Commissioning - Health Committee Contents


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 200 - 219)

THURSDAY 14 JANUARY 2010

PROFESSOR ANDREW STREET AND DR PETER BRAMBLEBY

  Q200  Dr Stoate: Can you explain up-coding to us and how much of a problem it is in your experience?

  Dr Brambleby: To give a simple illustration, a different tariff is paid for someone who has an operation to replace a faulty hip and an individual who has it done with complications. The difference in price can be in the order of £1,000. If you were a clinical coder in a hospital with an incentive to protect your income, possibly for very laudable purposes, you would scrutinise very carefully to see whether there was any mention of diabetes, in which case you could add it as a second diagnostic field. The price will then go up. But the reality may be that the additional cost of that episode from the patient's diabetes is not commensurate with the amount of money the trust has just attracted. That is up-coding. If it was deliberately exploited to the maximum allowed by the rules that would be gaming, but if there was a deliberate attempt to add codes that did not exist that would be fraud.

  Q201  Dr Stoate: Do you have much evidence that gaming is going on?

  Dr Brambleby: The longitudinal trends we observe would suggest that trusts use the maximum flexibility available to them to attract the greatest possible cost for each episode, so if that is gaming perhaps. Prices were set on the basis of the typical experience of a typical patient and that is why different bands and healthcare-related groups were put in place. However, once the price has been set there is an incentive to move the goal posts and to reclassify people for the maximum income.

  Q202  Dr Stoate: Do you have much evidence of cost shifting where a hospital sends someone back to the GP with a long list of things which effectively that GP pays for subsequently? I have seen examples of it.

  Dr Brambleby: We do not see as much of it now as we did in the old days. There is now a developing sense of common purpose. At the end of the day there is one NHS budget and not much point in cost shifting, but there is competition and so if anything there is reluctance to move people around the system because then you lose your tariff-paying customers.

  Q203  Dr Stoate: Can you explain what tariff granularity is?

  Dr Brambleby: I believe it means the degree of specification within the tariff. If you had a tariff for an orthopaedic episode it would have very low granularity. If you could break your orthopaedic episodes into hips, knees, carpel tunnels and so forth that would increase the granularity; you would have smaller grains. I think that is what it means, but it is an ugly term.

  Q204  Charlotte Atkins: What impact has payment by results had on the quality of care for patients?

  Dr Brambleby: It is definitely mixed. There is an upside and very definite downside. On the upside one of the rationales, such as there are, behind payment by results is to encourage different providers to compete on the basis of quality because the price is fixed. It harks back to the question about fixed prices put by Mr Scott. In that regard it has been a stimulus to improve quality. On the downside it has not encouraged us to look at, or indeed commission, whole pathways or patterns of care and that can have a negative impact. To illustrate that, in my patch we had evidence recently from a general practitioner who said he wished a patient could have ended his days in his own home but because of the disinvestment in the community nursing set-up that community support was not available. Therefore, the person died in a place not of his or her choice, and at greater expense. That is an example of an anomaly in the system that adversely impacts on the patient's quality of care.

  Q205  Charlotte Atkins: In a hospital context there is no incentive for the hospital to discharge the patient as quickly as possible. The patient may be lying on the bed waiting for a doctor or consultant to come along to do whatever has to be done. Very often there does not appear to be very much urgency in terms of co-ordinating all the tests and consultations that a patient needs once in hospital. Payment by results does not really help us achieve a more co-ordinated and focused pathway of care.

  Dr Brambleby: Yes and no. That takes us into a technical area of trim points. For example, a patient may be an emergency admission for a chronic obstructive pulmonary disease that has flared up. Whether the patient stays for three days or 17 days we pay the same tariff. In that case there will be a very strong incentive on the hospital for the stay to be a shorter space of time because it is not getting any added income, but it becomes difficult at the trim points. The gap between two and three days is very substantial; it is more than £1,000. Therefore, there is a disincentive to keep the patient for a shorter time because one loses money potentially. At the other end, once the 15 or 17 days are up thereafter it is a daily rate, so there are mixed incentives for either keeping or discharging the patient. To amplify that just a little, imagine a system where chronic obstructive pulmonary disease patients stay on average a week but the trust wants to get it down nearer to four or five days and quite sensibly improve efficiency. If it does that simply by referring the patient to a community provider who will pick up the rest of the patient's recuperation and a new tariff and cost begins one can end up adding more cost to the system. That takes us from trim points to "bundling" and "unbundling" tariffs. Those of us who work at the sharp end of commissioning would like to see much more commissioning of patterns and pathways rather than simply episodes of care.

  Q206  Charlotte Atkins: Can you identify any benefits from payment by results?

