The role of carbon markets in preventing dangerous climate change - Environmental Audit Committee Contents


Memorandum submitted by the Department of Energy and Climate Change

SUMMARY

    — The Stern Review of the economics of climate change highlighted the need for a carbon price signal across countries and sectors to ensure that emission reductions are delivered in the most cost effective way.

    — The UK is committed to building on the EU Emissions Trading System (EU ETS) as the principal way of pricing carbon in the economy.

    — Building on the lessons learnt from Phases I and II of the EU ETS, including as set out in previous reports from the Environmental Audit Committee, Phase III (from 2013) has been significantly revised. The combination of a more ambitious, EU-wide cap on emissions with an annually declining trajectory to 2020 and beyond; auctioning as the preferred means of allocation; and limited access to project credits from outside the EU will result in more emission reductions, more predictable market conditions and improved certainty for industry and investors.

    — The potential of the global carbon market is only just being realised. It is important to get the design of the EU ETS right. With the right focus, and improved credibility, the EU ETS can become the basis for a global carbon market.

    — National and regional carbon markets offer significant potential for international climate policy. Making the global carbon market deeper, wider and more liquid will increase the potential to reduce emissions at least cost. The UK Government and the EU are keen to build a global carbon market by linking the EU ETS to other emerging trading systems which demonstrate a high level of environmental integrity and robust design.

OVERVIEW

  1.  This memorandum sets out the Government's view on the issues highlighted by the Committee as areas it would like to explore in its inquiry.

Potential contribution of international emissions trading to delivering a global greenhouse gas stabilisation target, consistent with the UK's goal of limiting global warming to 2oC

  2.  The Stern Review of the economics of climate change highlighted the need for a carbon price signal across countries and sectors to ensure that emission reductions are delivered in the most cost effective way.

  3.  International emissions trading through a cap and trade system can keep emissions within set limits, whilst allowing emission reductions to be made at least cost through the trading of allowances. This is the UK's carbon price instrument of choice.

  4.  Participation in national and regional carbon markets offers a significant contribution to tackling global climate change, in particular we consider:

    — mandatory cap and trade systems developed with a high level of environmental integrity and robust design are cost-effective instruments to reduce greenhouse gas emissions;

    — robust monitoring, reporting and verification rules underpin credible emissions trading;

    — future linking of emissions trading systems may provide more emissions reductions at lower cost, and accelerate the scale of innovation;

    — larger trading volumes and improved market liquidity are likely to yield more robust price signals; and

    — linked systems may stabilize investor expectations, provide political certainty on the continued existence of the carbon market and help mobilize capital for the transition to a global low-carbon economy.

Whether, and under what circumstances, emissions trading ought to be supplemented or replaced by tax or regulation

  5.  Emissions trading uniquely provides the opportunity to set a global price on carbon, delivering true transparency of the cost of carbon and ensuring this cost is met by those who produce emissions. However, emissions trading can only be part of the solution to tackle climate change. Other measures such as tax incentives and regulation will also be required.

  6.  Taxes and trading will have equivalent outcomes in certain circumstances. When there is uncertainty over the damage value of the marginal unit of emissions, trading is preferred, because emissions trading imposes an absolute cap, above which emissions cannot rise.

  7.  The Stern review highlighted the need for polices such as the EU ETS, which price carbon, to be supplemented with other policies which overcome the barriers to innovation of low-carbon technologies, and the barriers to consumer behaviour change. Additional policies, including taxes and regulation, will complement the aims of emissions trading systems by unlocking opportunities to reduce emissions at lower cost than otherwise possible.

THE EU EMISSIONS TRADING SYSTEM

The record of Phase II of the EU ETS, and prospects for the success of Phase III

  8.  The challenge of Phase II, running from 2008-12, has been to address the problems of Phase I and improve the credibility of the EU ETS as an effective tool in tackling climate change. In Phase II, UK effort is expected to produce a reduction of 29.3 Mega tonnes of CO2 (MtCO2) annually compared to projected business as usual emissions for 2010. This is due to a tighter Phase II cap of 2082.68 MtCO2 (per year). EU effort compared to 2005 is expected to produce a reduction of 215.8 MtCO2. This is 9.3% per year below 2005 emissions—with UK effort 13% below 2005 emissions.

