Low carbon technologies in a green economy - Energy and Climate Change Contents


Memorandum submitted by the South East England Development Agency (SEEDA)

SUMMARY POINTS

  1.  SEEDA fully endorses the joint memorandum already submitted on behalf of England's Regional development Agencies. We do however have a few additional issues that we believe the Committee should consider, and in particular would propose the following key areas for the Committee to explore and make recommendations on:

    (a) Major economic opportunities for the UK will come from the supply chain associated with the major expansion of offshore wind. These will be lost if the critical link with UK Ports is not made and if the UK's "offer" to international wind technology companies is not sufficiently attractive and supportive.

    (b) We are concerned that the recommendations of the Commission on Environmental Markets and Economic Performance (CEMEP), while fully accepted by Government, are not being fully implemented. In particular, we remain concerned that Government measures will have a medium term benefit but greater urgency is needed on measures and incentives that will impact now to bring low-carbon innovation and market development; such as forward-looking public procurement.

    (c) In addition, the urgent need to avoid dangerous climate change as well as achieve economic benefit for the UK demands a more enlightened approach to payback and rates of return. Companies, especially SMEs, need to secure financial support to progress innovation from successful R&D and demonstration to full commercialisation to bridge the so-called "valley of death"; there is a need for more substantive support and for new ways of generating it.

    (d) We propose a possible solution—a "Green Bond"—which, for innovative, pre-commercial companies, most of which are likely to be in an early, loss-making phase, would monetise all unutilised accumulated corporation tax losses and give an immediate cash payment which would substantially increase short-term cash flow and provide bridge financing through to commercialisation.

INTRODUCTION

  2.  SEEDA welcomes the opportunity to submit evidence to the Committee on this important topic. SEEDA fully supports and endorses the joint memorandum submitted by the North West Development Agency on behalf of England's nine Regional Development Agencies (RDAs); however, we wish to emphasise a number of key issues, as follows:

PORTS AND RENEWABLE ENERGY SUPPLY CHAIN OPPORTUNITIES

  3.  We welcome the Government's recognition of the importance of UK Ports in the context of marine renewable energy, particularly offshore wind, and DECC's initiative in producing a UK Ports Prospectus and in March, bringing together port operators and energy developers.

  4.  However, given the major UK supply chain opportunities associated with the major expansion of offshore wind envisaged by Government (an additional 25GW by 2020), suitable UK Port facilities, especially for concrete construction and turbine assembly, are both a critical anchor and conduit for the involvement of the UK supply chain.

  5.  With no indigenous UK-based manufacturer of large-scale wind turbines, economic benefit to the UK from offshore wind expansion will derive largely from maximising supply chain involvement. Construction of an additional 25GW of offshore wind turbines could cost of the order of £75bn. A study[79] of the Scroby Sands windfarm found that over 40% of the value of the scheme accrued to the UK. Even if, by 2020 only 20% of the value of the additional 25GW was available to UK supply chain companies, this would represent a highly significant £15 billion market opportunity.

  6.  However, since it is perfectly possible (and indeed, there are direct examples) to construct and maintain a UK offshore wind farm without setting foot in the UK, much, if not all, of this supply chain opportunity could be lost if the critical link with UK ports is not made and if the UK "offer" to international wind technology companies is not sufficiently attractive and supportive. While Government is in dialogue with interested Ports, we would wish to see suitable incentives in place (EIB energy infrastructure support loans, for example) to encourage Port engagement with offshore renewable energy opportunities and suitable enhancement of facilities where required; Government might also require Port owners to address and respond positively to offshore renewable energy opportunities in their Port Development plans.

LOW-CARBON INNOVATION AND PROCUREMENT

  7.  Support for low-carbon innovation clearly has a key role in driving forward the "green economy", and we welcome the work of the Energy Research Partnership and the initiative of the Energy Technologies Institute, Technology Strategy Board and Carbon Trust to produce a joint innovation strategy to clarify and improve the targeting of their support. We are however concerned that the recommendations of the Commission on Environmental Markets and Economic Performance (CEMEP), while fully accepted by Government in 2008, are not being fully implemented, nor, it seems, have they fully informed the Government's Low Carbon Industrial "Vision". The Commission, set up by Gordon Brown, when Chancellor, sought to identify what was needed for the UK to maximise benefits from the growing global market opportunities for low/zero carbon products and services associated with the imperative to tackle global warming.

