The role of carbon markets in preventing dangerous climate change - Environmental Audit Committee Contents


Memorandum submitted by the Engineering Employers' Federation (EEF)

ABOUT EEF

  With over 6,000 business members from the manufacturing community (employing approximately one million employees) and more than 20,000 associate companies, EEF is dedicated to fostering enterprise and evolution across manufacturing to keep industry competitive, dynamic and future focused.

As the only membership organisation dedicated entirely to manufacturing, we are an established UK leader in the delivery of business services, government representation and industry intelligence.

Commercially driven and re-investing profits for the benefit of industry and members, EEF's trusted influence means that manufacturing companies are particularly receptive to the advice and service offerings of carefully-selected partners with whom we choose to work.

  Our network of offices in England and Wales keeps us close to our members, allowing us to focus on local issues and thereby to function as a unique community. Our London office provides a focal point for development of our broad portfolio of business services designed to deliver maximum value. From London, EEF provides first-class representation with government and regulatory bodies and supports our local offices in their programmes to influence regional policy. Our structure places us at the heart of the UK business community.

  EEF's broad service portfolio is delivered by an unparalleled team of experts including 30 economists and policy specialists, 90 HR and legal advisers, 150 health, safety and environment advisors, 20 occupational health specialists and around 200 trainers, based in our regional offices and in centres of excellence nationwide.

  UK Steel, a division of EEF, is the sectoral trade association for the steel industry. All the country's steelmakers are in membership, as well as many downstream steel processors.

OVERVIEW

Potential contribution of international emissions trading to delivering a global greenhouse gas stabilisation target, consistent with the UK's goal of limiting global warming to 2°C

  1.  Emissions trading schemes, in various forms, have emerged as one of the main tools for governments, around the World, in delivering Greenhouse Gas (GHG) emissions reductions. Trading schemes in general, deliver certainty, by way of the cap, and can address reductions where most readily available at least cost.

2.  As carbon dioxide (CO2) is a global gas and global climate change is a global problem, it is certain that any possible solution must also require global action. EEF believes that the most effective, transparent and long-term solution is a global cap on emissions, delivered through a cap and trade scheme, which would place all participants on an equal footing. This does not mean setting the same target across all countries, but the scheme should seek to deliver a "level playing field" that fully addresses the critical issue of "carbon leakage". A level price for carbon should exist across all linked schemes (the current price for allowances within the RGGI scheme is $3.38, with EUA trading at

9.50).

3.  EEF does believe that there are potentially equally effective methods of reducing global emissions than just a cap and trade scheme, such as a carbon tax.

  4.  A truly global agreement will enable GHG emissions reductions to be made at least cost, but only if all participating countries are able to invest in other parts of the World.

Whether, and under what circumstances, emissions trading ought to be supplemented or replaced by tax or regulation

  5.  Emissions trading is only one of several possible instruments for reducing global GHG emissions. It works well for sectors that are not subject to international competition, such as power generation. For other sectors it works best when all major emitters in the world are included. However, emissions trading does provide a credible means for delivering, through the imposition of a cap, a predictable outcome, and within Europe remains a more politically achievable solution than alternative measures.

6.  That said, this should not rule out other instruments, such as tax, standards or regulation, particularly for downstream sectors. Indeed, Copenhagen does give international negotiators the opportunity to reassess if trading through cap and trade schemes is the most effective method of achieving the goal of limiting a global temperature increase to 2°C. Copenhagen does provide the last chance for governments to consider the merits of a carbon tax.

  7.  EEF has previously opposed such a tax, favouring a cap and trade scheme in the UK, as the simplest way of reducing emissions from industry. However, with hindsight, we have seen cap and trade schemes become over complex, over crowded and over lapping, as is the rest of the climate change policy area. Regional cap and trade schemes also fail adequately to address carbon leakage, and to account for embedded emissions at borders for both imports and exports.

  8.  A carbon tax regime across the whole economy would truly account for all embedded carbon throughout supply chains and could be administered effectively at the border. This would enable consumers to take informed decisions when purchasing goods and services, giving businesses that provide low-carbon solutions to gain a competitive advantage in the market. Such initiative will also allow consumers to make choices relating to materials.

  9.  A carbon tax would provide long-term certainty for participants in making low-carbon investments and encourage the funding of emerging technologies.

  10.  Unless all other options and solutions of reducing global GHG are considered in the run up to Copenhagen, then we may well be limiting ourselves to a system (cap and trade) that may not provide the best road to tackling climate change.

