Social Care - Health Committee Contents


Examination of Witnesses (Question Numbers 180-199)

MR RAPHAEL WITTENBERG AND PROFESSOR CAROL JAGGER

5 NOVEMBER 2009

  Q180  Dr Taylor: So it gets more complicated by the moment, does it not?

  Mr Wittenberg: Yes. In the model in which I have been involved we try to look separately at different groups and think about the overlap but yes.

  Q181  Dr Taylor: Is there any way of forecasting how much costs are going to go up?

  Mr Wittenberg: Certainly we do that although we do emphasise that we are not producing forecasts in the sense that there is clearly no way of being sure what is going to happen let alone people's expectations and wishes. What we do is to produce what we call projections. That is to say that we say "Supposing X, Y and Z, then how much would expenditure be?" That is basically the approach we take. For example, in the modelling which has been done for the Green Paper and earlier modelling, we said, "Let's assume the numbers of older people go up in line with the official ONS population projections. Let us assume that the pattern of care remains the same, that the probability of people with some particular characteristics receiving care is constant. Let us also assume that the unit cost of care, that is to say the cost of an hour's home care, rises by 2% a year in real terms" or an alternative can be looked at. On that basis, yes, we have produced projections and we produced them originally for the Royal Commission for a whole lot of different government agencies and the EU since then.

  Q182  Dr Taylor: What is the margin of error?

  Mr Wittenberg: It is not possible to give a statistical answer to that. It is not as though one were just looking at, say, the confidence intervals of a particular survey. Of course those exist, it is really that one has, with each of these parameters we have been talking about, the numbers of older people, disability, household composition, unit costs, to think what the plausible range is in each. Then you either vary them one after the other, which is what we have done, or you take all the scenarios. We try to look at a minimum and a maximum; the range is great and the biggest factor is the uncertainty about unit costs because clearly our base case at the moment is to assume unit costs rising about 2% a year in real terms but that may be rather high.

  Q183  Dr Taylor: We are coming on to unit costs. One encouraging comment was from Professor Jagger that some degree of obesity is protective in older people. As somebody with a BMI above where it should be, I find that very reassuring.

  Professor Jagger: Overweight rather than obese.

  Q184  Sandra Gidley: I just want to pick up on unit costs. You said that they would be increasing 2% a year in real terms. Can you clarify the reasons for saying that? Why is it not just in line with inflation? Is it more people or are there actual costs? No, if it is unit costs it is the cost per person.

  Mr Wittenberg: Actually by unit cost, let us say of home care, I mean the cost per hour. Home care is very, very labour intensive. In general terms—we are not talking about the next couple of years but well ahead—the Treasury have assumed that productivity and average earnings will both rise by 2% a year in real terms. This is for very long-term projections over the next 50 years and we have taken that as our base case. Of course that may not be the case and there are lots of reasons why it may not be. Particularly if one uses the 2% assumption and particularly assuming that the average earnings of care staff will go up in line with the average earnings of the labour force generally, that may not be the case. I have seen people arguing it both ways; some say care staff earnings might rise faster and that could depend on future policy on the national minimum wage, for example. So it is partly policy related. Another view is that because the qualifications required are not very high and there may be fewer jobs over time for people with lower qualifications, the earnings of this group may rise more slowly. There are also issues about expectations. Obviously if quality of care rises, that may or may not affect the unit costs.

  Q185  Sandra Gidley: Basically you do not have a clue by the sound of it.

  Mr Wittenberg: There is no categorical answer. We can look at past trends and clearly the real unit costs, particularly of care home provision, have risen but there may be other reasons there as well. It is difficult. Sensitivity analysis is wise and in the short term, given the present state of the public finances, one might reasonably question whether 2% was too high and perhaps the short term and the long term may differ.

  Q186  Sandra Gidley: You also have a demanding baby-boom generation coming up who may be demanding improved services. Do you not think that is likely as well?

