Dairy Farmers of Britain - Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Committee Contents


Further supplementary memorandum submitted by Mr Philip Moody (DFoB 45)

INQUIRY INTO DAIRY FARMERS OF BRITAIN LTD ("DFB")

  I thought it would be helpful for me to draw to your attention those aspects of the DFB story that demonstrate, in my opinion:

    (a) why DFB failed;

    (b) what lessons that can be learned from the failure of DFB; and

    (c) the implications for cooperatives generally.

Capitalisation

  DFB was charged by its members to pursue a vertical integration strategy of acquiring and owning processing businesses downstream from farm gate. However, for such a strategy to be pursued on a scale sufficient to influence the overall milk price return to members for a business the size (in UK terms) of DFB, was always likely to require an extent of capital in excess of the capability or willingness of members to provide.

  I stated in evidence that the Board assessed that the total amount of capital available to it to invest in the strategy without outside investors was in the region of £100 million to £150 million. We always identified that circa £50 million was the reasonable maximum that we could raise from members leaving the balance to be secured from borrowings, dependent on the financial performance of the underlying business. At that time, banks were typically lending between 50% and 65% of total capital assuming suitable debt performance covenants.

  I also stated that DFB was under-capitalised to achieve its strategic aims. This is because the Board understood the need to be capable of raising capital of in the order of £250 million to £500 million in total, such was the scale of ambition.

  This identified a "capital gap" which was exacerbated with a reducing member base as this presented a long term contraction in capital available to the business. However, DFB could not attract third party equity investment due to the conflict between profit and milk price—members would want a high milk price whereby investors would want the lowest milk price necessary to secure supply, in order to maximise profits.

  The Board sought to innovate a solution by approaching the US Private Placement market (low yield long term income bonds), and attracted strong interest in its strategic ambitions. However, the requirements of this financial market are quite restrictive and whilst DFB may have been able to satisfy them, it is not an opportunity afforded to most cooperatives in the UK due as much to scale as anything else.

  The fact is that most financial institutions do not understand the cooperative model and those that do are not attracted to invest long term capital in most cases. That means that farmers have to bear the capital strain in the development years and, unlike many successful European cooperatives who were helped in their formative years with Government supported "soft loans", and have had many years of steady growth to build their balance sheets, the UK market is moving too fast to afford that luxury. This places a huge burden in the short term on farmers, leading to cooperatives being under-capitalised compared to their private competitors.

  If, therefore, the UK wishes to see the successful development of a strong cooperative sector, it needs to provide long term capital to enable them to bridge this gap until the cooperatives have had an opportunity to get established and to build their balance sheets as a result.

  This issue has been identified by the English Farming & Food Partnerships Ltd who are seeking to identify innovative solutions to this need. However, Government could help by improving the environment (such as in areas of tax reliefs) to kick-start investment in this area. The reality, however, is that HM Customs & Excise has ruled not to grant tax relief for farmers' losses in DFB or, to put it another way, to tax them on money they have never received, which can only add considerably to the damaging industry impact of DFB's collapse. Correcting this unfairness and granting tax relief for inward investment into focussed agrifood funds or companies would be helpful.

Operating Model

  To seek to bridge this capital gap, DFB chose to operate what is called a "margin organisation" business model. That is to say that the milk price would always be set at a level that enabled the business to have sound finances, passing the risk onto the members in proportion to their milk supply and thus utilising their collective financial strength in support of the cooperative. It was on this basis that banks lent to DFB.

  DFB also chose to retain capital from members through retention from their milk price, effectively deferring part of the payment for their milk price to form part of the businesses long term loan capital. However, Council always opted to prevent this mechanism from being used to build reserves.

  This proved ultimately to be a flawed model as members increasingly compared their milk price with alternatives available from other milk processors whose capital needs and risk was borne by shareholders, not the milk suppliers.

  This put pressure on DFB to either pay an unsustainably high milk price that would undermine the business, or to risk member disaffection and resignation that would equally undermine the business.

  The point here is that this issue dominated financial policy in the Board as milk price was seen as the overriding priority at all times (putting farmer directors who were in the majority in an impossible position of conflict), leading to the delay or postponement of rationalisation projects if the cost suffered in any one year was greater than the benefit returned.

  Ultimately, the Board was forced through member pressure of resignations to pay a milk price that the business could not afford without implementing bold restructuring programmes, and this led to a breakdown of trust with the banks who were depending on the margin organising principle of members standing fully behind the risk of the business.

  I would suggest that the lesson to be learned from this experience is to ensure that the price paid for milk is set by open market forces and that any losses sustained by the business be taken into context of the overall capital needs. I would also suggest that sensible capital levels need to be established at the outset (including general reserves) and for the ambitions of the strategy to be set accordingly.