  11.  It is however vital that alternative methods such as taxation be seen precisely as that: alternatives, not supplements.

THE EU EMISSIONS TRADING SCHEME

The record of Phase II of the EU ETS, and prospects for the success of Phase III

  12.  It is too early to access whether Phase II of the EU ETS has been successful, as we are only now starting the second year of a five year phase of the scheme. Of course, the ability to bank Phase II allowances into Phase III provides a strong link between the Phases, that was absent in the transition from Phase I to II.

13.  We need to be clear as to what is meant by "success" of the Phase. If the aim of the EU ETS is to reduce carbon emissions within the EU27, then we are virtually guarantied success, as this is dictated by the cap, which will be met, as the price of allowances will be set at the cost of abatement. This issue is further explored below.

Extent to which the carbon price will be sufficient to drive low-carbon investment, in particular decarbonisation of energy

14.  It should be clearly understood that an emissions trading cap and a carbon price, are essentially two separate drivers in reducing emissions. The cap delivers certainty and in terms of the EU ETS will be met, irrespective of the price of EU Allowances (EUA). It is often asserted that a low carbon price will weaken the EU ETS, but it should be remembered that the aim of the Directive is to reduce absolute emissions to a pre-determined level, by an agreed date. A high or low carbon price does not affect this outcome.

15.  If the price of carbon is low, this can only mean one of two things: either that output is lower than predicted, for example as a result of a cyclical downturn or the loss of market share to imports, or that there are more opportunities for cost-effective mitigation than previously envisaged.

  16.  Commentators who assert that the current low carbon price indicates that EU ETS is failing need to take a longer-term perspective. We all share the hope that the current economic downturn is temporary and that industrial production will return to pre-crisis levels in the medium to long term. Carbon emissions will then of course rise, largely in line with production, and many industrial participants will again need to enter into the market to purchase allowances, if EUAs were not banked during this downturn.

  17.  It would be extremely short sighted to consider adjusting the current cap to take into account this temporary reduction in carbon emissions. It should be recognised that this is a long-term exercise and short-term fluctuations between supply for carbon and demand for carbon will take place. However, having set the pathway towards a particular long-term target and in the absence of incontrovertible evidence of a need for further action, then the need to long-term certainty should prevail.

  18.  EEF appreciates the danger that a low "spot price" for carbon, may inhibit future investment in a low-carbon economy. However, we would reiterate that the EU ETS is a market based scheme, aiming to deliver a tangible cap on industrial emissions at least cost. There are other policy instruments currently in place, that also aim to drive low-carbon investment, in particular decarbonisation of energy, such as the Renewables Obligation (capital grants scheme), the Climate Change Act and other parts of the Climate action and renewable energy package, agreed in December 2008.

  19.  Governments can not, and should not, rely on the EU ETS alone to deliver the catalyst to long-term low-carbon investment. EEF has concerns that the keenly anticipated expansion in low-carbon energy generating capacity, most notably from nuclear, that is vital over the next decade, may be derailed by a low carbon price. The Government must ensure that the financial viability of these major schemes is robust and the vagaries of a short-term EUA price fluctuation does not dictate the UK ability to meet its commitments as set out in the Climate Change Act.

  20.  EEF does not believe that creating an artificial floor (or indeed ceiling) price for EUA should be introduced. Artificially influencing the prices of EUA would jeopardise the market based functions of the scheme and could send a signal to participants that further government intervention may be possible. Ironically, this could have the effect of creating uncertainty in the market.

  21.  It is possible that an artificial floor price could actually limit options to link the EU ETS with other trading schemes.

Impacts of economic recession on the workings of the EU ETS

  22.  As the EU ETS is based on absolute targets allocated on an ex-ante basis, it is entirely predictable that if the manufacturing sector is hit by an economic downturn, which results in a drop in output, then carbon emissions from the sector will be reduced significantly, albeit temporarily.

23.  EEF has previously advocated that the scheme should be based on efficiency of plant, rather than absolute targets, and that allocation of allowances should be ex-post, based on actual production levels, and not an estimate based on historical production.

  24.  Both of these proposals would have addressed the perceived carbon price and cap issues that have resulted in the perception that the scheme is not working. For example, if allowances had been subject to ex-post adjustment, it is likely that carbon prices would not have collapsed to the extent seen during the current recession.

