbury's shareholders to accept the price that is currently on the table. At that stage one might say that it is time to walk away. The problem is the fuelling of all of this by advisers, investment banks and so on. The Times made a calculation based on figures sourced from Reuters for the last year that fees of about £600 million could be spent in this takeover battle on advisers, lawyers, investment banks and other people regardless of whether or not this happens. One of my big worries is that the Cadbury brand will end up taking on the costs of its own acquisition and defence which could run even closer to £1 billion plus the interest on leverage funds used to acquire it—even if Kraft put in more cash which it does not have today. What will that do to a profitable business and therefore to the cost base? It is not about Kraft's way of managing it; I think it is about the consequences of what it is doing which potentially puts its own business as well as Cadbury's at risk.

  Q20  Mr Clapham: Cadbury is a successful company and the shareholders of both companies would perhaps be better looked after were Cadbury able to continue as a prosperous company in the UK.

  Professor Bones: I think it was KPMG who did a piece of work about seven or eight years ago which showed that 80% of hostile takeovers failed to deliver the case that was put to shareholders to justify the price paid. The 20% that delivered the case, succeeded because they were underpinned by factors such as common cultures, a common understanding and so on. Until I left Cadbury's its track record was that 80% of its acquisitions met or bettered the business case. That is because Cadbury has never conducted a hostile acquisition. Its latest acquisition was Green & Black's which came to Cadbury and asked to be taken over. It asked to be taken over because Cadbury had values; it had a belief in brand, it understood what Green & Black's stood for in terms of responsibility and ethical sourcing, but could give the manufacturing, procurement and distribution scale—Green & Black's is now taking on America very strongly—in order to build the Green & Black's brands, so it would invest in it long-term. As to Kraft and Cadbury, having worked for one and looked carefully at the other their cultures are very different; their way of operating is so different; their business conscience and approach are different. Particularly with the leverage involved this cannot be anything other than a potential disaster as opposed to a potential success whatever price is paid for it. This is not an issue of government policy, but it does say something about how we educate business managers. They really do not understand that to waste share-owner money on a potential ego trip, (for that is what they have done in this bid) is a serious issue.

  Q21  Ian Stewart: Successive governments have bought into the concept of a shareholder democracy. You have argued that the reforms have given the decision-making power to a small number of fund-holders which is not necessarily in the interests of many shareholders. We live in a market economy. Any economic system has strengths and weaknesses. You have raised concerns about the different roles of the shareholders and middlemen in relation to takeover decisions. What can be changed to ensure that the interests of the individual investor are protected? I believe that earlier you were keen to say something about that. This is now your opportunity.

  Professor Bones: Perhaps I may go back to Adam Smith because there is an important principle here to do with investors. When Smith wrote his original text he talked about the invisible hand in the market. Quite often that has been hijacked by neoclassical or monetarist economists who say that the logic of the invisible hand is that one therefore leaves the market alone. The invisible hand was the guiding social and political principle behind investment decisions; in other words, despite the return that could have been offered to Scottish bankers more often than not they chose to invest in Scottish or local opportunities even though the returns perhaps were financially not as great. One could say that if only RBS had done that it would have been fine. What is really interesting about it is that what Smith noted, and is still true today, is that the real investor, the owner of the capital, does not make an entirely financial decision. If you ask ordinary share owners about transaction A or transaction B quite often regardless of price there will be other reasons for keeping the shares or some of them. Smith picked this up. Obviously, he could not measure it and he called it "the invisible hand". I believe that as a result of the rise of intermediating forces the invisible hand has become the invisible incentive. For stakeholders the invisible incentive is the way they run the funds, the cash they need, the profitability target and potentially the trigger of bonus payments which would lead to decision A as opposed to decision B; in other words, they are not acting for my long-term capital interests but perhaps for their long-term and sometimes short-term gain. It is a completely different interest from that of the share owner. In a market economy—again, this is not an attack on the market—this strikes one as a market failure and therefore the Government could consider putting some constraints on the funds to make sure they consult the owners of the capital before they act on their behalf. For most fund managers it is not their capital; it is not their skin in the game but my skin and yours. For pension funds it is quite easy to do it because you can say that if a pension fund hold block A in company B then the trustee should be consulted on how the shares or number of votes it holds should be cast. There are trustee mechanisms in place today for pension funds that can easily be engaged to do that. The other thing Government must do is consider democratising funds and requiring the fund management company to consult the owners of the capital when a decision has a pecuniary benefit to the fund management company itself, which accounts for quite a lot of decisions. I believe there is a role for Government in the market in terms of structuring funds, not to intervene in the actions of the market but to say to it that it will act properly so that the real owners of the capital have their say. You can see, therefore, fund managers casting three votes: a percentage for yes, a percentage for no and a percentage for abstaining, as they are entitled to do today. I do not believe that you would not have to change the law for them to do that.

  Q22  Ian Stewart: Do you argue that we are not concerned with just the qualitative aspect of the decision-making and what we need is for Government to look at regulation?