Role of Council

  In nearly all other farmer cooperatives with which I have come into contact, the Members Council is treated as a communication body to enable the Board to assess likely member reaction to particular issues under its consideration and to enable views expressed by members to filter through to the Board. Voting is still held in the hands of individual members who all have the right to receive information, attend at general meetings, ask questions of the directors, and vote.

  In the case of DFB, however, the Council was given a very different role in that it was formally enfranchised by the members to vote on their behalf, with Council Members themselves being appointed by a series of regional elections. Council was set up to enable a democratic streamlined voting process but ended up as a Member governance body.

  I believe this model had two fundamental flaws:

    1. Council Members were burdened with a responsibility, for which they were not adequately trained or experienced, to adopt a level of governance that they could never properly fulfil, simply due to a lack of detailed knowledge of the business which, for essential commercial reasons, always had to be held confidential to the Board; and

    2. the Governance structure of the company was blurred in the sense that there was confusion as to exactly what the role of Council was, and where the division of responsibility fell between the Council and the Board.

  I believe this structure, linked to the constant comparison with European cooperatives, led to confusion between the role of the Council as devised in the Rules and the role of a supervisory board in a European corporate model.

  The lesson to be learned here is to ensure that all voting is retained in the hands of individual members (as is the case with shareholders in publicly listed companies), to ensure full engagement by them directly with their Board of Directors and to avoid confusion and conflict within the governance structure.

Constitution of the Board

  DFB was set up to be "farmer controlled" as opposed to simply "farmer owned". This farmer control was embedded within the rules and culture of the business. The Rules limited the number of outside directors and always ensured that the farmer directors were in the majority.

  This structure denied the Board an essential commercial balance between farmer representatives, experienced non-executives and executive management and placed an extremely onerous responsibility on the farmer directors who knew that, ultimately, they had both the power and the obligation to direct Board decisions.

  It is important to add that there is no implied criticism here of the farmer directors themselves who always discharged their responsibilities with diligence and commitment, and who earned my total respect for their integrity and dedication to DFB.

  I believe the lesson to be learned is for businesses of this complexity to have farmer representation, not farmer control, and for the constitution of the Board of Directors to comprise farmer representation, senior executives and outside non-executives.

What was the root cause of DFB's Failure?

  In the case of DFB, much focus has been applied to whether or not, too much was paid for ACC. The fact is that, irrespective of whether or not this was the case, it wasn't fundamental to the failure of the business. Had the business generated the profit stream expected by the Board at the time of acquisition, the company would have had no difficulty in meeting its obligations to the banks and members.

  The most significant problem was an onerous 4 year contract that was signed by ACC immediately prior to the sale, committing ACC to supply product to a competitor business at a price that was below the cost at which DFB could produce and deliver the product. This contract generated losses of in the order of £4 million per annum and also enabled the competitor to use the cheap DFB product to quote against DFB in respect of customers it was already supplying, thereby causing it either to lose these customers or reduce its prices with the resultant impact on profit margin. The total financial impact was therefore much greater.

  These losses had a dramatic impact on DFB:

    (a) they eroded cash and profit which impacted directly on the ability of the business to pay a competitive milk price which, in turn, affected member confidence and support for the business;

    (b) they worked against the efforts of management to make the business less dependent on CRTG as a customer;

    (c) they eroded the ability of the business to finance much needed capital expenditure with which to improve the efficiency of the processing factories; and

    (d) they dramatically reduced the re-sale value and opportunity of the business.

  However, perhaps most importantly of all, it was well recognised by the DFB Board that CRTG would most likely put the milk supply contract out for open tender when it came up for renewal in 2007, and that competitors would aggressively price against DFB in that process. DFB therefore had a well articulated business plan encompassing a range of profit improvement programmes ("PIPs") designed to make the business fully competitive by that time. In the end, the company delivered on virtually all of these PIPs but their effect was simply to recover some of the losses suffered through the onerous competitor supply contract as opposed to enable the business to become more competitive. The 2007 renewal, which ultimately proved to be more competitive than envisaged due to the impact of Wiseman's new Bridgewater processing plant, resulted in a material reduction in price paid by CRTG that placed a burden on the business from which it was ultimately unable to recover.

  There are many other contributory factors to the failure but that, in my opinion, was the root cause and however the Board tried to find commercial and strategic solutions, the scale of the liquids division losses were ultimately too great. This was foremost a commercial failure and was not caused by constitutional, governance or structural issues. The corporate governance process was both rigorous and robust.

Philip Moody

February 2010





 
previous page contents

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2010
Prepared 25 March 2010