Social Care - Health Committee Contents


Memorandum by the MAP2030 Research Group (SC 55)

SOCIAL CARE

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

    — This memorandum covers the costs of long-term care and disability benefits for people aged 65 and over under a range of potential reforms to the funding system in England.

    — Under the current system, public expenditure on long-term care and disability benefits for older people is projected to rise from £15.8 billion in 2007 to £37.6 billion in 2032, an increase of 225%.

    — The public expenditure costs in 2007 of introducing a policy of free personal care, along the lines proposed by the Royal Commission on Long Term Care (1999), would be approximately £1,980 million more than the current system; of introducing free personal care for people living at home, proposed by the Prime Minister at the Labour Party Conference, would be approximately £660 million more than the current system; and of introducing a Partnership model the along lines suggested by the Green Paper, assuming 33% of personal care costs are guaranteed (HMG 2009), would be approximately £470 million more than the current system.

    — The Green Paper proposes that the new National Care Service could be funded by transferring some disability benefits into the social care system. If, under the Partnership model considered here, Attendance Allowance and Disability Living Allowance for older people were withdrawn, then public expenditure costs in 2007 would be approximately £4,140 million lower than under the current system.

    — Average weekly financial gains to care home residents would be largest for free personal care (around £95 a week in 2007), but would be between £30 and £40 a week under partnership options.

    — Average weekly gains for home care users would be some £20-£30 a week under free personal care. They would be just £1 to £2 a week under the partnership model or, if Attendance Allowance and Disability Allowance were withdrawn, home care users would lose around £40 a week on average.

    — Gains from all the reform options examined are largest for care recipients in the highest fifth of the (age-specific) income distribution and smallest in the lowest fifth. Under the partnership model with Attendance Allowance and Disability Living Allowance withdrawn, losses are largest in the lowest income group.

    — Our findings on the partnership model are dependent on the form of the means test which would remain for that part of care costs not met by the state, particularly if Attendance Allowance and Disability Allowance are withdrawn. We have assumed that those means tests would operate as now. If they were more generous, gains (losses) could be larger (smaller) and more targeted on those on lower incomes.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

  The MAP2030 Research Group is funded (grant number RES-339-25-0002) under the New Dynamics of Ageing Programme, a cross-council research programme involving the Economic and Social Research Council (ESRC), the Medical Research Council (MRC), the Arts and Humanities Research Council (AHRC), the Biotechnology and Biological Sciences Research Council (BBSRC) and the Engineering and Physical Sciences Research Council (EPSRC).

  The Family Resources Survey and General Household Survey are crown copyright and made available by the Office for National Statistics via the UK Data Archive.

  All responsibility for the analysis and views expressed in this paper rests with the authors.

    Ruth Hancock and Marcello Morciano

    Health Economics Group, Faculty of Health

    University of East Anglia

    Juliette Malley, Derek King, Linda Pickard, and Adelina Comas-Herrera

    Personal Social Services Research Unit

    London School of Economics

PAYING FOR LONG-TERM CARE: POTENTIAL REFORMS TO FUNDING LONG-TERM CARE

  1.  This discussion paper has been prepared by the MAP2030 study team as a contribution to the House of Commons Health Select Committee Inquiry into Social Care. This inter-disciplinary team, covering a number of institutions, is investigating the needs and resources of older people to 2030. It should be noted at the outset that this report is independent of work commissioned from the PSSRU by the Department of Health, exploring the costs and benefits of funding options in the Government's Green Paper Shaping the Future of Care Together (HMG 2009).

  2.  The present paper covers a range of potential reforms to the funding system for long-term care in England. It presents current and projected future public expenditure costs of long-term care for older people under the reform options and the implications of the options for the costs of care borne by individuals in different income groups. The reform options considered here include a version of "free" personal care which was a policy recommended by the Royal Commission on Long Term Care (1999), the version of "free" personal care proposed by the Prime Minister at the Labour Party Conference, and several versions of a Partnership model along lines suggested by the recent Green Paper on care and support (HMG 2009).