  Dr Brambleby: There have been some. I am not by any means alone as a clinician working in the NHS to be deeply ambivalent about payment by results. We feel that it was a sincere and partially successful attempt to address the wrong question. What we see as the mission, which is hidden or imbedded in "co-mission-ing", is to improve the health of the population, not just secure healthcare for the population and not necessarily make the hospitals the pivot or the main gravitational attraction for that care. It is the overall health of the patient for which we want to commission. To that end payment by results has been a distraction and distortion and is tangibly counter-productive in some cases.

  Q207  Sandra Gidley: You suggested that payment by results is "too blunt" a tool for many clinical pathways and that "purchasers have to pay the tariff whether the patient is better or worse, alive or dead." What system would you have instead?

  Dr Brambleby: To set some reference or normative costs for a typical admission would be very helpful. Had payment by results stopped at a guide price or a starter for negotiating—maybe a maximum price—it would have taken us some way. Where it fell down was that, first, it was far too late; we needed it right at the beginning of the internal market and long before we started to talk to external providers. I should like to come back to the point about the rationale for payment by results. A lot of it was to bring the external independent sector into the market on a level playing field. The major flaw in it was that it did not apply right across the health system; it did not even apply right across the hospital system. In the early years it was set just for planned operations and procedures in the hospital context, not the rest. Therefore, for it to be successful and achieve what we hoped it would and reach its considerable potential tariffs should have been set right across the board for mental health episodes and community episodes. A quick check should have been made that if we multiplied the current volume of activity by the tariffs set for that activity did it come close to the money available so it did not break the system? Did we have the IT in place to monitor all of this? It should have been piloted in one or two areas to check that it worked and then launched. That would have made a lot of sense. It could then have achieved its full potential. If I give an analogy which I think is helpful, it is a bit like changing from driving on the left to driving on the right. If you are to do it you do not simply say it should be introduced for buses and lorries for the first six months to see how it goes. I do not believe that is a ridiculous analogy because that is what it has felt like. It has not been gaming per se. I do not believe there has been a lot of deliberate manipulation of the system for ulterior or narrow ends but the system has led to people bumping into one another.

  Q208  Sandra Gidley: You wanted to come back to external providers.

  Dr Brambleby: I think I managed to slip it in. Having said that, it was explained to us that one of the principal rationales for introducing payment by results and to fix the tariff and make it non-negotiable was to give new entrants into the healthcare field the security of income for, say, a three-year period which would justify their investment in capital and staff to enter the market in the hope that contestability and competition would drive up quality. In the end it had an adverse impact to a degree; it got in the way of quality, flexibility and choice.

  Q209  Dr Naysmith: When you answer Charlotte Atkins' question earlier I got the impression that your ambivalence about the PbR system was more to do with the fact that you hoped we would move into the community and more into public health and this system really was not doing that. Is that a fair summary of what you said?

  Dr Brambleby: It is a very fair summary. They key word in your question is "hoped". We had hopes and expectations.

  Q210  Dr Naysmith: It is the government's stated aim to shift more care out of hospitals and into the community and yet it seems PbR is having exactly the opposite effect. Is that how you see it?

  Dr Brambleby: It is a question of degree, but generally that is how I see it. There are some unnecessary impediments to the development of community services and the community setting has suffered hitherto and is now in a weaker position; it starts from a poorer base than it might have done, say, five, seven, 10 or 12 years ago.

  Q211  Dr Naysmith: How do you believe PbR sits with other recent reforms such as practice-based commissioning and foundation trust hospitals?

  Dr Brambleby: Those are two very different questions. I am a fan of practice-based comissioning. It would add another clinical voice to the discussion which should be about "co-mission-ing". It takes us back to the "mission2. I do not suggest for a moment that the clinical voice should be the dominant one. There should be a partnership between the patient voice, the policymaker who holds the purse strings and the clinician. But what it does is address, to a degree, the secondary/primary imbalance. GPs are ideally placed to assess the need of their practice population, to do something about it by prescribing, referring or whatever, to assess the quality in real time because they see their patients afterwards, and, as an addition to that mix, to have some knowledge and control over the budget. I do not go as far as to say they have to own the budget but they certainly have to see it, recognise it and own the opportunity cost, to use the jargon. As to foundation trusts, I think that if a local hospital has a good connection with its local population—it is often a major feature of local population, and there are friends of local hospitals up and down the country—that can only be a good thing. If the freedoms that they enjoy are used responsibly and there is a sense of common purpose about meeting local health needs within the available budget, fine.

  Q212  Dr Naysmith: Do you believe that PbR facilitates the standards of commissioning that world-class commissioning now calls for, or is it an obstacle?

  Dr Brambleby: Perhaps I should declare an interest in that I was invited by Mark Britnell and Gary Belfield to have some input into defining the World-Class Commissioning values and competencies.

  Q213  Dr Naysmith: That makes you more of an expert, so we are glad to hear it.