  Professor Bones: I am not a great believer in over-regulating anything, but this is an area where there is a surprising lack of regulation. I am not surprised because these funds and their impact have mushroomed over the past 30 to 40 years. In the old days of a stock-holding company if we were shareholders of company A we would all turn up in the room and cast a vote. For most large corporations the annual general meetings are a bit of a joke. The annual general meeting vote may go against a remuneration report but millions of shares cast by 10 investment fund managers in favour of it gets it through. I am saying that is not in the best interests of capitalism or the market economy in this country.

  Q23  Ian Stewart: In your view what department should lead on that? Would it be the Department for Business, Innovation and Skills or HM Treasury?

  Professor Bones: It is a business ownership issue. If you have a department that looks after the interests of good governance in business it should pay attention to how the real owners of the capital employed by that business are engaged in decisions about that business.

  Q24  Ian Stewart: Have you had any discussions with either Department about these issues or shareholder rights?

  Professor Bones: I have submitted my opinion on the matters of principle to officials in the Department for Business, Innovation and Skills and not surprisingly it is very similar to the written evidence you have in front of you.

  Q25  Ian Stewart: You have given us your views about potential regulation and to which department you think that should relate. If the free market is to be maintained as you wish it to be can any reasonable protections be given to listed companies on the London Stock Exchange so that they remain listed in the UK rather than move to other stock exchanges? That appeared to be your concern earlier.

  Professor Bones: In some ways it is a consequence of the globalisation of everything. Ultimately, business will globalise as well. I do not believe there is anything other than very unsubtle and ultimately unhelpful regulation that can be put in place to protect LSE-listed companies over and above other organisations, hence my earlier comment on the research and development side. There are things that Government can do which are perhaps more sophisticated and challenging.

  Q26  Ian Stewart: Do you argue that rather than heavy-handed regulation for the LSE and so on labour market development issues like training and skills can play an important role in this area?

  Professor Bones: Yes. I am surprised by the public policy gap in terms of the pronouncements of legislators and others who say that the supply side in the economy is as important as the demand side and yet do not think of the consequences of economic transition which will happen inevitably in relation to things like strategic skills and opportunities for training and development. We are at risk of potentially de-skilling Britain. Whether you put 50% or 80% through university will not make a hoot of difference. What is important is that there is skilled, challenging and well remunerated employment available to people with skills and good education. We are banging people through university at the minute. As someone who sits in one of Europe's top business schools it is really difficult to see where a lot of our graduates will go over the next few years if fewer and fewer opportunities exist for really skilled people. Thinking about the demand side and what one does in the market to protect it is as important as thinking about the supply side.

  Q27  Mr Hoyle: You state in your memorandum that, "The ultimate irony for any government would be the sight of the corporate banking team at RBS or any other government-owned institution being paid multi-million-pound bonuses for funding the acquisition of a UK company by a US conglomerate at a price that failed to reflect real market value with an outcome that damaged the long-term interests of the UK economy." Those are very strong words, and I totally agree with them. To push it along a bit, quite rightly you criticise the role of RBS. Effectively, it is a state-owned bank—we can all agree on that—and it is providing funds for a takeover. Do you think the Government should intervene as the virtual owner of RBS to stop it facilitating Kraft's takeover in the bid for Cadbury?

  Professor Bones: As to Kraft's bid for Cadbury, the involvement of a taxpayer-owned bank in supporting a less than successful global conglomerate to buy a successful British company is surprising. I am particularly surprised that the Government as the main representative of the taxpayer shareholder in RBS has not said to RBS that now it owns the bank—it did not want to do so and would probably like to get rid of it at some point soon—it will operate not just for short-term profitability but for the long-term interests of the United Kingdom. I do not believe there is any shame or problem with the major shareholder saying that to the bank and then getting the bank to respond with an investment policy that meets its profitability targets but at the same time supports British businesses. I just do not understand why we have not done it.

  Q28  Mr Hoyle: The suggestion is that we bring morality into banking?

  Professor Bones: It is not morality. Perhaps you bring in exactly what Smith said: you bring back to banking the invisible hand.

  Q29  Mr Hoyle: I do not disagree with you. There is a role there and RBS ought to think about what it is doing. At some point there is more to life than profit. We are talking of the future of UK jobs, R&D and so on. We can go through all of that. Would not the issue be that it would only go to another bank, so is it not the case that a British-based bank which gives a profit to the taxpayer is not allowed to do it but we are quite happy for a foreign bank to increase profits for its shareholders?

  Professor Bones: The answer is: yes, as has always been the case. I just think it is remarkable that where we have the opportunity to leverage the banking sector we do not take it to build the economy. Whilst leaving it for others is fine, I think that to make it that much more difficult to do these sorts of things is a perfectly legitimate government ambition where it tries to protect what it sees as jobs and productivity in the UK.

  Q30  Mr Hoyle: Do you believe that in part this takeover has been created by Cadbury itself because the demerger of Schweppes has made it more attractive? It has put profit in the bank and invited companies round the world to take it over? Is it Cadbury's own failure that has caused it?