  3.  In light of concerns about the restricted coverage of the current system we compare expenditure under a selection of the reform options to expenditure under a potential expansion in care services for older people along the lines of the care packages recommended in the Wanless report on funding social care (Wanless 2006). Such an expansion could also come about as a result of the reforms themselves: by reducing the cost of care to individuals the reforms might generate an increase in demand for care. The reforms could drive up the fees that care homes charge to local authorities. The sensitivity of the reforms to such changes is therefore investigated. All estimates relate to England and are expressed in constant 2007 prices.

METHOD

  4.  The method is as used in an earlier study and is described in detail in Hancock et al (2007). The analyses were conducted using two linked models—the CARESIM microsimulation model and the Personal Social Services Research Unit (PSSRU) cell-based long-term care finance model. CARESIM simulates the incomes and assets of future cohorts of older people and their ability to contribute towards care home fees or the costs of home-based care, should such care be needed (Hancock et al. 2003). The PSSRU model makes projections of demand for long-term care and associated expenditure, under clearly specified assumptions (Wittenberg et al. 2006).

POLICY OPTIONS CONSIDERED[31]

Funding Policy Options Considered

  5.   Free personal care: The policy of free personal care has been described and discussed in detail elsewhere (Royal Commission on Long-Term Care 1999, Wanless 2006). The Royal Commission report envisaged several ways of implementing free personal care, one of which was that, for residential care, there would be a personal care allowance, applied by all local authorities (Royal Commission on Long Term Care 1999: 66 £6.39). This sum would be deducted from the charges made in individual care homes, leaving the balance representing living and housing costs[32]. There would be means-testing of ability to pay for hotel costs, entitling people with little means to receive help with the charges for living and housing. An important feature of this approach is that the amount allowed for personal care is applicable in any care home. This "fixed care costs" version of free personal care is the one we model. The weekly personal care allowance was set at £248.70 in April 2007 and assumed to rise with general price inflation in future years. The cost of all need for personal care at home, as assessed by local authorities, is assumed to be met by the state under free personal care.

  6.   Free personal care for those with the highest needs living in the community: The Prime Minister announced the Government's intention to introduce a policy of free personal care for older people with the highest needs living at home. We model the implications of this policy by assuming that the means-test for local authority support for home care would be abolished for older people with personal care needs currently receiving "high" or "very high" packages of care, as defined by our model. In practice this means that those people with personal care needs receiving packages of home care of five or more hours per week would no longer contribute to the costs of their care. The means test remains for people receiving fewer than five hours of home care, for those without personal care needs and for older people living in care homes.

  7.   Options relating to a partnership model: The Green Paper proposes a partnership model in which everyone who qualifies for care and support on the basis of their care needs would be entitled to have a set proportion of their basic care and support costs met by the state. The proposal has a progressive element such that older people with fewer means will have more of their costs met by the state; and those with the fewest means will have all their care costs met by the state (HMG, 2009). Based on our interpretation of the Green Paper, we assume that all those who qualify for care are eligible to have one-third of their personal care costs met by the state.[33] The Green paper is not specific on who would be eligible for more than a third of their care costs. We assume that those who under the current funding system are entitled to a state contribution of more than one-third of their care costs, continue to receive the same state contribution as under the current system.[34]

  8.   Partnership model with withdrawal of some disability benefits: The Green Paper also proposed that the new National Care Service could be funded by transferring monies from some elements of the benefits system into the social care system. It suggests that one option is to withdraw Attendance Allowance (AA) for new claimants and transfer the money into the social care system (HMG, 2009). AA is a non means-tested benefit for disabled older people aged 65 and over and is payable at one of two rates. We model a variant of the partnership scheme in which AA and Disability Living Allowance (DLA)[35] are withdrawn. Since receipt of AA or the middle or higher rate of DLA determines eligibility for a Severe Disability Premium (SDP) in Pension Credit we assume that if AA and DLA were withdrawn, the SDP would also be withdrawn. Receipt of AA and DLA also determine eligibility for Carer's Allowance for carers of people with impairment, and the Pension Credit Carer Premium, but our analysis does not cover these benefits. Modelling of the withdrawal of AA under the current system, carried out by Forder and Fernandez (2009) for the Department of Health, has allowed for some targeting, but this does not seem to be described in the Green Paper itself and has not been modelled here. The Green Paper also implies some transitional arrangements, whereby "people receiving any of the relevant benefits at the time of reform would continue to receive an equivalent level of support and protection under a new and better care and support system" (HMG 2009: 104). The modelling here does not take account of this phasing-in of the reforms.