  9.  To increase the efficiency of the system and to help prevent windfall profits, auctioning of allowances has been introduced as an allocation methodology. The UK is auctioning 7% of its allowances in Phase II, with fewer free allowances to the large electricity producers sector.

  10.  The next Phase of the EU ETS from 2013, builds on the lessons of Phases I and II, and contains a number of major improvements. Most importantly, the EU has put in place the measures to deliver a unilateral 20% reduction in greenhouse gas emissions by 2020 from 1990 levels, with the potential to rise to 30% as part of an international climate agreement.

  11.  The revised EU ETS Directive provides for a fundamentally different and more rigorous approach to setting the cap on emissions. A central EU cap will guarantee that the EU ETS will deliver its share of emission reductions. The cap is set at a more ambitious level. For the first time, there is an annually declining trajectory for the cap to 2020 and beyond which will deliver emissions 21% below 2005 levels by 2020.

  12.  There will also be a significant increase in auctioning in Phase III, including 100% auctioning in the power sector in the UK and across most of the EU, and a greater harmonisation of the rules of the system to eliminate distortion across the EU.

  13.  Detailed implementation measures will be agreed through technical comitology procedures led by the European Commission over 2009-11.

  14.  We believe the revised EU ETS should result in more predictable market conditions, a more stable carbon price and improved long-term certainty for industry.

Extent to which the carbon price will be sufficient to drive low-carbon investment, in particular decarbonisation of energy

  15.  Setting the emissions cap on the EU ETS in order to meet our emissions reduction targets creates a price for carbon allowances arising from abatement costs in the industrial sectors covered by the system. This price is a result of the cap setting. Government has not taken a view that any particular price of carbon is the "right" price for other policy areas, other than through internal Government guidance on how to cost carbon impacts in policy appraisal. The carbon price creates dynamic incentives for firms to invest in low-carbon technologies. The level of incentive will depend on the carbon price, and on future expectations for the price. High carbon prices will increase returns from low-carbon investments or from developing low-carbon technologies. However, in order to meet emissions reductions at least cost—particularly in sectors outside the ETS- further policies to support innovation in low-carbon technologies and to drive behavioural change, will also be required.

  16.  In order to provide the correct incentives for low-carbon investments, firms need to form expectations about the future level of the carbon price. This is particularly important for capital intensive sectors with lengthy payback periods on investments, such as electricity generation. Failure to signal future carbon constraints clearly could result in investors underestimating future prices, and to lock-in of high-carbon investments, increasing the overall cost to the economy of meeting emissions reduction targets. The revised EU ETS Directive agreed in December sets an annual reduction in cap of 1.74% per annum from 2013 to 2020 and beyond, and so gives a long-term price signal sought by investors.

Impacts of economic recession on the workings of the EU ETS

  17.  In the EU carbon market we are currently witnessing a reduction in volumes and lower prices resulting from reduced manufacturing output, lower electricity demand and lower forecasts for GHG emissions in the short term. The fall in the price of carbon has also followed the fall in other commodity prices. Due to reduced manufacturing demand some companies are also selling their allowances, thus increasing the overall supply. Allowing carbon prices to reflect these changing market fundamentals is necessary for achieving fixed emissions reductions at least cost as it incentivises participants to change their behaviour accordingly.

  18.  It should become easier for firms to comply with emissions targets under a lower carbon price as compliance costs will be lower. In turn, the cost pass-through to consumers should fall.

  19.  There are significant risks in attempting to manage the carbon price. Introducing price caps or floors could make emissions trading more uncertain by in effect generating speculation on the next possible Government intervention in the market. Our approach is to set the right, long-term regulatory framework with a reducing cap on emissions (as with Phase III of the EU ETS), and allow the market to help achieve these reductions cost-effectively.