  Professor Bones: Cadbury has been under pressure from its major share owners for some time to dispose of its soft drinks business which, if you exclude the United States, owned only 3% of the world market as against Coke and Pepsi that own 20% to 30% each. But it was ultimately Cadbury Schweppes' poison pill equivalent because it was a very difficult thing to have and it put a number of big predators at bay. Clearly, by doing what its intermediating stakeholders wanted to do, which was to get rid of the drinks industry, it created a lot of value for those people in the short-term, but that value is now not reflected in continuing share price growth. It has since focused on confectionery. It is a very good commercial company. If you want my personal opinion, a share owner in Cadbury would be much better served by a link with Hershey than with Kraft. Hershey owns in perpetuity all of Cadbury's production licences from its products in the United States in the early 1980s when it had to get out in a hurry or go bust. Frankly, if one is looking at the interests of Cadbury one will say that to get back control of its US brands is much more attractive to management and a much better proposition for Cadbury's share owners than to become part of a processed food conglomerate.

  Q31  Mr Hoyle: Basically, I believe that Cadbury is the good guy and Kraft is the bad guy, so we are on the same side. You go on to say that the US conglomerate is not a very successful one and Kraft is perhaps a failing company. If that is so do you think RBS ought to fund Cadbury to do a reverse takeover of Kraft and sell off the failing company? Would that make sense?

  Professor Bones: I do not think Cadbury is an expert in processed foods and it probably should avoid it at all costs.

  Q32  Mr Hoyle: That is why you would sell it off.

  Professor Bones: I do not believe Kraft is a failing company; it is just not a very strongly performing company. It is a company that has all the trappings of the US conglomerate up to and including the corporate jet.

  Q33  Mr Hoyle: There is a big saving there, is there not?

  Professor Bones: If I were Irene Rosenfeld I would look to my own margins and costs before grabbing something else in order to improve my growth figures. If I were a Kraft shareholder I would insist on that. As to funding, the challenge for RBS is that according to the CBI there are a lot of British businesses—here I agree with the director general—looking and applying for but failing to get funds for jobs, investment, expansion and capital investment. Frankly, if I was an RBS shareholder, which is why I pick on RBS as a taxpayer-owned bank, I would be looking to use those assets to build Britain's recovery from recession which is pretty slow at the minute.

  Q34  Roger Berry: Referring to the final paragraph of your memorandum just quoted by my colleague, I do not find this situation strange at all. You have said repeatedly that you believe by and large the market should be allowed to operate, but there are two quite distinct issues here, are there not? In a sense you are rolling them up into a rather nice final paragraph. One issue is takeover policy; the other is the role of banks. Do you agree that getting the takeover policy right is the issue and in a sense whether or not RBS is involved in this is a sideshow? If there is an opportunity for RBS to make money you would advocate that banks should be allowed to do so. In the final paragraph are you not moving the issue away from the key point which is takeover policy? I will take swipes against RBS like the best of them; they deserve quite a lot, but that is not the issue here. The issue is takeover policy, is it not?

  Professor Bones: I think it is an interesting side issue though a related one. The core issue, to which the Committee may wish to return in some detail, is that it appears to me the distance that has been created between the owners of capital and the stewards of it, ie the managers of an enterprise, and therefore the lack of communication and mutual interest is a fundamental shift in the capitalist structure over the past 50 to 60 years which is starting to put at risk whether the joint stock company is a sensible solution for capital ownership. Ultimately, it is a bit of a farce because the real owners of the capital do not get to cast the votes. For most big stock-holding companies there is a little oligarchy at the top that casts a lot of votes and has a lot of power. That strikes me as a much more fundamental issue for policy than some of the specifics around Cadbury/Kraft. If you can get the rights of ownership right so owners can say, "This is my capital and I want a say", you create the grounds for a successful share-owning and property-owning democracy with real accountability. At the moment in my view the stewards are getting off lightly and a lot of middle people are making a lot of money.

  Q35  Roger Berry: But do not those who own RBS, whether it is the state or individuals, benefit from that or any other bank making money out of takeovers?

  Professor Bones: Indeed; the Exchequer benefits from RBS making money out of takeovers, but in the long-term does the British economy benefit from some of these actions?

  Q36  Lembit Öpik: Given Roger Berry's question and the real world, the Government has said that basically it is looking after RBS until it can stand on its own two feet again. In order to do what you describe the Government would have to do something extra: to start using its stock in RBS to guide social or economic policy. Leaving aside the political discussion, is it practical for the Government to do that without directly contradicting its own objectives, ie rehabilitating RBS and giving it back to the private sector?

  Professor Bones: The success of the Co-operative Bank and the co-operative movement generally over the past few years is probably an example of why it might be in the long-term interests of private sector banking to think more about social and political issues than just short-term profit.

  Chairman: That is a subject for another time but it is a fascinating one. Thank you very much for that very helpful discussion.





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2010
Prepared 6 April 2010