The role of carbon markets in preventing dangerous climate change - Environmental Audit Committee Contents


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 28-48)

MR LARRY LOHMANN, MR OSCAR REYES AND MR TIM JONES

31 MARCH 2009

  Q28  Chairman: Good morning. I think you have heard the preceding exchanges. We are quite tight for time, we have got about 30 minutes or so, so we will try and do as much as we can in that period. I know that two of you are calling for the Government to withdraw from the international carbon markets. How practical is that? If we wanted to come out of the EU ETS for example, what would be the obstacles for doing so?

  Mr Reyes: To take the EU ETS as a starting point, obviously what we have at the moment is the Directive that went through in December. There are still various negotiations on-going with that in relation to comitology and review processes that we can feed into. To actually withdraw, there would need to be a reassertion of that debate. There are other ways in which the UK could take leadership, particularly in terms of not encouraging the further expansion of the carbon markets in relation to international processes. That would have the de facto effect of requiring a revision of existing policy at EU level. At the moment I would say that the focus should be on the Copenhagen negotiations on the international framework within which the EU ETS sits, and that will be the means by which you will stimulate a re-opening of that debate.

  Mr Lohmann: I guess I would add I do not see any obstacles to the UK showing leadership by unilaterally saying it will not use the linking Directive to accept offset credits to fulfil its obligations. I do not think there is any obstacle to doing that immediately. I think that would be a good start and it would set a pattern of leadership which would have reverberations worldwide.

  Q29  Chairman: What would then replace the trading scheme?

  Mr Lohmann: A few weeks ago Adair Turner made a statement which amused me. He said something like few would shed a tear if suddenly the collateralised debt obligation squared disappeared from the face of the earth. I think we need to look at the carbon markets in the same light. Do we need a replacement for collateralised debt obligation squared? No, we need to get rid of them, and the same could be said of the carbon market. We need to get rid of the carbon market. In the last session we have heard people talk about how regulation is indispensable and how standard-setting for specific projects is indispensable. What was not stressed so much in the last session perhaps was the fact that carbon trading interferes with many of these measures. That was stressed to a certain degree but I think not enough. I think we need to step back from the question of what would replace the carbon market and say why is the carbon market failing and what sort of measures is it interfering with and what sort of measures would have a chance of success?

  Q30  Chairman: Tell us what sort of measures would have a chance of success?

  Mr Lohmann: We have heard already that regulation has a proven record of success in these matters in fostering innovation. Britain is full of all sorts of positive initiatives, proposals and detailed plans for transition to a zero carbon economy. We have people like Roger Levitt and we have Zero Carbon Britain. What we lack is support for these resources and plans that are already there for restructuring the way energy is produced, for even restructuring the way communities operate and think about their power, for restructuring transport. There is no lack. We could stack up the documentation to the ceiling here for the initiatives that are there that would work.

  Q31  Chairman: I am asking you what the policies are to introduce those. There are plenty of plans but they not being implemented. You say that the carbon markets will not help them so what will help them?

  Mr Lohmann: We need policies to support resources and plans that are already there.

  Q32  Chairman: Regulation?

  Mr Lohmann: Regulation, support for already existing community initiatives. We are all aware of things like the Transition Towns and instead of interfering with these initiatives, governments should be supporting them. One of the prerequisites for talking about what has to be done is to find out the things that are already being done that are working, instead of concentrating on the ideologically motivated idea that the markets are going to solve all of these problems automatically without us paying attention to what knowledge already exists in society.

  Q33  Chairman: Is there a role for carbon taxes in this process?