Impacts on and responses by UK firms covered by the EU ETS

  25.  The impacts on UK installations covered by the EU ETS are entirely predictable. If the output from a sector falls to 50% in the same month, as a year ago, like we have seen in the UK steel sector, then emissions will fall and many of those installations will be long in allowances and will need to decide whether to trade or bank surplus allowances. In some instances, the decision to sell EUA will be out of necessity to ensure basic survival of that installation,.

26.  Selling surplus allowances in the event of reduced production is perfectly valid & legal within the rules of the scheme, so to is reducing production a valid way to reduce emissions.

Implications of the EU ETS for business competitiveness, and how to address them

  27.  The implications of the EU ETS for business competitiveness are considerable for those sectors that are fully exposed to international competition and are highly carbon intensive. EEF is reasonably satisfied that the agreed EU ETS revised directive text does take account of this.

28.  Of course, issuing 100% free allocation to sectors that are subject to carbon leakage limits the additional unilateral cost to those sectors in complying with the scheme. However, cost increases will still be borne by those sectors, as the free allocation is based on the cap, rather than need.

  29.  EEF does not favour border measures as the preferred route for addressing carbon leakage. Border measures would not address the loss of export competitiveness, and they could only be made compliant with the WTO principle of national treatment by the introduction of an unworkable level of complexity and furthermore could lead to retaliatory measures and could undermine international cooperation to achieve a global emissions reduction target.

  30.  It is therefore imperative that a robust international agreement to reduce global GHG emissions is agreed in Copenhagen in December 2009. Only then can we ensure that all competitors in the market are equally "incentivised" to become more efficient and to pass through the cost of GHG into pricing of products, enabling purchasers to make comparative choices between materials, in the knowledge that they include the global warming impact in the price. This will eliminate the element of competitive distortion from international trade.

  31.  However, the importance of international "sectoral agreements" should not be underestimated. It is acknowledged that a truly international agreement must include a critical mass of high-GHG-emitting countries, if it is to have any hope of succeeding. This is also true of addressing carbon leakage. Only if a critical mass of, for example, steel companies across the globe are included in an agreement, can that sector fully internalise the cost of carbon. This would apply to all globally traded sectors and highlights that geographical agreements alone, may not solve the competitiveness concerns.

Effects of the expansion of the EU ETS to encompass aviation

  32.  Whilst EEF advocates that all parts of the economy should play a part in limiting GHG emissions in order to meet targets set out within both the EU ETS and the Climate Change Act, we have concerns that including aviation into the EU ETS in 2012 could distort the market significantly.

33.  As a matter of record, EEF was opposed to the inclusion of aviation. The sector currently has little abatement potential, other than through reducing the number of flights. If the EU wishes to encourage people to fly less, there are more effective economic measures at its disposal.

  34.  Unless the cap is increased to fully take account of emissions from the aviation sector, then the effect of including the sector in the scheme will be to tighten targets for the remaining installations.

Allocation or auctioning of EU ETS credits, and the use of auctioning revenues

  35.  EEF does not believe that the hypothecation of auction revenues for government business support for carbon mitigation purposes is the most effective way of providing significant, long-term support and certainty of outcome in the aim of reducing UK GHG emissions.

36.  To hypothecate auction receipts is short sighted and would not provide the timely support for industry at times when the support is needed most, namely when auction revenues are low, during an economic downturn. When the economy is buoyant, business is better placed to invest in future mitigation measures and therefore it is expected that the need for direct support to reduce emissions is less crucial. Business support should be assessed on a case by case basis.

  37.  If the UK is to have the ability to develop the technological solutions needed to address climate change, far greater investment in R&D will be required—well beyond the resources of individual companies.

  38.  EEF strongly believes that government should firmly commit to long term, significant support for accelerating the transition of the UK towards a low-carbon economy. UK R&D government funding support is extremely low compared to other Member States and other regions.

  39.  Whilst we accept the setting up of the Environmental Transformation Fund could go some way to addressing this, we have concerns that much of the funding is not focused on UK business, but international projects.

  40.  Committed business support from government, therefore could provide a unique opportunity to assign funding to UK industry that will enable it to become a world leader in climate change mitigation. As we have said, this support does not have to come directly from the money raised through EU ETS auctions, but should come out of the Treasury Consolidated Fund.

  41.  The important question here is whether the government is fully committed to working with UK industry to deliver the low-carbon economy that EEF members are working hard to achieve.