  9.   Effects of rises in care home fees: In independent care homes, fees paid in respect of residents who are supported by the local authority are often lower than those paid by "self-funders". The free personal care and partnership model options would increase the proportion of care home residents eligible for local authority support with their fees and it is implicitly assumed here that all those receiving local authority support with their fees under the reform options would be eligible for the lower local authority fee rates. There could therefore be pressure for local authorities to increase the fees they offer care home owners in respect of local authority supported residents.[36] Two possibilities are considered here. In the first, local authority fees are assumed to remain at their current levels. In this case, part of the costs of the change would implicitly fall to care home providers, which is probably unrealistic. If fees for local authority-funded residents do not rise, the reforms would yield reduced revenue for care home providers and some might go out of business. In the second possibility, local authority fees are assumed to rise such that provider income per resident remains at its 2007 level under the current funding system. The higher fee rates are assumed to apply to all supported residents and not just to those specifically benefiting from the reformed funding system. The state contribution to personal care is taken to be unchanged so that all of the fee rise relates to hotel costs and is subject to means-tested user charges under all options.

Pattern of Care Policy Options Considered

  10.   Wanless pattern of care: A scenario describing an expansion of services for disabled older people is modelled along the lines of the "core business" scenario described in the King's Fund Social Care Review, led by Sir Derek Wanless (Wanless 2006). In the Wanless Review, under this scenario all older people identified as having personal care needs receive services at levels which are deemed to be cost-effective. Cost-effective services are defined as those which cost less than £20,000 per person per year to produce an outcomes gain equivalent to one ADLAY, where an ADLAY is an ADL[37]-adjusted life year and can be understood as a year of life fully ADL-compensated. In the scenario reported here we have expanded services so that the total numbers of older people receiving services match those reported in Wanless (2006).

  11.  This scenario addresses the criticism that there is large unmet need in the current system (CSCI 2008; HMG, 2009). It also demonstrates the sensitivity of the projections to changes in the eligibility criteria for care services, which is of central importance to the partnership model since the offer of public resources is available only to those who "qualify" for care and support services. Combined with the free personal care and partnership funding reforms this pattern of care can also give an indication of the public expenditure consequences of demand for care increasing in response to the reduced care costs that individuals would face under those reforms.

"BASE CASE" ASSUMPTIONS

  12.  The PSSRU and CARESIM models produce projections on the basis of specific assumptions about future trends in the key drivers of demand for long-term care (Box 1). A base case projection takes account of expected changes in factors exogenous to long-term care policy, such as demographic trends and trends in housing tenure. It holds constant factors endogenous to long-term care policy, such as patterns of care and the funding system. The base case is used as a comparison when the assumptions of the model are varied in alternative scenarios.

BOX 1

KEY ASSUMPTIONS OF THE BASE CASE



  —  The number of people by age and gender changes in line with the Government Actuary's Department 2006-based population projections for England.
  —  Marital status changes in line with GAD 2006-based marital status and cohabitation projections for England and Wales.
  —  Prevalence rates of disability by age and gender remain unchanged, as reported in the 2001-02 General Household Survey (GHS) for Great Britain.
  —  Home-ownership rates, as reported in the pooled 2003-04, 2004-05 and 2005-06 Family Resources Survey (FRS), change in line with projections produced by the CARESIM model.
  —  The proportions of older people receiving informal care, formal community care services, residential care services and disability benefits remain constant for each sub-group by age, disability and other needs-related characteristics.
  —  The funding system remains unchanged as the current system for England.
  —  Health and social care unit costs rise by 2% per year in real terms (but non-staff revenue costs remain constant in real terms). Real Gross Domestic Product rises in line with HM Treasury assumptions.
  —  The supply of formal care will adjust to match demand and demand will be no more constrained by supply in the future than in the base year.


PUBLIC EXPENDITURE UNDER CURRENT FUNDING SYSTEM AND POLICY OPTIONS

  13.  All results relating to public expenditure under the current funding system and policy options are shown in Tables 1 and 2 and Figure 1.