  Mr Lohmann: Yes, there is a role for carbon taxes, but what I would add to the discussion in the previous session is, like carbon trading, carbon tax is a price mechanism and there are certain limitations to price mechanisms when you are talking about the kind of fundamental transitions that climate change demands. There is a problem here which I like to call the "Goldilocks" problem. I would say it is an ideology that somewhere out there, there are prices which are not too low and not too high, but they are just right. In other words, they are not so low that they would not allow any change to take place, but they are not so high that they would bankrupt so many companies and bankrupt society and which would be so disruptive that they would disrupt society. The idea of the carbon market is that there exists this ideal Goldilocks set of prices but, in fact, if we reflect just a moment, we realise that that is not true. It depends on the context of existing research and development. For example, is there existing development of other forms of energy production that do not rely on carbon? If those have not been developed previously then introducing a carbon tax by itself is not going to solve the problem, because you have an incentive to switch to something else but when you look around there is nothing else to switch to. Carbon tax is useful once it is placed in that context but what we are lacking now is the context of concerted investment in restructuring the way energy is produced and the way transport is organised and so on.

  Q34  Colin Challen: Is it your view that the ETS cap-and-trade scheme should not be part of the suite of policy approaches to climate change or do you think that the ETS poisons the other policy approaches?

  Mr Lohmann: So far I think the record is, yes, it has poisoned other policy approaches. It is quite clear from both UK and EU policy that carbon trading is actually interfering with restructuring the way that energy is produced. The UK Government has been quite explicit that one of their reasons for reluctance in more support for renewables is that they are worried that it will interfere with the carbon market, with the carbon price. Article 26 of the EU legislation (and I forget the name) requires that shifts in energy production be the most efficient. What do they mean by efficient? Well, given carbon trading, what efficient means is that you can be efficient by going abroad and finding rather bogus or fraudulent offset credits in order to claim that your operations are more efficient. If that is the way trading is working, obviously it is poison for an attempt at a fundamental technological shift. It is poison in other ways as well, including the dangers of a bubble, the dangers of a crash, the dangers of the financialisation of the carbon market, but maybe we can get to that later.

  Q35  Colin Challen: This efficiency philosophy underpins this whole approach. Is it the philosophy that you find wrong-headed or merely the application of it?

  Mr Lohmann: There is nothing wrong with the idea of efficiency, but what the word efficiency does in the context of a carbon market is it sets up an incentive for all the players to use their maximum ingenuity in order to find gimmicks to say that they are efficient. They find efficiencies by making one thing equivalent to another, by telling us that it is the same thing whether we stop the third runway at Heathrow or we stop Kingsnorth, and that is the same thing as planting trees in some country abroad or setting up a wind farm somewhere else. This is supposedly efficiency because those things are made into the same thing and so you can say since they are the same, let us choose the cheapest one. The problem is you have to step back and ask are these things actually the same or not. No, they are not, but the use of the word efficiency encourages us to believe that they are. I would say there is nothing wrong with the word efficiency by itself, but as it is used in the creation of this new market and all of these new equivalencies which are not equivalent, then it becomes a problem and the word efficiency starts to justify all sorts of regressive and counter-productive measures.

  Q36  Dr Turner: Talking of uncertain offshore credits, I would like to hear your views on the Clean Development Mechanism and what contribution you feel it makes to either tackling climate change or promoting sustainable development around the world?

  Mr Jones: In terms of tackling climate change, it makes a negative impact because it gives us an excuse to carry on with projects like Kingsnorth in the UK whilst funding things which do nothing to cut emissions. We know about the issue of additionality with CDM credits. I have heard a European Commission spokesperson publicly saying that 40% of CDM credits are not additional and there are other estimates which push it much higher to 75%, so 75% of these projects would probably not happen anyway.[28] It is a negative impact in tackling climate change because of the excuse it then gives us in the rich world to keep on emitting. In terms of sustainable development, the whole thing is structured around providing cheap ways of getting carbon credits for northern companies, so it is not rooted in trying to look at how do we allow sustainable development and a low-carbon economy to happen in developing countries. It needs a complete mind-set shift. The key way we need to do this is to de-link what we are doing to help develop low-carbon development from targets in the north. We have to accept that in the UK and in the EU we have to radically decarbonise our economies as quickly as possible. That is one challenge. The separate challenge is how we support low-carbon development in the south. As long as you link the two then you will have this incentive to just look for the cheap ways of generating credits to meet our own targets. Any effort to reform the CDM needs to look and say we need to completely de-link it from northern targets and then look at how can we promote low-carbon development in the Global South.