  Mr Wittenberg: Yes and there has been quite a lot of commentary on that and the general view, from what I have read, is that is likely, although I have to say that with home care that is more likely to affect the numbers of hours per week perhaps than unit costs. With residential care of course it could affect the weekly cost in terms of the facilities of the care home.

  Q187  Sandra Gidley: What is going to be the impact of personalisation on the unit costs of long-term care services?

  Mr Wittenberg: There are two possible issues here. Talking again about the cost of one hour's home care, what one might suppose is, if block or bulk purchasing by councils, some of whom have quite a bit of a monopsony power, that is to say they are the only big purchaser in their area, that replacement of that by lots of individual micropurchasing might give providers the opportunity to raise prices through the diversification of purchasing. There may be ways of handling that and it could be that people could come together and purchase collectively or the council could help them do that. There is a possibility of rising unit costs from that source. Part of the evidence would be from the care sector where it is well known that in general self-funders seem to be charged more than the local authority pays. There is one set of issues about unit costs in that sense of the word. There is another set of issues about whether the weekly care costs would be higher for people receiving personal budgets, let us say, rather than people receiving conventional services and that is something that the evaluation of the Ibsen project examined. There is the second question as to whether the weekly care costs will be different under individual budgets, now personal budgets, from conventional packages of care. That is one of the issues addressed in the evaluation of the individual budget pilots in which the PSSRU and others were involved. They found no statistically significant difference, as I understand it, in the average weekly cost between the sample who were receiving individual budgets and the control sample, the comparison with people who are not.

  Q188  Sandra Gidley: Were the individual budgets higher?

  Mr Wittenberg: No, there was no statistically significant difference.

  Q189  Sandra Gidley: Sorry, I thought you said they were higher.

  Mr Wittenberg: There was no statistically significant difference as I understand it.

  Q190  Sandra Gidley: Would high rises in unit costs impact on the suitability of the different funding systems in the Green Paper?

  Mr Wittenberg: I am just thinking whether there is a link between those two matters. Personalisation could apply on any of the funding systems in principle and therefore the issue of whether personalisation would increase unit costs and the issue of whether the funding mechanism would do something are not the same. An issue which could arise for the comprehensive scheme, which arose in Scotland with free personal care, is what happens if the local authority were to seek to purchase for everybody, the people who are now privately funded as well as those who are publicly funded. My understanding of what happened in Scotland is that care home providers were very unhappy about that and that on the whole has not happened. Again, I suppose this could arise under any of the funding systems so maybe the two issues are not that closely related.

  Sandra Gidley: So you do not think there will be a connection.

  Q191  Dr Stoate: When we talk about people living on their own and having greater dependency needs in the future, someone always talks about the dependency ratio between the number of people economically active compared with those economically inactive and how we sort that out. Is that always the case? There are clearly younger people who are not economically active and older people who are. What is your view about whether that is a real issue or not?

  Mr Wittenberg: The dependency ratio I have come across is often simply the population ratio of numbers of people over 65, over state pension age, and either the rest of the population or the rest of the working-age population. I think that people seem to find that, as far as I can tell, a very useful, very quick summary indicator of the changing balance between younger and older people. Clearly when one is looking at long-term care demand one has to go rather deeper than that and realise several things. One is that 40% of the gross expenditure on social care actually relates to people below 65. Secondly, of the 60% that relates to people above 65, the vast majority actually relates to people above 75 and in many cases even older than that. I find the dependency ratio perhaps very useful as a headline starting figure but clearly in doing detailed work we need more detail. In addition it has been pointed out that there are plenty of people working beyond state pension age and there are plenty of people who have retired before it.

  Q192  Dr Stoate: Obviously productivity tends to change over time, probably tends to increase in supply over time and so as we go along outwardly improves. Does this have implications for affordability, given that the country will presumably become wealthier over time?