Impacts on and responses by UK firms covered by the EU ETS

  20.  In Phase II, UK emitters are expected to be net purchasers of allowances from installations in other Member States. That said, some installations received more allowances than required and were able to sell them on. Increased auctioning of allowances in Phase III and the tighter cap will reduce the potential for such gains to be made.

Implications of the EU ETS for business competitiveness, and how to address them

  21.  The UK Government recognises that carbon leakage (production moving out of the EU because of the price of carbon) is an issue which must be addressed in Phase III of the EU ETS. However, current analysis indicates that only a small number of sectors will be at significant risk of carbon leakage. Of course, the best solution in the long term is to develop the global carbon market as part of an international agreement so as to provide a more level playing field for business. In the interim, we support the allocation of allowances for free, based on efficiency benchmarks, to those sectors at significant risk. This assessment should be made on an evidence based approach. The revised EU ETS Directive provides for a reassessment of this approach based on a reappraisal of the carbon leakage risks facing EU manufacturing industries, considered in light of any future international climate agreement.

Effects of the expansion of the EU ETS to encompass aviation

  22.  On 24 October 2008, the Council of the European Union adopted a Directive that will include all flights arriving at and departing from European airports in the EU ETS from 2012 onwards. This means that net aviation emissions cannot increase beyond 97% of average 2004-06 emissions levels in 2012 and 95% of average 2004-06 emissions levels in 2013. Any growth in aircraft emissions above these levels will only be made possible by the aviation sector paying for commensurate carbon savings elsewhere in the EU economy.

  23.  The European Commission estimates that by 2020 a total of 183 million tonnes of CO2 will be saved per year on the flights covered by the EU ETS, a 46% reduction compared with business as usual.

Allocation or auctioning of EU ETS credits, and the use of auctioning revenues

  24.  The Government supports high rates of auctioning under the revised EU ETS from 2013. Auctioning is the simplest and most transparent allocation methodology and it reinforces the incentive to reduce emissions, and to invest in and develop cleaner technologies.

  25.  The revised Directive provides for a substantial increase in auctioning levels and overall at least 60% of allowances will be auctioned by 2020, compared to around 3% in Phase II. Auction levels will be 100% for the power sector in the UK and across most of the EU.

  26.  As part of the revised EU ETS Directive, the European Council adopted a non legally binding political declaration indicating Member States' willingness to spend at least half of the auction revenues or equivalent to tackle climate change both in the EU and in developing countries. The Government is content with this approach, which we believe will provide a strong signal of the EU's willingness to invest in a low-carbon economy and offer support to the international community ahead of negotiations in Copenhagen at the end of this year.

DEVELOPMENT OF A GLOBAL CARBON MARKET

Progress of cap and trade schemes in other countries (notably, the United States), and the prospects for, and practicalities of, linking between them

  27.  We recognise the economic and environmental benefits of expanding the reach of the EU ETS and are working with our international partners towards linking of emerging emissions trading systems. There are practical constraints to linking with other trading systems, with comparability one of the main challenges. The European Commission has developed criteria for linking to the EU ETS. These include:

    — A robust and environmentally ambitious emissions cap. The EU will only link to mandatory cap and trade systems—with an absolute cap on greenhouse gas emissions.

    — Trading systems should be free of Government intervention, such as price caps or ex post adjustments.

    — Credible emissions trading systems that deliver real greenhouse gas emissions reductions. This means covering sectors or sources where reliable monitoring and reporting of emissions is possible and having robust and trustworthy compliance and enforcement.

  28.  The first regional cap and trade system in the US, the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative covering North Eastern States, became operational this year. There are two other regional cap and trade initiatives under development; the Western Climate Initiative and the Midwestern Climate Change Accord. President Obama has announced his intention to seek the agreement of Congress to a Federal cap and trade system. The EU is committed to encouraging a single US Federal emissions trading system that can link to the EU ETS.