  Mr Lohmann: I agree with Tim. My only addition would be that it is not only that the CDM is interfering with climate progress here in the North and also with sustainable development problems in the South, it is also that the CDM, in practice, as I have seen from visiting some of these projects myself, is actually interfering with climate progress in the south as well. Two easy examples just from India which I have visited. There is a huge complex of sponge iron factories in Chhattisgarh state. These are hugely polluting, coal-fired, water-abstracting plants and yet they are deriving extra funding from the CDM. You ask the question how is this helping India turn toward a green development pathway? It is not, it is actually propping up the same companies that have to be the targets for change in the global South. Another project I visited with some colleagues was a hydroelectric dam project where again the hydroelectric dam project is receiving funding from the CDM which is helping these projects continue, yet the projects themselves are actually, in fact, destroying a lot of the low-carbon practices, a lot of the knowledge of low-carbon agriculture which is being used in the local area, because it is incompatible with the irrigation system which the villagers have developed there, and are continuing to develop, which does not use fossil fuels, yet the dams are actually destroying the system and probably will be displacing the villagers. Again, you have to ask, is this helping India preserve what it already knows about a low-carbon way of living, way of livelihood, way of providing jobs, or is it interfering with that and the answer has to be it is interfering with that.

  Q37  Dr Turner: I think what you are telling us is that as a mechanism the CDM is pretty much discredited. One of the things which have certainly contributed towards that is the HFC replacement projects under the CDM. We have heard that UNFCCC might decide to take those out of the Clean Development Mechanism. Do you know what the latest position on that is?

  Mr Jones: I am not sure any of us know the latest position. The one thing I would add is HFC projects are clearly the most outstandingly bad of the CDM projects in terms of helping cut emissions. It does not mean that other kinds of projects are okay, all kinds of projects, whether around N2O, renewables, hydro, coal powered stations, have additionality problems and all the problems which are not exclusive to HFC. Getting rid of HFC projects, even if it did happen, would not tackle the problems of the CDM.

  Q38  Dr Turner: The CDM forms part of the policy portfolio of both DfID and DECC. Do you see any evidence that they are working together on this? To what extent do you think UK policy on emissions trading and reduction is dependent on the CDM process, after all a certain percentage of our climate reduction targets under the Climate Change Act is anticipated being achieved offshore, ie mainly in CDM projects? As far as DfID is concerned, how does this mesh with proper sustainable development? You have given us one outstanding example of how it is anti-sustainable development. How do you see these problems?

  Mr Reyes: The other player is BERR here and to date, as far as I am aware, it is DfID and BERR who have had the major stake in setting out the relationship with CDM.

  Mr Jones: On the UK position, we know that because of the huge number of CDM credits in the ETS, 50% plus, and the fact that the Climate Change Act allows for meeting our targets through the ETS, we are set to be meeting our targets primarily through offsetting. The Committee on Climate Change did not help clarify the situation totally because they argued strongly that CDM credits should be very limited, but also did not differentiate between how the ETS is full of CDM credits in the advice they gave us at the start of December before the directive midway through December. We are mad. We are absolutely mad because we have set up what we think is this grand target of 80% by 2050 and maybe something like 40% by 2020 and huge amounts of it are going to happen through paying for dodgy offsets. The Government is using this to justify allowing a third runway at Heathrow in particular, but also the worry is they are going to use it to justify new unabated coal power.

  Mr Reyes: There are various other problems of counting this in this regard to which are not just about the CDM, but are also about what happens domestically within Europe in relation to effort sharing, for example, which is further allowing industry to buy credits, in this case from Eastern Europe, and treat those as equivalent to emissions reductions in the UK. The point we would make is reductions need to be domestic reductions to see that we are actually reducing something and not simply buying in credits from elsewhere as a replacement for that.

  Q39  Dr Turner: We want to encourage climate change mitigation in developing countries anyway. Clearly, as it stands, the CDM is not fit for purpose as far as that is concerned. Can you see any policy mechanisms which will achieve that?

