The future of Britain's electricity networks - Energy and Climate Change Contents


Memorandum submitted by the Sussex Energy Group

ABOUT THE SUSSEX ENERGY GROUP

  1.  The Sussex Energy Group undertakes academically rigorous, inter-disciplinary research that engages with policy-makers and practitioners. The aim of our research is to identify ways of achieving the transition to sustainable, low carbon energy systems whilst addressing other important policy objectives such as energy security. We a group of 15 social scientists, working from a multidisciplinary perspective. Our core support is provided by the Economic and Social Research Council, and we also have funding from a diverse array of other sources. Through the Group, the University of Sussex is a core partner of the Tyndall Centre for Climate Change Research. The Group is also part of the UK Energy Research Centre.

2.  We welcome this inquiry into the future of Britain's electricity networks. Networks are often forgotten in debates about energy futures, yet they will play a crucial role in facilitating the transition to a sustainable, low carbon energy system. In our response to the Committee's questions, we have spent most of the time on those questions in which we have particular expertise. This expertise derives from a number of related Sussex Energy Group projects and activities. These include research on the governance and regulation of electricity networks in the UK and Denmark, the role of control systems in these networks, and on the policy implications of decentralised energy systems.

SPECIFIC RESPONSES TO THE COMMITTEE'S QUESTIONS

What should the Government's vision be for Britain's electricity networks, if it is to meet the EU 2020 renewables target, and longer-term security of energy supply and climate change goals?

  3.  The EU 2020 target will mean a significant increase in the deployment of renewable energy in the UK. Renewable electricity production will play a particularly prominent role in meeting the UK's target under the EU burden-sharing agreement. This expansion of renewable electricity—together with other changes required to reduce carbon emissions—will require electricity networks to be extended to new locations, and to operate in new ways. The planned expansion of offshore wind power will increase the amount of intermittent power generation in the electricity system and will also require a new offshore network infrastructure to be built. The growing deployment of other renewable technologies and combined heat and power (CHP) is likely to entail a shift in the scale of electricity generation. Electricity distribution networks will therefore be required to integrate generation at a range of scales—from an individual household solar panel to an inner-city CHP plant. Distribution system operators will need to play a more active role in system operation and control.

4.  What will need to change is not just the layout of cables, but rather the overall system infrastructure that connects generation and supply, including for example new control systems infrastructure that can integrate demand into system operation. This transformation will not just be a technical challenge. The government's vision also needs to have economic, institutional and regulatory components. History shows that technologies, institutions and policies change in inter-related ways. In the UK, these changes have built an increasingly centralised electricity system which is built around fossil and nuclear generation. The "lock-in" of this system to a centralised model presents a challenge when government policies now require the system to change.[117]

5.  Overcoming this lock-in therefore requires regulatory and policy changes which support the required changes in technologies. This has consequences for the approach to economic analysis and regulation that is followed by government and the regulator. In the past, UK regulation has approached potential changes in electricity networks in a piecemeal fashion. Potential new investments have been assessed to see whether they improve the efficiency of the electricity network we currently have. But the need to change to a significantly different network architecture means that such an approach is no longer fit for purpose. Economic appraisal will need to take account of the electricity networks that will be required in the future—and use these future systems as a benchmark against which new investments are appraised.

How do we ensure the regulatory framework is flexible enough to cope with uncertainty over the future generation mix?

  6.  There are two challenges to consider: to build a network infrastructure that is flexible enough to accommodate various development options for both generation and demand (which clearly come at a cost), and to have a regulatory framework that allows for this infrastructure flexibility and is itself flexible enough to adapt to new developments.

7.  The current UK system of incentive regulation of networks is a relative flexible regime, with fixed regulatory periods, regular reviews and in-built learning processes. However, this regulatory framework was developed to increase the efficiency of the existing network, and minimise costs to consumers. Long-term transformation of these networks in the way that is now necessary is more difficult to achieve within this regulatory framework. As the discussion surrounding the recent Transmission Access Review[118] has demonstrated, regulators now need to allow investment that is more strategic—and to take a view of the way in which medium and long-term targets for renewables might be achieved.

  8.  Therefore, in order to promote a long-term transformation of the network, incentives that mimic market forces need to be complemented by instruments that: (i) go beyond one five-year regulatory period; (ii) link regulatory interventions to scenarios of future development options; and (iii) provide coordination mechanisms for the stakeholders involved. Some progress has been made by Ofgem to fulfil these requirements. For example, the recently completed Long Term Electricity Network Scenarios (LENS) project sets out a range of scenarios for the future of electricity grids.[119] The Transmission Access Review has proposed some new incentives for investment "ahead of need" to connect generation assets such as offshore windfarms. However, progress in implementing new incentives has often been slow. Therefore, questions remain about the extent to which these changes are occurring fast enough to deliver the UK's 15% renewable energy target.