DEVELOPMENT OF A GLOBAL CARBON MARKET

Progress of cap and trade schemes in other countries (notably, the United States), and the prospects for, and practicalities of, linking between them

  42.  Linking of trading schemes will increase liquidity of the EU ETS carbon market in Phase III However, it will only address leakage if those schemes subject sectors to comparable levels of carbon cost internalisation. Moves to link national, sub-federal or regional entities can only be acceptable if there is equivalent scope/coverage and equivalence of effort (eg RGGI where only power stations are caught will could result in artificial market distortions) within all the schemes that propose to be linked.

43.  The development of cap and trade schemes in other countries and states is progressing at a significant pace. Most encouraging of all is the commitment by the new US administration to, "Implement an economy-wide cap-and-trade program to reduce greenhouse gas emissions 80% by 2050" and to "Make the US a Leader on Climate Change".

44.  A step-by-step, bottom-up approach, with an ultimate aim of a global agreement may yield a more robust system, than a scheme delivered by a top down approach. It is now for governments to bring firm proposals and commitment to the negotiating table in Copenhagen in December 2009.

  45.  EEF believes that it is not regional coverage that is fundamental to whether a scheme should be considered for linkage to the EU ETS, but rather the robustness of the scheme and whether it puts competing sectors on an equal footing.

The robustness and effectiveness of "offset" schemes (ie those without a cap), such as the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM), and the issues around linking them to cap and trade schemes

  46.  EEF believes that the option of meeting domestic targets through carbon credits derived from abatement overseas is essential. Emissions should be reduced where it is most cost-effective to do so. Therefore, there should be as few restrictions as possible over the quantity and sources of credits which can be used to meet EU targets.

47.  However, this can only be achieved if credits represent actual emissions reductions. Credits should not be counted unless assurances exist that emission reductions associated with such credits are genuine, sustainable and fully verifiable to a standard comparable to that agreed by the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) Executive Board.

  48.  If this mechanism is adhered to then linking these schemes to domestic, or international trading schemes can only improve their ability to deliver reduction targets and achieve the aim of limiting the change in our climate. The ability to use CDM credits can increase international cooperation and expand abatement options.

UK CARBON BUDGETS

The relationship between emissions credits and the UK carbon budgets set up under the Climate Change Act

  49.  Given the Kyoto Protocol's wide political acceptance, and established rigour, EEF welcomes the government's proposal that all the units which are recognised under the Kyoto Protocol and EU ETS be eligible to count towards the UK carbon account. Otherwise the currency (ie CO2e) will be valued differently in its accounts than from the UK's. Taking this into consideration, we agree that carbon units recognised under the international agreements such as Kyoto Protocol and EU ETS qualify.

50.  Furthermore, the adoption of a plausible method for carbon accounting has the potential to make carbon off-setting easier and more credible. Its adoption could remove some of the uncertainties related to the use of off-setting methods and accelerate their acceptance in the Kyoto process and the international carbon market.

51.  By using consistently recognised carbon units, both government and non-governmental organisations will be able to demonstrate that they have used the appropriate process to assess risks, define boundaries, measure emissions and report on them in a way that is meaningful and comparable. A rigorous and consistent method of reporting will add credibility to the cuts in emissions being made and will make it easier for government to set credible targets for the future.

Transparency of and justification for counting the purchase of emissions credits (especially from "offset" schemes) as decreasing emissions from the UK

  52.  As we have said before, while EEF supports the unlimited use of CDM credits without restrictions, we believe that any approved CDM carbon credits must be assessed to be additional ie that the planned emission reductions would not occur without the additional incentive provided by carbon credits. Therefore, EEF would urge the government to note that "additionality" is key to the integrity of carbon markets and should be a prerequisite for carbon reduction incentives and regulations in future public policy including the formulation of the UK carbon account. EEF believes that if the UK government is aiming to structure a carbon account that reflects meaningful incremental emissions reductions, additionality is required and needs to be assured.

53.  Furthermore, for the carbon markets to remain credible enough to be used for compliance against future carbon mandates, the UK needs to protect the credibility of existing carbon markets. Government should encourage carbon offset markets that can help reduce greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions. This requires that both government and non-governmental organisations find ways to select and target emissions reductions that are additional and measurable.

  54.  EEF advocates that government need to work closely with EU and international partners to improve the rules of the CDM, but strongly urge that businesses be given adequate information and consulted on the process at an early stage. Standards for additionality need to be clear, stringent and measurable in order to avoid injecting uncertainty into the carbon market.

3 March 2009


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2010
Prepared 8 February 2010