  Mr Jones: The point was made earlier. First of all we need to de-link this from having ways to meet UK targets. You have got to look at it purely as a problem of how you help low-carbon development in the global south. One key thing which does not happen with the CDM is getting the buy-in from local communities, for local communities to want projects, to give their consent to projects and to benefit from those projects. What you will find if that happens is that would increase some of the economic cost of it. One of the reasons credits are so cheap in the global south is because CDM projects do not have to get the buy-in from local communities. To get local communities agreeing to projects and benefiting from them would be a key requirement which will involve more resources and more technology being made available. At the moment we are so far away from getting into the detail of this because the position of the UK and the EU within the global negotiations is still very much focused on offsetting, and when they are talking about additional funds they are talking about channelling them through the World Bank. A key thing that developing countries are saying is these funds cannot go through the World Bank because that is an institution which is governed by the rich world, it needs to go through an institution under the UNFCCC. There needs to be that accountability to developing countries' governments, but then in terms of programmes on the ground it needs to be accountable to local people. What we need to see in the negotiations is far more understanding on the part of the EU and other rich countries of justice, that they are still entering these negotiations in a world view of, "Well, we're just going to try and get as much out of it as we can", rather than humbly saying, "We're the ones who have caused this problem, we're going to work with you to help tackle it". At the moment there is far too much of the EU going in and grandstanding developing countries and insisting on things and ignoring the proposals that are coming from developing countries.

  Mr Lohmann: I think traditionally one of the problems with bilateral development agencies or organisations such as DfID is they tend, in a way—to overstate it a little bit—to become appendages to export industries. I mean that very broadly, not only exported technologies but export of our expertise that we are still very proud of having developed and so forth. One of the problems with linking development to the CDM is it makes this problem much worse than it was to begin with because of the huge sums of money involved, the connections with local rich polluting companies in the South that come into the equation, and so forth. In answer to the question of what can we do to support green development paths, which already exist in many southern countries—again, as in Britain, a lot of the resources for a turnaround of the way energy is organised, the way transport is organised and so forth, they already exist in the South—in order to tackle this, in DfID and other organisations, for one thing this has to be disentangled from the thing called "the carbon market". Tim was saying, that is a first step, a basic step. Also, it has to be recognised that there is a lot of research to be done on our part in the Northern countries, the industrialised countries, to try to find out what resources exist in the South, not only will that benefit Southern countries in their turn towards a green development path but would benefit us in learning to benefit our own technologies and so forth. This research is not taking place, especially with the carbon market, because of the incentive to find offset credits so that we can continue business as usual. But there is also a more traditional problem here. There is also a traditional bias in organisations like DfID. They are tied too much into the mentality and the practices of, "Let's make some money out of this for Britain."

  Q40  Joan Walley: You are painting a very depressing picture. I think what you have said and in the evidence you have given you have pointed to some of the weaknesses in the whole CDM structure and how you define additionality and all these kinds of things. Do you think there is anything that could be done to improve oversight and regulation of the Clean Development Mechanism and, if so, what should that be?

  Mr Reyes: I have a Uruguayan colleague who was asked, "How do you improve the Clean Development Mechanism?", and she said it is like being asked, "What is the best way to kill my mother?" and her answer was, "I don't want to kill my mother, I don't want you to kill her". I think it is a bit of a similar question from our point of view in relation to the Clean Development Mechanism. There are various proposals for how it could be differently regulated and improved which have differential implications, some of which are quite technical in relation, for example, to banking or price floors and so on. What these do not do is address what some of the fundamental problems are with the mechanism, in particular, like any carbon trading, it is abstracting from how and where particular changes are made. It is reducing those kinds of changes to price incentives, then adding on a series of other problems in relation to additionality criteria. The forms that are being proposed in terms of regulation are not getting to the root of what the problems are with the offset mechanisms and particularly how those would interrelate with emissions trading.