  29.  Australia's Carbon Pollution Reduction Scheme is due to commence trading in 2010. They have introduced price caps for the first phase of their system and the EU will not consider linking the system to the EU ETS whilst these are in place. A voluntary emission trading system has been developed by Japan—however there are no moves as yet to make this mandatory. Regional voluntary Emission Trading Systems are under development in Taiwan, and are also being considered in South Korea.

The robustness and effectiveness of "offset" schemes (ie those without a cap), such as the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM), and the issues around linking them to cap and trade schemes

  30.  The Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) helps to drive global investment in low-carbon technologies. It provides a source of income and technology valued by developing countries to support a shift away from high-emitting "business as usual" development, essential for their long-term transition to low-carbon economies.

  31.  Nevertheless, the Government regards CDM as a transitional mechanism towards building our long-term vision of a truly global carbon market. In the medium term, we wish to see advanced developing countries move away from CDM towards sectoral crediting and trading under sectoral caps.

  32.  CDM will continue to play a role in the least developed countries. The Government believes that a number of reforms are needed of CDM, including:

    — Improvements to administrative efficiency and transparency of the assessment process.

    — Improved methods for assessing emission reductions. Benchmarking should replace the less reliable, more subjective, assessment against "Business As Usual" emission projections.

    — Development of special approaches for sectors where abatement is particularly cheap in comparison to the number of emissions that can be generated.

  33.  The UK Government has been clear that the EU must demonstrate it is serious about the transition to a low-carbon economy through emission reductions within its borders. We should not rely disproportionately on third countries in order to meet Europe's own targets. Therefore, we see a limit on the use of international project credits as appropriate in the context of the EU's unilateral commitments to reduce emissions.

  34.  There has been a small increase in access to CDM credits in Phase III of the EU ETS, to harmonise some of the discrepancies in allocation that occurred in Phase II. However, this increase has been limited such that at least 50% of absolute reductions (in terms of effort) in the EU ETS take place within Europe. This compares to access to credits in Phase II equivalent to more than four times required effort. This restriction on access to credits provides a strong incentive for developing countries to sign up to a global deal in order to increase their access to a global carbon market.

UK CARBON BUDGETS

The relationship between emissions credits and the UK carbon budgets set up under the Climate Change Act

  35.  The Climate Change Act 2008 creates a new approach to responding to climate change in the UK through setting ambitious targets, taking powers to help achieve them, and strengthening the institutional framework in this area. To help provide long-term clarity, the Act requires the Government to establish a system of "carbon budgets" capping emissions over successive five-year periods.

  36.  The Act allows carbon units purchased from overseas to be counted as credits against carbon budgets, while units sold to other countries should be counted as a debit. This is important to ensure that the UK and UK businesses are able to participate in emissions trading systems such as the EU ETS, and access cost-effective abatement opportunities outside the UK. The independent Committee on Climate Change is required to provide advice, in relation to each budgetary period, on the appropriate balance between domestic and international effort, and the Government must set a legally-binding limit on the amount of credits that may be counted towards each budget. In addition, the Act requires the Government to consider the need to reduce UK emissions when considering how to meet the targets and budgets. Together, these provisions ensure the maximum possible transparency about our plans for meeting targets and for moving the UK to a low-carbon economy, while retaining the option of using international credits where appropriate.

Transparency of and justification for counting the purchase of emissions credits (especially from "offset" schemes) as decreasing emissions from the UK

  37.  The concept of tradable carbon units is an important part of the international climate change architecture. Under the Kyoto Protocol, countries may trade carbon units with each other provided this is supplemental to domestic action to reduce emissions. The provisions in the Act allowing overseas credits to count towards carbon budgets are therefore consistent with the existing international approach as well as the policy approach set out in the Stern Review.

  38.  In terms of whether credits from "offset" schemes may count towards carbon budgets, we propose that only units which are internationally recognised under UN and EU rules may be eligible. These units have been subject to significant scrutiny and are widely accepted as representing genuine and verifiable emissions reductions.

February 2009





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2010
Prepared 8 February 2010