  Mr Wittenberg: Yes. When we presented our results from the model we have done we presented projected expenditure relative to gross domestic product, national income for that very reason. What complicates it, as we discussed earlier, is the real rise in unit costs. There is in a way a link between these things. The reason, for example, that the Treasury projects in the long run—I am not talking about now of course—rises in economic growth of GDP is partly issues of changes in the working-age population, in the workforce, and partly increases in the per person productivity and that in turn then feeds into issues about average earnings and unit costs. Absolutely clearly one would hope and expect that when we come out of the recession the economy would grow again and that would affect affordability, but one has to recognise that the same forces may cause the unit costs to rise. The two are interrelated.

  Q193  Stephen Hesford: Models and projections and predictions and forecasts. Can you unpick what they are? What should we really be talking about? Should we be talking about models, predictions or projections? What do you like to talk about?

  Mr Wittenberg: I personally like to talk about projections really because I feel that is what the PSSRU, along with colleagues at Leicester and the University of East Anglia and elsewhere, have been doing. By which I mean that we are not saying this is what will definitely happen because that, for reasons we have discussed, is impossible. We would rather say "On this set of assumptions this is what we think expenditure would be like. On that set of assumptions it will be something else. This is what I would understand by projections. It is on a set of assumptions and scenarios about some of the drivers of expenditure. I personally talk about projections.

  Q194  Stephen Hesford: In an historical sense, I do not know how long you have been with the Department or the Civil Service, maybe some years—

  Mr Wittenberg: Yes.

  Q195  Stephen Hesford: You have seen a few projections and a few outcomes and the two may or may not be the same thing and they may be vastly different. How confident, based on your experience over time, have you become in your projections as against what you know then actually happened?

  Mr Wittenberg: That is something we have sometimes been asked but never really pursued, to check whether the projections produced for the Royal Commission met with reality and we have not done this partly because we know that so many factors have changed that we did not know about at the time. It is doubtful that would be a useful exercise.

  Q196  Stephen Hesford: From whose point of view? Your sanity?

  Mr Wittenberg: No, from the point of view of commenting on whether the model is good or not. Because if a lot has changed—

  Q197  Stephen Hesford: Sorry, but you said model now not projection.

  Mr Wittenberg: Right. Maybe I should say the model is the piece of software, for micro-simulation it is a piece of computer code for the aggregate model is an Excel spreadsheet. What is sitting on the computer is the model and its output is the projection. I am sorry if I did not explain that earlier.

  Q198  Stephen Hesford: You do your best and that is where we are.

  Mr Wittenberg: Yes.

  Q199  Stephen Hesford: You make the assumptions and then unforeseeable variables which you have just spoken about, changes in mortality, morbidity, fashion, risk factors, medical progress, migration, inward, outward, birth rate all these things. What is the margin? Do different variables have different margins of error so that some are more confident than others or are they all the same?

  Mr Wittenberg: They are not all the same. It is something we have looked at quite a bit because it does depend how far ahead one makes the projections for; I should make that point. The projections we have produced, particularly to look ahead say 20 years or more, become particularly sensitive to assumptions about unit costs; the 2% we were talking about earlier versus 1% obviously compounds over a 20-year period and that becomes enormous. By contrast, we have looked at life expectancy, we have looked at the various official projections; ONS produce low and high life expectancy projections and by contrast the difference is considerable but it is not on that same scale. We did have a bit of dialogue with ONS about that and they said that was a function of what they felt were appropriate scenarios. Our colleague at LSE, for example, Professor Mike Murphy, has produced a yet higher life expectancy assumption and has explained at a recent seminar his reasons for that, but even that is not certain. The unit costs appear to be particularly important. Looking ahead a long period of time again the dependency rates, the work we have done with Carol Jagger, it is clearly very important that over a long period of time, if there is compression or expansion or morbidity, that matters. Informal care? We have found that a bit less, if there were relatively small changes in the supply, but again it depends hugely on assumptions one makes about what would substitute for informal care. Similarly, if we get a change in rates between residential and home care that will not make a huge difference unless one believes that the home care package is going to be a lot cheaper or a lot more expensive. My feeling is that the biggest issues really are the unit costs and the disability dependency issues in terms of sensitivity and perhaps I should have said expectations as well which are of course almost unknowable.



 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2010
Prepared 12 March 2010