  Mr Jones: You can set up debates about reform or abolish in terms of saying there is a need for some kind of resources or maybe technology transfer to the global south to help in low-carbon development, but that is so far removed from how the CDM is set up at the moment that I do not think it makes much sense talking about tweaking with the CDM. It would be a lot more sensible to get rid of the thing. We could talk about a more positive vision, and unfortunately it comes across as negative because we are stuck in a world with these really bad things, but there are visions out there of a more positive way of doing this, but you need to get rid of the bad stuff first before you can move on to the good stuff.

  Q41  Joan Walley: Moving on to what could be the good stuff. We had evidence in our last inquiry about where you could get money directed to smaller local community initiatives of one kind or another instead of the traditional way of using the CDM. Could you see that as something which could be developed?

  Mr Lohmann: It could be developed independently of the CDM. Obviously from a climate point of view you do not want any kind of project, no matter how good, if it is being used to produce carbon credits for us to slow down our progress, that is a very negative thing. As Tim was saying, the problem is not so much money but, yes, money is needed for support of a lot of locally responsible initiatives. These will not be projects that will necessarily make money for the export industry here and they will not at all be projects which are going to provide us with carbon credits to continue business as usual. That is quite a difficult challenge, but I do not see anything negative about it, I see that as a refreshing way of re-orienting our mindset to what really matters. There is a lot of will out there. One of the problems with "foreign aid" as it is conceived now is a lot of people in the public at large think it already is helping people to achieve their own low-carbon, environmentally-responsible, provision-of-livelihood sort of projects, whereas the rule is that it is not. That does not mean it cannot be and by acknowledging what has to be done I think is a positive step.

  Q42  Joan Walley: How would you set out to achieve doing that so that money could go to these smaller community projects in that kind of way and changing the whole system really? How would you move towards doing that?

  Mr Lohmann: An indispensable first step which has never been taken is serious research in hundreds and thousands of localities to find out what is going on there, what progress has already been made, what the problems are and so forth, to find out from the local perspective, as Tim was mentioning.

  Q43  Joan Walley: Who would co-ordinate that research?

  Mr Lohmann: I think the Government would be a very good candidate to help provide support for researchers to undertake that kind of project.

  Mr Reyes: I would say two additional things. One is in terms of the current money framework. We have made the point that it is problematic to link this money coming to projects to prevention or emissions reductions here effectively as a sort of structural link. The other thing is one of the things carbon trading does is that it tends to encourage the financialisation of a lot of problems which are not simply financial. One example of this is I just got back from Costa Rica where they are pushing to become a carbon neutral country effectively. What that means in practice is a lot of money is going to pineapple plantations for an export industry, it is based on an export-led development model, and the carbon neutral label there is being used as an additional selling point. That, in turn, is undermining the food sovereignty of communities there and it is also having a damaging effect on forests, as many monocultural plantations do. At the same time, we also visited a reforestation project that had been ongoing for 25 years which was not able to access such funds, yet this was someone who was doing reforestation in a proper way, which involved seed gathering and whatever. What they said was these large-scale structures of economic incentives at international level were preventing the kind of project work they wanted to do because, in effect, they were feeding the wrong kind of development model for the kind of work they were trying to do at community level. I would be wary of putting the problem in terms of simply large financial transfers.

  Q44  Chairman: Is not your view that the CDM is so irredeemably flawed that the European Commission idea of having credits which are based on whole sectors rather than individual projects is not worth exploring?

  Mr Reyes: It is radically unclear what is being proposed by the EU. Even IETA, the International Emissions Trading Association, said is this action that is being proposed another form of offset, in which case it runs into all of the same problems and further ones in terms of the fact that instead of having an additionality criteria you now give to the industry a role to set its own standards and then talk about those efficiency standards as equivalent to emissions reduction, when clearly it is not. It could mean in expanding the carbon markets in that way from a project-based or sectoral-based approach, you could compound the problem. I think what is being proposed at the moment is really unclear. There can also be various kinds of perverse incentives which come into that to not regulate. We have seen in the carbon markets they can often have perverse incentives to not regulate and they are not stimulating public investment. I think we would put the emphasis on not running these things through a market-based approach. Insofar as you are talking about sectors—and there is also talk in the international negotiations about sectoral approaches that are not related to markets—they should not be running it through markets, they should be talking about what is the kind of investment, what are the kinds of international standards that are needed and can we ensure those are strict. I would say that would be a better framing for approaching sectoral problems rather than running it through the carbon market and then having all those additional problems of how that links into existing market structures, how that makes things fungible equivalent, which we are already seeing as a problem with the carbon market space.