What are the technical, commercial and regulatory barriers that need to be overcome to ensure sufficient network capacity is in place to connect a large increase in onshore renewables, particularly wind power, as well as new nuclear build in the future? For example issues may include the use of locational pricing, or the availability of skills.

  9.  A number of barriers are slowing down the connection and integration of wind energy within the UK electricity network. For example, there is a particularly large queue of wind power plants waiting for connection in Scotland. Both cost and planning barriers to network investments have contributed to this slow progress.

10.  For offshore wind, the barriers are largely due to the incumbent regulatory regime. This regime gives transmission companies little incentive to invest strategically in offshore infrastructure. Such strategic investment may be required before there are firm plans to build specific offshore wind farms that will full use the resulting transmission capacity. Whilst this brings with it risks of over-investment and stranded assets, the work of the Energy Networks Strategy Group shows some network investments are fairly robust to different scenarios of renewables deployment in the UK.[120] So the risks of implementing these "ahead of need" are relatively low.

  11.  According to one recent assessment, other regulatory barriers include the inability of the incumbent regime to differentiate between different types of generation, to recognise the `replacement' role of renewable generation, or to allow transmission capacity to be shared between renewable and non-renewable generation.[121] The process of developing modifications to this regime has been slow. It is already over six years since the former DTI published its strategy for offshore wind: Future Offshore.[122] Whilst the need for new incentives for offshore transmission investment was acknowledged in this strategy, implementation of these incentives has not yet been completed.

  12.  As a result of the Transmission Access Review, some options for a new regulatory approach have been put forward. These include both short term fix to speed up the connection process and overcome the immediate barriers to progress. A range of long-term options have also been proposed. Whilst all have pros and cons, some of the more market-based options are highly complex. Although they are designed to maximise economic efficiency, there are concerns that these arrangements for transmission investment and access will be expensive and time consuming to implement.

What challenges will higher levels of embedded and distributed generation create for Britain's electricity networks?

  13.  There are a number of technical, economic and regulatory and political challenges associated with higher levels of distributed generation in the UK. One of the key reasons why such generation is seen as "difficult" the UK context is that the incumbent system is highly centralised. Unlike many other European countries, the UK has no recent tradition of decentralised electricity production. It is also important to note that distributed electricity generation (and other distributed energy options) can be deployed at a range of scales. Distributed generation can include household technologies such as micro-CHP or solar PV panels, small-scale wind farm in a village or a city-wide CHP system. Implementation of these options could include a variety of different investors from householders and energy companies to local authorities. But significant policy changes are required to enable this full range of actors and options to play a significant role.

14.  The technical challenges arise because distributed generation has a particularly strong impact on the existing distribution network. In the UK, this network was not designed for that purpose. Furthermore, distributed generation is not just about connecting new plants to the existing system, but also about innovation and transformation of the system so that such plants can be properly integrated into system operation. The associated regulatory challenges arise because a more decentralised electricity system requires distribution network operators to take on a more active role in managing their networks—and therefore need the appropriate incentives to do so. The impact of distributed generation on distribution networks can vary widely and depends, for example, on the density and number of distributed generators on the system, the extent to which networks are urban or rural, and the types of distributed generators that are connected. These factors and others should be taken into account by the regulatory framework, especially when comparing the efficiency of network operators.

  15.  The technical and regulatory impacts of distributed generation are explored further in the Table below. This shows how both sets of impacts will vary according to the approach taken to distributed generation. This approach ranges from piecemeal connection (in the left hand column) to transformation (in the right had column). In the former case, each generator is appraised with reference to the current system and is connected as a "one off". In the latter case, there is a strategic and co-ordinated approach to developing generation and network infrastructure together with demand-side measures. The result is a network that is very different to the one we have today. At present, the UK regulatory regime is making some tentative moves from connection to integration. It has a long way to go before it is capable of facilitating the innovation and system transformation that would be required to absorb significant amounts of distributed generation.

Table: From the connection of distributed generation (DG) to system transformation
ConnectionIntegration InnovationTransformation
Technical issuesConnection of DG to distribution network

DG contributes energy to system
Integration of DG into operation of existing network
DG takes some responsibility for system support
DG contributes capacity to system
See Integration;

Development and deployment of innovative network technologies to integrate DG into network operation
Transformation of network structure beyond innovation in individual parts of the network. Changes in overall system design and control
Economic and Regulatory IssuesDG connection means additional network costs Additional network costs of DG can be reduced;

In some cases, DG can help reduce network costs
See Integration;

Additional costs and benefits of RD&D
Difficult to apply "traditional" cost-benefit analysis to system transformation


What are the estimated costs of upgrading our electricity networks, and how will these be met?