Public Expenditure under Current Funding System

  14.  Public expenditure on long-term care and disability benefits for people aged 65 and over is projected to rise, under base case assumptions, from £15.8 billion in 2007 to £37.6 billion in 2032, an increase of 225%. These figures relate to public expenditure on long-term health services and social services and to all disability benefits for older people in England. If Gross Domestic Product (GDP) rose in line with HM Treasury assumptions, public expenditure on long-term care and benefits would rise from 1.29% of GDP in 2007 to 2.05% in 2032. These projections are sensitive to varying the assumptions about future life expectancy, trends in disability rates and trends in real unit costs (Wittenberg et al. 2006). They relate to the funding system currently used in England.

Public Expenditure Costs of Options

  15.  Under free personal care (fixed care costs variant) around 100,000 privately-funded care homes residents and around 200,000 privately-funded users of home care would become eligible for public support. The additional net public expenditure cost, compared to continuation of the current funding system, would be around £1,980 million at 2007 prices comprising an additional cost of around £2,075 million to social services, offset by a saving of around £95 million in disability benefits. This saving occurs because publicly-funded care home residents cease to receive AA/DLA and under free personal care, all care home residents are publicly-funded. The additional net public expenditure cost would rise to around £3,750 million in 2027 and £4,890 million in 2032 at constant 2007 prices. Public expenditure on long-term care and disability benefits would rise from 1.46% of GDP in 2007 to 2.31% in 2032.

  16.  Under free personal care at home for people with high needs the additional net public expenditure cost would be around £660 million in 2007. The net additional cost would rise to around £1,380 million in 2027 and £1,770 million in 2032 at constant 2007 prices. Public expenditure on long-term care and disability benefits would rise from 1.35% of GDP in 2007 to 2.14% in 2032.

  17.  Under a Partnership model (with 33% of personal care costs guaranteed), the additional net public expenditure cost, above continuation of the current system, would be around £470 million in 2007, comprising a cost of around £570 million to social services offset by a saving of around £95 million in disability benefits. The net additional cost would rise to around £1,170 million in 2027 and £1,590 million in 2032 at constant 2007 prices. Public expenditure on long-term care and disability benefits would rise from 1.33% of GDP in 2007 to 2.13% in 2032.

  18.  If, under a Partnership model, disability benefits are withdrawn, net public expenditure cost would be around £4,140 million lower than under the current system in 2007.[38] There would be additional costs of around £1,175 million to social services but this is offset by a reduction of £5,320 million in disability benefits. The net reduction in public expenditure would rise to around £6,040 million in 2027 and £6,480 million in 2032 at constant 2007 prices. Public expenditure on long-term care and disability benefits would be 0.95% of GDP in 2007, which is a lower figure than the current percentage (1.29%). This would rise to 1.69% in 2032, which again would be lower than the percentage in 2032 under the current system (2.05%).[39]

Sensitivity Analysis: Care Home Fees

  19.  Under free personal care where care home fees for local authority-supported residents rise, the additional net public expenditure cost, above continuation of the current system, would be around £2,200 million at 2007 prices rising to around £4,220 million in 2027 and £5,510 million in 2032 at constant 2007 prices. Public expenditure on long-term care would rise from 1.47% of GDP in 2007 to 2.34% in 2032.

  20.  Under the Partnership model where care home fees rise, the additional net public expenditure would be around £710 million in 2007 rising to around £1,660 million in 2027 and £2,200 million in 2032 at constant 2007 prices. Public expenditure on long-term care would rise from 1.35% of GDP in 2007 to 2.17% in 2032.

  21.  If, under the Partnership model, disability benefits are withdrawn and LA fees rise, net public expenditure cost would be around £3,900 million lower in 2007. The reduction in public expenditure would be around £5,540 in 2027 and £5,820 million in 2032 at constant 2007 prices. Public expenditure on long-term care would rise from 0.97% of GDP in 2007 to 1.73% in 2032. These percentages are both lower than their respective equivalents under the current funding system.

Sensitivity Analysis: Wanless Packages of Care

  22.  This sensitivity analysis considers the net public expenditure cost of an expansion of care services for older people as per the care packages recommended in the Wanless report on the funding of social care. The additional net public expenditure cost, compared with continuation of current care packages, would be around £3,200 million at 2007 prices comprising a cost of around £2,550 million to social services, £200 million to the NHS and £485 million in disability benefits. The net cost would rise to around £8,110 million in 2027 and £10,140 million in 2032 at constant 2007 prices. Public expenditure on long-term care would rise from 1.56% of GDP in 2007 to 2.60% in 2032.