  8.  CEMEP identified four key themes to take forward: setting a long term policy framework to encourage confidence for business to invest; creating the conditions to allow innovation to flourish; ensuring the economy has the skills needed to be successful; and delivering this agenda through collaboration between government, business, trade unions, educational institutions and others. Public procurement has a key role in stimulating market development for low-carbon products and services, and CEMEP highlighted the importance of "forward procurement" (ie committing, at some future date, to purchase a product which does not yet exist) in generating 'innovation pull'. Wider application of forward procurement across the public sector would help to accelerate progress towards the low-carbon economy.

  9.  In our view, that acceleration is critical to securing the economic benefits from a low-carbon economy. CEMEP was particularly concerned at the Government's lack of urgency in supporting and delivering measures and incentives for low-carbon innovation and market development. The Commission drew attention to the risks involved, in terms of losing benefit of first-mover advantage, along with opportunities lost to faster-moving competitors in global markets. We remain concerned at the apparent lack of urgency and the real risk of missed opportunities, taken up instead by the UK's foreign competitors.

COMMERCIALISATION OF LOW-CARBON SOLUTIONS: BRIDGING THE "VALLEY OF DEATH"

  10.  Progressive regulation governing performance and technology clearly has a key role in stimulating product/process innovation; the rapid adoption of condensing boilers in the UK is a recent case in point. In our view, Government could do more through regulation to accelerate innovation to achieve low or zero-carbon solutions; the urgent need to avoid dangerous climate change demands a greater focus on outcomes, with a correspondingly more enlightened approach to payback and rates of return.

  11.  SEEDA works with a range of partners to support research and demonstration of innovative technologies, products and services. Drawing on our direct experience, we would wish to draw the Committee's attention to the important need, particularly acute in the economic downturn, for companies, especially SMEs, to secure financial support to progress innovation from successful R&D and demonstration to full commercialisation, to bridge what has been termed the "valley of death", where many worthwhile innovations perish. This is clearly another significant contributor—notwithstanding a wealth of innovative ideas—to the UK potentially losing out to international competition in growing global markets for low-carbon goods and services.

  12.  There is a clear need, therefore, for more substantive support for commercialisation of low-carbon technologies and a corresponding need to explore new ways of generating that support. We wish to bring to the Committee's attention a novel approach—a tradeable "Green Bond"—proposed by a key low-carbon technology company in the South East region. In our view, this initiative, if adopted, would offer the potential to generate up-front capital to support the commercialisation phase for the company's micro-CHP product.

  13.  The Green Bond would be designed to assist innovative, pre-commercial companies, most of which are likely to be loss-making, simply because of their position in the both the business and product development cycles. As a result of their loss-making performance, these companies will have accumulated unutilised corporation tax losses. These losses can be carried forward by the company and used to reduce corporation tax liabilities arising from future profits generated (when their product is in the market). The accumulated tax losses have a future cash value.

  14.  While the current R&D tax credit system allows companies to claim a tax repayment in cash based upon a percentage of losses incurred due to "approved" R&D expenditure, these tax losses would normally only be recoverable as a reduction in taxes payable on future profits generated by the firm. While useful to increase cash inflow from losses, the amount that can be recovered is restricted to only a small percentage of the total losses incurred by companies involved in new product development—typically 5% of losses incurred.

  15.  However, the "Green Bond" would involve an immediate cash payment based on 100% of the unutilised accumulated tax losses, which would substantially increase the short term cash flow of the business and serve as a bridge financing through to commercialisation.

    — The Bond is secured on accumulated tax losses and the repayment term is based on the future expected profitability of the company (a maximum of five years, say).

    — The Bond is a liability on the company's balance sheet.

    — The Bond pays an annual coupon at a level in line with long term yields of UK Government gilts.

    — The company would receive cash in exchange for Bonds by selling them to the Bank of England or possibly to the Treasury. The Bond could also be guaranteed by the government and sold to private investors.

    — The bond is repaid by the company, either by refinancing through the debt/equity markets or using payments it would have made by way of tax on future taxable profits.

  16.  The key aspect of this scheme is that it monetises an existing deferred tax asset of the company, but at a much earlier stage than the company would have achieved through the reduction of taxes payable on future profits generated by the company. The downside is that the government would have to accept "equity type" risk (as it does currently with the R&D tax credit system) by lending against current tax losses which could only be recovered against taxable profits to be earned in the future. This "equity type" risk could be reduced by requiring the company to raise some money from shareholders at the same time as the bond is issued.

June 2009






79   A Report to Renewables East by Douglas-Westwood Limited and ODE Limited. Commissioned by the DTI. DWL Report Number 334-04. July 2005. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2010
Prepared 28 March 2010