  16.  We have not developed our own estimates of the costs of upgrading electricity networks to facilitate the 2020 renewables target and other measures required to meet medium- and long-term emissions reduction targets. The government-led Electricity Networks Strategy Group recently published a cost estimate of £4.7 billion.[123] They argue that this expenditure would be required to meet the 2020 renewables target as well as to connect other generation investment it regarded as "essential" such as some new nuclear. As the ENSG acknowledge, the actual costs will depend on how the renewables target is met and a range of other factors.

17.  Looking further ahead, the costs of network investment to help facilitate the deep cuts in emissions required by 2050 are much more difficult to estimate. In principle, there are many possible ways to achieve such deep cuts which could have significantly different implications for networks. For example, a scenario in which the electricity system is extended to meet demand for heating and transport is likely to entail significantly higher network costs than a scenario in which transport and heating are met by other low carbon energy sources or carriers (eg hydrogen, renewable heat and so on). A set of scenarios for 2050 were recently developed for Ofgem which usefully illustrate a wide range of possible development pathways for UK electricity networks.[124] An economic analysis of these scenarios was carried out, albeit with the usual caveats about the difficulty of assessing costs over such long timescales.

18.  Whatever future pathway emerges for UK electricity networks, a key principle is that the majority of the costs should be shared across all consumers. There are two reasons for this. First, network assets are natural monopolies. Second, the need to upgrade and extend these network assets is driven by public policy objectives such as the 2020 renewables target. It is unlikely that new infrastructure to meet these objectives could be financed solely through transmission access payments by new generators. Similarly, it is difficult to justify passing on the costs of these network upgrades to consumers who happen to be connected near to the new generation assets.

How can the regulatory framework ensure adequate network investment in light of the current credit crunch and recession?

  19.  Many have argued that one of the responses to the credit crunch and recession should be public investment via green stimulus packages (a "Green New Deal").[125] These packages should comprise investment in a range of cleaner technologies, infrastructures and industries—and therefore represent an opportunity to increase investments in new, more innovative electricity network infrastructure. Accelerating electricity network investments through green stimulus packages could help to counter any negative impacts of the recession on investment plans. It would also have the advantage of tempering the regressive increases in consumer electricity bills that would otherwise be required.

How can the regulatory framework encourage network operators to innovate, and what is the potential of smart grid technologies?

20.  So far, the regulatory framework for electricity networks has not been particularly successful at encouraging innovation. The UK's price-based approach to regulation allows network companies to increase their charges by the retail price index minus an efficiency factor—a formula known as RPI-X. Whilst it has been argued in the past that this should act as a driver of innovation, it only does so if the aim of this innovation is to increase the efficiency of current network operation. As a result, innovation which would facilitate significant changes to the architecture and operation of networks has not been encouraged.

21.  In principle, the basic mechanisms of price-based regulation can be modified to promote innovation by including incentives for network operators to invest in research, development and demonstration (R,D&D). Mechanisms such as the Innovation Funding Incentive (IFI) and Registered Power Zones (RPZs) which were introduced in the UK a few years ago are designed to achieve this. These mechanisms were designed to allow distribution network companies to recover some of the costs of R,D&D investment from their customer base. However, these schemes have only had limited success.[126] The reason for this poor outcome is that the innovative capacity within network companies started from a very low base. Furthermore, the incentives from RPZ and IFI were tightly drawn and were not strong enough in many cases. If they are to succeed in future, these instruments need to be more long-term, they should include generators (not just network companies), and they should encourage cooperation between market participants.

  22.  Smart grid concepts, as pursued for example by the European Technology Platform on SmartGrids, covers a broad of technologies including network technologies, control systems, generation technologies, smart meters and storage. An electricity system with a higher share of intermittent and distributed generation will inevitably require an increasing level of operational flexibility on the generation side, including small-scale plants. It will also require consumers to adapt to these generation patterns to some extent—either actively (eg by changing their usage patterns) or passively (eg by allowing some appliances to be switched on and off remotely by their electricity supplier). Smart grids can help reduce the additional system costs a changing generation pattern entails and can increase the level of intermittent and distributed generation the system can absorb.

  23.  This vision of smart grids is a broad one, and involves considering how a transformation can be achieved within the overall electricity system. With this in mind, it is clear that the regulatory approach to network innovation in the UK is far from adequate. Other measures are required to encourage much more ambitious levels of innovation and the deployment of smarter grids as and when they are required. Direct funding for R,D&D outside the incentive regulation framework will be needed to complement the recent increases in public R,D&D funding for individual low carbon technologies. For example, public funding could help to support a series of smart grid experiments which include a variety of decentralised energy sources and new grid technologies. Some of these might integrate charging stations for electric vehicles or sophisticated control systems that are designed to turn domestic appliances on and off to help balance the system. Such experiments would facilitate learning about what works, and would help to inform future policies designed to implement smart grids more widely.