  23.  If free personal care was implemented alongside expanded packages of care, the additional net public expenditure cost would be around £5,640 million in 2007 rising to around £12,750 million in 2027 and £16,100 million in 2032 at constant 2007 prices. Public expenditure on long-term care would rise from 1.76% of GDP in 2007 to 2.92% in 2032.

  24.  If partnership was implemented alongside expanded packages of care, the additional net public expenditure cost would be around £3,610 million in 2007 rising to around £9,170 million in 2027 and £11,580 million in 2032 at constant 2007 prices. Public expenditure on long-term care would rise from 1.59% of GDP in 2007 to 2.27% in 2032.

Table 1

PUBLIC EXPENDITURE ON LONG-TERM CARE AND DISABILITY BENEFITS FOR PEOPLE AGED 65 AND OVER UNDER POTENTIAL REFORMS TO FUNDING LONG-TERM CARE, ENGLAND, 2007
£ million

Public expenditure Long-term care Disability benefits for
on long-term care PersonalNHS people aged 65+*
and disability Social
benefits for people Services
aged 65+

Base case—Current funding arrangement in England
15,8106,765 3,7255,320
Free personal care in all settings17,790 8,8403,7255,225
Free personal care for high/very high domiciliary care users 16,4657,4203,725 5,320
Partnership with 33% guarantee16,280 7,3303,7255,225
Partnership, AA/DLA (65+) discontinued 11,6707,9453,725 0
Free personal care + fee rise18,010 9,0603,7255,225
Partnership + fee rise16,515 7,5653,7255,230
Partnership, AA/DLA (65+) discontinued + fee rise 11,9108,1853,725 0
Wanless packages of care 19,015 9,2953,9155,805
Wanless packages of care + free personal care 21,45511,8553,915 5,685
Wanless + partnership19,425 9,8253,9155,685

Source: Caresim and PSSRU Models
Note: *"Disability benefits for people aged 65 and over" refers to Attendance Allowance (AA) and Disability Living Allowance (DLA).


Table 2

PUBLIC EXPENDITURE ON LONG-TERM CARE AND DISABILITY BENEFITS FOR PEOPLE AGED 65 AND OVER UNDER POTENTIAL REFORMS TO FUNDING LONG-TERM CARE, ENGLAND, 2007 AND 2032 (£ MILLION, % GDP)

    Public Expenditure—in £     million (2007 prices) Public expenditure % GDP
20072032* 20072032*

Base case—Current funding arrangement
15,81037,590 1.292.05
Free personal care17,790 42,4801.462.31
Free personal care for high/very high domiciliary care users 16,46539,3551.35 2.14
Partnership16,28039,180 1.332.13
Partnership, no AA/DLA11,670 31,1150.951.69
Free personal care + fee rise18,010 43,1001.472.34
Partnership + fee rise16,517 39,8151.352.17
Partnership, no AA/DLA + fee rise11,910 31,7700.971.73
Wanless19,01547,735 1.562.60
Wanless + free personal care21,455 53,6851.762.92
Wanless + partnership19,425 49,1651.592.67

Source: Caresim and PSSRU Models
Note: * Projections of public expenditure are under-estimates since they assume constant take-up rates of DLA by age and gender and do not allow for maturation of the DLA scheme.


Figure 1

PUBLIC EXPENDITURE ON LONG-TERM CARE AND DISABILITY BENEFITS (65+): DIFFERENCE BETWEEN CURRENT SYSTEM AND REFORM OPTIONS, ENGLAND, 2007 (£ MILLION)

  £ million


Source: Caresim and PSSRU Models

Notes: see notes to Tables 1 and 2

FINANCIAL GAINS AND LOSSES TO CARE HOME RESIDENTS AND HOME CARE USERS FROM THE REFORM OPTIONS

  25.  The average financial gains from reform options, in pounds per week (April 2007 prices), are shown in Table 3. Figures are given for people aged 65+ and aged 85+ in 2007, and aged 85+ in 2027. They are shown separately and in combination for care home residents and home care users. The gains are largest under free personal care for care home residents who would be on average about £95 a week better off in 2007 and £130 in 2027, or a little lower if care home fees rise. Gains to care home residents would be between £30 and £40 a week under the partnership options.