  Q45  Colin Challen: First of all, I would like to ask about REDD. In Copenhagen this year it may well be that forestry comes into the flexible mechanism structure somehow. What impact do you think that might have on markets if it were to be the case that we have forestry credits coming in from that?

  Mr Lohmann: In my view it would be a disaster. It would compound all of the problems we already see with standard offset projects through the CDM with a whole new set of conflicts, a whole new set of fraudulent procedures for accounting, a whole new power politics, in effect. What we are talking about is basically using enormous land areas which people are already living on, using, deriving their livelihoods from, and saying, okay, the carbon in this area is going to belong to the industrialised countries. What that entails in terms of legal measures and enforcement measures is very frightening, especially when you look at the precedent of previous global schemes for supposedly solving the forest problem through market means, such as the Tropical Forestry Action Plan of the 1980s and early 1990s. You can see the precedent for disaster is enormous, especially given the huge sums of money that are involved. A lot of this stems basically from a very fundamental misconception, the idea that biotic carbon is somehow going to give us a free licence to continue the use of fossil fuels. There is not going to be enough biotic carbon in the world to make up for even a fraction of the fossil fuels which remain to be mined underground. The solution is to keep the fossil fuels underground, not to try to find millions and millions of hectares of land which people are already using for a multitude of other purposes and then turn it into a carbon preservation machine using often draconian methods of enforcement and economically insensitive ways of ensuring carbon rights.

  Mr Reyes: I have two additions. In relation to how the market works, one of the problems we have with the carbon market is that in a sense the cap is a bit of a misnomer because what we have seen in relation to offset is that all of these mechanisms are coming in to loosen what is a cap. Instead of having tight regulations on emissions, carbon markets are effectively offering a series of loopholes and gaps whereby things can appear to be reductions which are not, in fact, reductions. REDD just exacerbates that problem on a massive scale, basically, if you were to link the forest carbon credits which would be generated by REDD to the mainstream of the carbon market. One of the other dangers with REDD schemes in financialising forests and the carbon store within them is that it can exacerbate land concentration and land conflicts, which is similar to the example I gave before. A much better approach would be to grant proper tenure rights and land rights to people, forest dependant communities, indigenous communities there, rather than seeking to run REDD schemes which, from what we see at the moment, look likely to benefit the main drivers of deforestation, the companies and industries that have been involved in that, whether it is the pulp and paper industry or other extractive industries in forest areas which are what actually have really been driving deforestation.

  Q46  Colin Challen: From the evidence from all three of you I feel what we are talking about here in the cap and trade system is something akin to the Emperor's clothes, that we can only think we are dressed if we simply have confidence in the idea, then somebody just points it out there is no reason why we should have that confidence, which is similar, perhaps, to the way the financial markets work. We are now told that is all based on confidence and if people believe it is going to work, then it generally works. With the collapse of the markets and the economic crisis we face, do you think there are any lessons that people who are wedded to cap and trade should learn from the way we have gone into this economic crisis, notwithstanding your objections in principle to cap and trade?