  24.  A final important observation on this question is that the current electricity system can accommodate a higher share of new generators and innovative technologies than it does at the moment. Although smart grid technologies will become important to increase the share of intermittent and distributed generation in future, their promise should not distract attention from what can be done already without them.

Is there sufficient investment in R&D and innovation for transmission and distribution technologies?

  25.  There is clear evidence that electricity market liberalisation in general and RPI-X price-based regulation in particular have led to a significant decline in R&D and innovation. While it is difficult to judge what counts as a sufficient level of R&D and innovation, this trend needs to be reversed to provide the necessary electricity network technologies to support a rapid expansion of renewables. In principle, there can be an R&D level that is too high and inefficient. However, given the potential and demand for innovations in the electricity system, it can be argued that the regulatory framework should err on the side of innovation, which may partly happen at the expense of efficiency in the short-term. As stated above, a key priority within this should be to fund the demonstration of new electricity system concepts which combine new network technologies with those for generation, demand management and so on.

What can the UK learn from the experience of other countries' management of their electricity networks?

26.  In terms of developing and adapting the incentive regulation framework for electricity networks to new objectives, the UK has gone much further than many other countries. However, this leadership in developing and adapting the RPI-X framework does not mean that the UK cannot learn from the different approaches followed by other countries. In some cases, other countries have developed more effective ways of managing their networks in new and innovative ways.

27.  A prominent example is Denmark, a country that is very advanced in the deployment of distributed generation (DG) sources and network development. Incentive regulation only plays a minor role in this process. For example, a key instrument in Denmark to deal with the costs of connecting distributed renewable energy and combined heat and power (CHP) plants has been a mechanism to share the network costs. These network costs are not borne by the individual network company that connects DG to its network, but companies get reimbursed for these costs and the costs are then distributed among all consumers via the network companies. Distributed generation is not seen as a property of an individual distribution network, but rather as a property of the system as a whole, driven by national policy targets. From this point of view it would seem inappropriate to preserve or increase the efficiency of an individual network by not connecting DG to that specific network. Socialisation of network costs goes a long way to explain why—unlike in the UK—the network costs of DG have not been a major issue in Denmark.

  28.  Another example of a mechanism outside the incentive regulation framework, is the governance of network R&D in Denmark. Within the regulation of network tariffs in Denmark, there are no regulatory instruments that are specifically geared towards promoting innovation. However, there is a separate funding mechanism for R&D based on a public service obligation. Through a fund generated by this obligation, the system operator (energinet.dk) can run strategic RD&D projects on a system level, together with the distribution companies. One example is the cell projects that aim to decentralise network control to individual parts of the electricity network. Another is the more pervasive Ecogrid project which aims to develop ways to increase the deployment of renewable energy in Denmark without entailing a knock-on increase in Denmark's reliance on neighbouring countries' electricity systems to balance variations in supply and demand.

  29.  The need to initiate pilot projects to explore future system architectures has also been recognised in Germany, where the eEnergy programme has just been launched by the government.[127] This provides direct funding to companies for smart grid pilot projects where individual technologies are combined to test new system solutions.

  30.  A final important lesson should be learned from other countries such as Denmark, Spain or Germany with higher shares of renewables and CHP in their electricity systems. Their experience shows that while networks are important, it is at least as important to provide an effective overall framework of economic incentives for these types of generation to be built in the first place. Getting the right incentives for electricity network development to facilitate this is only part of the story.

March 2009







117   Foresight (2008). Powering Our Lives: Sustainable Energy Management and the Built Environment. London, Government Office for Science. Back

118   Ofgem (2008). Transmission Access Review: Final Report. London, Ofgem. Back

119   Ault, G, D Frame, et al. (2008). Electricity Network Scenarios for Great Britain in 2050. Final Report for Ofgem's LENS Project. London, Ofgem. Back

120   Electricity Networks Strategy Group (2009). Our Electricity Transmission Network: A Vision for 2020. London, ENSG. Back

121   Baker, P (2008). Developing a transmission access regime to deliver the UK's renewable targets. BIEE Academic Conference, Oxford. September. Back

122   Department of Trade and Industry (2002). Future Offshore. London, DTI. Back

123   Electricity Networks Strategy Group (2009). Our Electricity Transmission Network: A Vision for 2020. London, ENSG. Back

124   Ault, G, D Frame, et al. (2008). Electricity Network Scenarios for Great Britain in 2050. Final Report for Ofgem's LENS Project. London, Ofgem. Back

125   See for example, Bowen, A, S Fankhauser, et al. (2009). An outline of the case for a "green" stimulus. London, LSE. Back

126   See for example, Woodman, B and P Baker (2008). Regulatory Frameworks for Decentralised Energy. Energy Policy 36(12): 4527-4531. Back

127   See www.e-energie.info. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2010
Prepared 23 February 2010