  26.  Under free personal care, gains are somewhat lower for home care users—some £20-£30 per week. They are a little higher under Wanless patterns of care. This is because these patterns of care assume that more people are cared for at home with more expensive packages of care than at present. A move from the current funding system to free personal care under these patterns of care is therefore more beneficial for home care users than under current patterns of care. Home care users gain only small sums from the partnership model when AA and DLA are retained. If AA and DLA are withdrawn they lose about £40 a week.

  27.  These losses need some explanation. Because there are variations in how local authorities charge for home care services, we have assumed a standard means test that embodies the principles set out in national guidance. We have also had to make assumptions about how the means tests would work if AA and DLA were withdrawn. For the current funding system we assume that all Local Authorities include AA and DLA in the income which is taken into account in assessing user contributions to home care. We also assume, to comply with national guidance, that they therefore disregard part of any AA/DLA that the recipient uses towards Disability Related Expenditure (DRE)[40]. Under current guidance, if LAs disregard AA/DLA into account in the means tests, they do not need to make any allowance for DRE. We have assumed that if AA/DLA were withdrawn, LAs would not make any allowance for DRE but would apply an otherwise similar means test to the proportion of care costs not met by the state (ie two-thirds). Thus although some users gain from the non means-tested 33% state contribution, the loss of AA/DLA (and in consequence the DRE disregard) more than outweighs this gain for most.

Table 3

AVERAGE WEEKLY GAINS, CARE HOME RESIDENTS AND HOME CARE USERS, 2007 AND 2027 £S PW, APRIL 2007 PRICES

    Care home residents and     home care users combined     Care home residents     Home care users
    2007     2027    2007     2027    2007     2027

65+85+ 85+65+85+ 85+65+85+ 85+
Free personal care in all settings47.00 56.3071.3095.50 96.30131.2024.60 28.4031.30
Free personal care for high/very high needs home care users 12.4013.2014.10 0.000.000.00 18.1022.4023.50
Partnership model, 33% guarantee 12.90 16.6025.7037.30 38.1061.101.60 1.702.10
Partnership model, AA/DLA (65+), discontinued -16.10-8.200.80 37.3038.1061.10 -40.80-40.50-39.50
Free personal care + LA fee rise43.80 52.1064.3085.30 86.30112.6024.60 28.4031.30
Partnership + fee rise10.10 13.1019.2028.40 29.1044.701.60 1.702.10
Partnership with AA/DLA (65+) discontinued + fee rise -19.00-11.90-5.80 28.4029.1044.70 -40.80-40.50-39.50
Free personal care in all settings under Wanless patterns of care 44.6054.6065.70 96.00101.70135.70 31.8038.3042.60
Partnership under Wanless patterns of care 8.7011.5017.50 36.8040.0062.90 1.701.702.50
Partnership with AA/DLA (65+) discontinued under Wanless patterns of care -18.90-13.00-10.40 36.8040.0062.90 -32.70-31.20-34.70

Source: CARESIM model





How do Financial Gains and Losses Vary by Income Group?

  28.  To assess how the financial effects of the reform options for care recipients are likely to vary across different income groups, the average gains within each fifth (quintile) of the income distribution are compared[41]. Care recipients are classified according to the quintile of the income distribution in which their income falls, where that distribution is specific to five-year age group. In the analysis that follows, someone classified as having an income in the highest income quintile has a high income relative to people of a similar age. This may not be a high income relative to the total population. When compared to the total population income distribution, older people are in general concentrated in the second and third quintiles of the income distribution, and this is even more pronounced for those aged 85 and over.

  29.  Financial gains and losses are measured by changes in users' disposable incomes after meeting care costs[42]. The distribution of these gains and losses are shown for care recipients aged 85 and over, in figures 2 (2007) and 3 (2027).