  Dr Brambleby: I do not know about "expert". But it started very well with defining some of the values in World-Class Commissioning. As I have seen from the evidence of Mr Britnell to your Committee, it was about adding life to people's years as well as years to people's lives. That takes us into education, housing, leisure opportunities, having a job and being all you can be. It is an awful lot more than simply the delivery of caring services when you are ill. Therefore, the values were good. Commissioning competencies made a helpful attempt to define, belatedly, the syllabus. If you wanted to be a commissioner and learn your craft here were the competencies which as an individual or organisation you needed to cover to be good at what you did. I believe that has been sidetracked into an understanding of commissioning as the procurement of secondary healthcare services. It has lost its way slightly in overemphasis on the transactional side of commissioning and has not sufficiently emphasised the partnership approach and a much wider health improvement agenda rather than a healthcare delivery agenda.

  Q214  Charlotte Atkins: Senior officials of the Department of Health have told us that commissioning did not really start to work until two years ago. Is that a fair assessment?

  Dr Brambleby: Yes; it had not begun to realise anything like its true potential until two years ago.

  Q215  Charlotte Atkins: Why do you think that was?

  Dr Brambleby: That is a key question. I think it would be interesting to ask people to define what they mean by "commissioning" because many see it as the procurement of secondary healthcare. They use it synonymously with purchasing and payment but it is different. It was explained to me by one of my trainers when I came into this area. Think of the difference between commissioning a painting and purchasing it. There is a totally different relationship between the artist and the person who holds the funds. As someone who has committed his career to the commissioning function I have been waiting eagerly for it to start for the past 19 years.

  Q216  Charlotte Atkins: Is that because people are just not skilled enough in commissioning the right things, or do you think the levers are not right?

  Dr Brambleby: The skills are abundant. The NHS is blessed with innovative people with good ideas and commissioning could fly. What has happened is that we have not managed between ourselves either to construct a system that really liberates that creativity and local accountability, shaping local pathways to local needs within a finite budget—we could go a long way but the system sometimes gets in our way—or have sufficient ambition to go for the available levers. It is a very rich question and a very mixed answer. It has left us with very mixed patterns across the country.

  Q217  Charlotte Atkins: Presumably, it varies around the country; it is not uniquely good or bad. In different parts of the country different commissioners do a better or worse job?

  Dr Brambleby: Exactly so. If I may venture an opinion to illustrate how asking new questions leads to new answers, there is an approach to commissioning practised in other countries round the world, some parts of Canada being a good example. It is called "programme budgeting" which is sometimes linked to "marginal analysis". Here the proposition is a very simple one. Instead of a PCT asking how much is spent on this or that hospital, prescribing general practice and community services, the question is how much is spent on mental health, cancer and maternity services, etc, across the board. That should not be a difficult question but at the moment people struggle to answer it. On the principle that it is better to light a candle than curse the darkness there are some enthusiasts, of whom I claim to be one, who say we should see if we can construct that debate. It is timely to raise it because today on the Department of Health's website the 2008-09 returns from every PCT in the country have just been posted. Every PCT in the country has declared where it estimates it has spent its resources in that year on mental health, maternity and so on, that is, the 20 chapters of the international classification of diseases. If we could correlate the programme objectives and the providers' objectives we would be an awfully long way down the road of being able to account for where the money was going and do more good with it. For example, I should not look at Scarborough Hospital simply as a £100 million-plus trust near the coast; I should think of it as 6% of our cancer programme, 20% of our maternity programme and so on. Every year we should have a discussion at the PCT about what we want to do for mental health and maternity and therefore what we want our various hospitals to contribute, or our GPs and community services to contribute. "Is everybody happy with that? Do patients agree with that?" If so, we let the contracts and then on a monthly or annual basis we ask: "How are mental health and maternity are getting on? Is it costing what we thought? What will we do if it is going adrift? Is it delivering the outcomes we hoped for?" There is a better way.

  Q218  Charlotte Atkins: Do you believe World-Class Commissioning has improved patient care?

  Dr Brambleby: To a degree, yes, but it is nowhere near its full potential. Is it sufficiently complete and finished as an exercise? No.

  Q219  Charlotte Atkins: What needs to happen to take it to completion?

  Dr Brambleby: I believe there needs to be a re-attunement and re-engagement in what the mission for commissioning is, to get everybody on the same page. "Are we a national health service or a national healthcare procurement business?" "What is the dominant theme and therefore what is the model?" If we are a health improvement business it takes us into the realms of practice-based commissioning and much closer partnership working with local authorities which can have a very significant impact on how well and how long people live. Take for example educational attainment. It takes one to a different model from the one being pursued fairly aggressively with an entire competency based on whether the market is being stimulated. It is a very market-oriented approach, whereas one could develop some of the earlier competencies such as: "Are you showing leadership? Are you engaging with your local community? Are you truly accountable and delivering what local people need?"


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2010
Prepared 8 April 2010