  Mr Lohmann: I think in economic terms—never mind the climate—there are a lot of lessons to be learned from the financial crash. What we have seen with the financial crash, supposedly to provide liquidity, is there has been the development of a lot of speculative new financial instruments so that people can take the opposite side of all possible transactions. These instruments were quickly developed in a way in which, again, were creating equivalences which were not real, making predictions that could not be made about the future of price volatility, and so forth. Everything was riding on these new products whose value was bogus, could not be determined, and nobody even knows where they are now. The carbon market is a very similar thing, in particular with things like CDM credits and offset credits where the supposed valuation is created by the private consultants who come up with these additionality equations and write hundreds of documents with complicated Greek letters and equations in them to show how much carbon is being saved. We have already seen the controversies this is raising even at this stage of the carbon market. If these instruments are allowed to develop further and if, as some people think, the carbon market becomes the next biggest market in the world after the derivatives market, then I think the economic dangers are really severe. Just last week there was a hearing in the US Congress on what they are calling "sub-prime carbon". I have got the report here, which is very enlightening and I would recommend it to you. It is not talking so much about the climate issues, it is talking about the problems of sub-prime carbon developing in a way which could undermine the whole financial system once again just when we have got through with learning a lesson about these improperly valued derivatives.

  Q47  Colin Challen: You mentioned the equations, and I have seen one or two in CDM applications, it is the technical bit I do not understand. Are you saying they are absolutely refutable, you could find somebody else who would question the actual carbon which allegedly is being saved simply by unpicking those equations, is that your assertion?

  Mr Lohmann: That happens all the time. If you hire one consultant to give you an assessment of how much carbon is being saved by one project, you will get a different assessment from what you get if you hire another consultant. It is very much smoke and mirrors, just in the way the financial derivatives market was smoke and mirrors, a lot of fancy equations but when it came down to it they were not based on intellectually respectable premises. We have seen this before and we should not make the same mistake again.

  Mr Reyes: In the case of offsets, what it is trying to do is take an unknowable future scenario and reduce that to a certainty, which you need to do in order to create some kind of tradable commodity effectively. Also, in relation to your earlier question, this would be one of the fundamental problems that, in effect, even now we are hearing, "The carbon market is very volatile, what should we do?", well, we should increase liquidity and make a global carbon market, which seems to run in the contradictory direction from what we have seen as being the problems in the financial crisis. What is underlying the problems with the carbon market and the reason why it is volatile is not to do with a lack of liquidity in the market, but to do with the fact that it is underlain by a fundamentally unstable commodity. Carbon is not carbon, it is a series of contentious equivalents between different kinds of gases and very different kinds of projects. That is both true in terms of what effect that has in terms of the market but also has very serious environmental implications because the market will see as the same a tonne of carbon—a tonne of carbon is a tonne of carbon is a tonne of carbon—what we are saying is the environmental impact of these very different processes of whether you are having a "sink" project in one place or a hydroelectric dam in another or a coal powered station are very different environmentally. What we need to do is remove this architecture from the picture and say we need to concentrate on the tried and tested methods of regulations, standards and price incentives.

  Q48  Chairman: The impact of some of the fiscal measures can be called into question. Perhaps you can have a cap without the trade, maybe that is what we should be talking about. If you take, for example, tax, like airport passenger duty, which may or may not be a green tax—I cannot quite decide that point—if the Treasury says that it saves so much carbon, surely that kind of analysis is just as ropy, you could argue, as any analysis that underpins the ETS and you start unpicking the whole question of the impact of CO2 in the climate change context. Surely if you start unpicking all of this you could always find another group of people who will question your particular equation.

  Mr Jones: Which is why you need to get out of the mindset of thinking of one silver bullet solution to tackle climate change, so this is the one policy, whether it is trading or a tax. You have to have a vision of where we are going to go, which is to stop taking fossil fuels out of the ground, and how to get there is going to be a range of policies. On aviation, you are going to probably need some kind of price to reduce demand, but you are also going to need to halt the infrastructure, so to stop new runways from being built. You need various policies in different sectors, so get out of the mindset of, "We want one way of tackling climate change and this is it", which is the problem, and seeing that we need a whole load of different solutions depending on the situation.

  Chairman: I think we had better call it a day there. Thank you very much indeed for coming in.





28   Note by Witness: The witness meant to say that 75% of these projects would probably be happening, not would not. Back


 
previous page contents

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2010
Prepared 8 February 2010