Figure 2


Figure 3


Source: CARESIM model

  30.  Under all the options, gains are highest and losses smallest in the top income group; gains are smallest and losses largest in the lowest income group. In 2007 care recipients (aged 85+) in the top income group gain around £90 a week from free personal care, some £20 a week from the partnership options and lose a maximum of £8 a week under the partnership models when AA/DLA is withdrawn. Care recipients in the lowest income group gain £20-£25 a week from free personal care, between £3 and £9 a week from partnership options which retain AA/DLA and lose up to £26 a week on average, when AA/DLA is withdrawn.

  31.  The picture in 2027 is similar to that in 2007, except that the extent to which the highest income group gain compared with a continuation of the current funding system is more marked, and differences in gains/losses across the lowest three income groups are less pronounced.

  32.  The distributional results take no account of how the revenue to finance the reform options might be raised, yet these may affect the results. In past work, we have examined the effect of financing free personal care by an increase in the higher rate of income tax and found that gains from free personal care would in fact be redistributive (Hancock et al 2007: 79). Under the partnership options where AA and DLA for those aged 65 and over is withdrawn, we have not shown the effect for people who are not receiving care services who would also lose their AA or DLA.

  33.  There are of course many different ways in which revenue could be raised to finance extra public spending on long-term care and they will differ in their distributional effects. Analysis of a range of revenue raising options is planned for the future as part of MAP2030.

DISCUSSION OF FINDINGS

  34.  A key finding is that current public expenditure would be lower by approximately £4 billion if disability benefits for older people were discontinued, even if a partnership model was introduced. The Green Paper does not contain much detail about its proposals and the modelling here has therefore relied on an interpretation of its intentions. For example, the Green Paper proposes to improve preventative services, such as re-ablement and tele-care, but these were not included in the modelling here because there is no indication of the extent of increases in spending on these services that might be implied. Nevertheless, if we had included these non-personal care costs, public expenditure costs would have been higher. Public expenditure costs would also have been higher in the initial period after the introduction of the reforms, had allowance been made here for some phasing-in of the changes. Finally, the detailed implementation of any withdrawal of disability benefits for older people, such as a targeting of the withdrawal, would also affect public expenditure costs and distributional effects.

  35.  However, there are also reasons why a discontinuation of disability benefits would reduce public long-term care expenditure under a partnership model. One reason is that disabled older people use disability benefits to pay for other disability-related expenditure, such as extra heating and special diets. A second reason is that disability benefits are a universal entitlement and all disabled older people, including those with informal carers, receive them. However, the Partnership model would not necessarily be universal in this sense. The Green Paper seems ambiguous on this point. Following some statements in the Green Paper (HMG 2009: 103-104), it has been assumed here that there would be a continuation of existing eligibility criteria, under which disabled older people with informal carers (including some of the most severely disabled in the community) are regarded as "less eligible" for publicly-funded long-term care than those without informal carers (Royal Commission on Long Term Care 1999, FACs 2003, CSCI 2008). Elsewhere, the Green Paper seems to suggest that the new National Care Service might include disabled older people with informal carers (HMG 2009: 119). If the modelling were to assume a genuinely universal entitlement to publicly-funded social care by all disabled people, public expenditure on long-term care would be greater and more of the public expenditure saved from withdrawing AA/DLA would be transferred to social care funding.

  36.  Our modelling highlights the importance of the (as yet unspecified) details of how, under the Partnership Model, the means tests for the part of the care costs not met automatically by the state would operate, particularly if AA/DLA are withdrawn. If for example, LAs were required to disregard DRE even with AA/DLA withdrawn, home care users would lose less or even gain under this scenario. Likewise, if the means test applied to the two-thirds of care costs for care home residents were more generous than at present, the proposals would benefit those on lower incomes more than our results suggest.

REFERENCESAge Concern Scotland (2003) Free for All? Age Concern Scotland's Report into Free

Personal and Nursing Care, Age Concern Scotland.

CSCI (Commission for Social Care Inspection) (2008) Cutting the Cake Fairly: CSCI Review of Eligibility Criteria for Social Care. London: CSCI.

Department of Health (2003) Fair Access to Care Services. Guidance on Eligibility Criteria for Adult Social Care. London: Department of Health.

Department of Health (2009) Impact Assessment of the Care and Support Green Paper. London: Department of Health. http://www.dh.gov.uk/prod_consum_dh/groups/dh_digitalassets/documents/digitalasset/dh_102731.pdf

Forder J and Fernandez J-L (2009) Analysing the Costs and Benefits of Social Care Funding Arrangements in England: Technical Report. PSSRU Discussion Paper 2644. http://www.pssru.ac.uk/pdf/dp2644.pdf

Hancock R, Comas-Herrera A Wittenberg R and Pickard L (2003) Who will pay for long-term care in the UK? Projections linking macro- and micro-simulation models. Fiscal Studies, 24(4) pp 387-426.

Hancock, R, Pickard, L, Wittenberg, R, Comas-Herrera, A, Juarez-Garcia, A, King, D & Malley, J (2007) Paying For Long-Term Care for Older People in the UK: Modelling the Costs and Distributional Effects of a Range of Options. Report to the Nuffield Foundation. PSSRU Discussion Paper 2336/2.

(http://www.pssru.ac.uk/pdf/dp2336_2.pdf)

HMG (2009) Shaping the Future of Care Together, CM 7673. London: The Stationery Office

Royal Commission on Long Term Care (1999) With Respect to Old Age. Cm 4192. London: The Stationery Office.

Wanless D (2006) Securing Good Care for Older People: Taking a Long-Term View. London: King's Fund.

Wittenberg R, Comas-Herrera A, King D, Malley, J, Pickard L and Darton R (2006) Future Demand for Long-Term Care, 2002 to 2041: Projections of Demand for Long-Term Care for Older People in England, PSSRU Discussion Paper 2330, March 2006 (www.pssru.ac.uk/pdf/dp2330.pdf).

November 2009







31   The modelling of all options considered here assumes continuation of existing eligibility criteria relating to disabled older people who receive informal care. Disabled older people with informal carers are currently treated as "less eligible" for publicly-funded support than those without (DH 2003). Some implications of this are discussed at the end. Back

32   In nursing homes there is now also a standard NHS contribution to the costs of nursing care. Back

33   The Green Paper also indicates that there would be investment in prevention, such as investment in re-ablement and tele-care (HMG 2009: 51-2, 103). This has not been included in the modelling here. Back

34   Although the options suggested by the Green Paper, modelled here, relate to the partnership option, it should be noted that there are similarities between the comprehensive option and free personal care. Back

35   A similar benefit which can be received by people aged over 65 who started to receive it before reaching that age for over 65s Back

36   In Scotland, when a "fixed care costs" version of free personal care was introduced, private and voluntary care providers were reluctant to provide places for older people under "integrated" contracts, under which local authorities managed the contractual arrangements with care homes on behalf of older people receiving free personal care (Age Concern Scotland, 2003: 19-20). The underlying problem, that local authority fees are lower than self-funders' fees, is addressed here by allowing for scenarios in which local authorities increase the fees they offer to care home owners. Back

37   ADL stands for Activities of Daily Living. Difficulties in or inability to perform ADLs is a common measure of the need for care. Back

38   The modelling looks at the effects if AA and DLA for people aged 65 and over were withdrawn in 2007 and therefore does not take into account transitional arrangements, which the Green Paper suggests would be introduced (see £7 above). Back

39   A reduction in net public expenditure costs is also shown in the impact assessment prepared by the Department of Health, which shows a reduction in public expenditure of £1.1 billion in 2024 under the partnership option with withdrawal of some disability benefits (DH 2009: 3). This is a smaller reduction than that shown here in 2027, but the precise reasons for the difference are difficult to ascertain because the DH has not yet published details of its modelling of the reform options. Back

40   DRE can include eg higher transport, laundry and heating costs attributable to the person's disability. Back

41   Income is the net income (before housing costs) of the family unit (single older person or older couple) that they would receive when living in their own homes without any care needs. The before housing costs definition is not identical to that used in the annual National Statistics publication "Households Below Average Income". Here we do not include Housing Benefit (HB) as income on the grounds that high HB is at least in part the result of high rent so that to include it in income, without deducting rent, may exaggerate the economic well-being of people with high rents. Income is adjusted for family size using the OECD equivalence scale of 1 for the first adult, 0.5 for each subsequent person aged at least 14 years and 0.3 for each child aged under 14. Back

42   There may also be changes in users' wealth if capital is depleted at different rates under the different options. This is not taken into account explicitly. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2010
Prepared 12 March 2010