DFID's Programme in Bangladesh - International Development Committee Contents


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 80 - 99)

TUESDAY 1 DECEMBER 2009

PROFESSOR GEOF WOOD AND DR MARTIN GREELEY

  Q80  Hugh Bayley: DFID has a civil service training programme which I presume is there in the belief that if you have a professionally trained, capable civil service you help to deal with some of these problems of corruption. Is the theory right and how effective is the training in meeting the goal?

  Professor Wood: If I can take this because I evaluated this programme with one of the DFID output purpose reviews two years ago, in December 2007. I think you are referring to what is called the MATT2 programme, Management at the Top, and this is a programme which is trying to create a critical mass of committed, like-minded senior civil servants at joint secretary and above, particularly identifying those who are likely to rather rapidly move into strong positions. When I was leading this review that meant I did have quite a bit of contact both with the cohorts as well as with the Establishments Division and the reforms that they are trying to take there. On paper, I think there are lots of positives in this programme. I have been trying to say to DFID and Dhaka that they should not under-estimate the significance of this programme for all their other projects in Bangladesh because, in the end, if you are trying to have projects in relation to the Bangladesh government the reality of that is that you need to have a senior cadre of civil servants on your side sharing the same vocabulary, the same ideas and attempting to see them through. Yes, I was quite impressed with some of this cohort and very impressed with the training. I did have some criticisms because I felt that they were having a cohort of training in Bangladesh and then rather rapidly wanting them to do the same thing as has always been done in the past, and has always failed, which is then send them abroad. Sending them abroad is, frankly, a kind of treat for the civil servants, and their patrons in the Establishments Division resisted my attempts—and my attempts were quite strong in the final briefing—to withdraw that part of the programme in order to divert that funding into the building up of capacity in Bangladesh, whether it is the Institute of Government Studies in BRAC or whether it is the Public Administration Institute in Dhaka University, or whatever, in order to build the capacity in Bangladesh to take them through and maintain this critical mass and a kind of esprit de corps within it. I can only see that as a good move but I am not sure about the patronage/sending them abroad aspect of it.

  Dr Greeley: Just to add that the problem even when you have well-trained high-calibre civil servants is that there is wholesale change at the top within the civil service establishment when there is a change in government and political friends are appointed from within the establishment, so it is very frustrating for DFID and other supporters of civil service strengthening.

  Q81  Hugh Bayley: You both lead me into my next question. Governance is a very important context for development in that better governance tends to produce better development. You can look at Ghana versus the DRC if you like in Africa, which I know better, but, generally speaking, there has been a reluctance from DFID to plunge into dealing with governance deficits within the political establishment, within the Parliament or within political party structures. The Foreign Office does a bit of this but DFID not very much and yet in Bangladesh it is absolutely clear to me that unless you improve the standards in public life in the political parties and in the Parliament you will still have one of your two hands tied behind your back. DFID is putting £5 million or £6 million, quite a large sum of money, into developing the parliamentary and political structures. Do you think this is wise? Is it likely to pay dividends? What role do you think the Westminster Parliament and parties could play in supporting DFID's work in this field?

  Dr Greeley: I think if you look at the experience under the caretaker government where there were very deliberate attempts by those in office at the time to enforce political party reform, we see that in fact there was sufficient political leverage with the leadership in both the BNP and the Awami League to resist that, and even when the caretaker government went to extremes of jailing the leadership and otherwise putting them in difficulties, there was sufficient political clout in both parties to resist that. I find it difficult to imagine that even so influential a voice as the British Government's is really going to make very much difference to that, but I welcome the pressure, and I think that continuing to spend in that manner, encouraging reform, is what we should be doing, but do not expect to count your chickens.

  Q82  Hugh Bayley: Can I ask you to comment before Geof does himself on Geof's example of setting up an all-party group within the Parliament to look at poverty reduction. Are you aware of this initiative or other initiatives of this kind and would you put this in the category of "worth trying"?

  Dr Greeley: I think the all-parliamentary approach is good, for sure, but again I am not very hopeful about it. I rather prefer the line that Geof was suggesting that if we are looking at generational transitions within the party political leadership then it is possible to identify some likely winners from a governance perspective and a shrewd level of support but not overwhelming public endorsement would be very appropriate.

  Professor Wood: You are going to listen to Pierre Landell-Mills after us and I am sure he will have comments on this as well. Part of the problem clearly with an all-party parliamentary group idea, just to pick that up, is that we can be absolutely sure for the moment that the opposition will not play into this. You are a mixed group here from a range of parties. This does not happen in Bangladesh and one of the ways that the opposition parties attempt to de-legitimise any government in power of course is not to play ball in the Assembly, on the main floor of the house as well as the committees, so this is going to take a long time.[1] I think you can only do this if you are prepared to see it holistically as a combination of pressure from civil society, good journalism, holding MPs to account and asking them why they are not participating in some of the business that they should be as opposition MPs. I think we just have to modify our aspirations and ambitions here. One of the problems with the aid business generally is that it expects results too quickly. Obviously that is a problem for governments in our own country where we try to justify taxpayers' money against programmes of support that may take a long time to materialise.


  Q83  Chairman: I take that point but John Battle put that question specifically to the Prime Minister about having an anti-poverty committee, which she was enthusiastic about and said she was going to take forward, but what you are saying is, is there no way that pressure can be brought to bear on the opposition to say, "So you care so little about poverty you are not prepared to take part?"

  Professor Wood: Exactly.

  Q84  Chairman: Does that have any effect?

  Professor Wood: I think that is where the pressure has to be applied. There has to be an element of embarrassment-creating processes.

  Hugh Bayley: Thank you, that was very interesting.

  Q85  Richard Burden: Could we just examine for a minute how the extent to which providing basic services through NGOs fits into this whole picture of accountability and what that means. In the evidence that you have put forward and the things you have said you have described Bangladesh as a "franchised state". Perhaps you could say to us what you think the developmental implications are of that and to what extent the state, with all the accountability issues we have been talking about, actually does have an influence or control over the policy and the strategic direction of basic services even if not the actual delivery of them?

  Professor Wood: I suppose I ought to kick off since that is a reference to my arguments here. For those of you who may not have come across this it is just a simple point that I was making in the late 1990s that there is a bit of a contradiction between having a lot of donor aid supporting the NGO activity in Bangladesh and the growth of it and so on, particularly in the area of the delivery of basic services—education and health and so on—and at the same time the donors being concerned about governance. Because it seems to me that what you have is NGOs effectively taking on the functions of the state but in a non-statutory framework in which they have no statutory obligation to their clients; it is a voluntary relationship essentially, so you have this problem. I think this is a big development problem in Bangladesh because clearly Bangladesh is famous for, and has led the world in the creation of, a series of NGOs, some of whom are now international as well like BRAC, who have done huge scales of work and implementation and brought ideas and so on to Bangladesh. So there is a lot of praise to be given for that process, but it does seem to me ultimately that there is a danger in over-privileging NGOs as a target of aid and strategic partnerships for DFID, say, the World Bank and anybody else, because it seems to me that then you have a self-fulfilling prophecy in that you are undermining the capacity of the state and you are getting in between the relationship between citizen and state and reproducing that accountability issue. I would make one more point. I know that Martin Greeley has a lot of familiarity with BRAC, as indeed I do, and you may have been given copies of this book, and I saw Abed a few weeks ago in Dhaka myself, so there is huge respect for an organisation of this kind.[2] I do not think we are yet there with the thinking but I wonder whether we have to say with a society like Bangladesh perhaps the political settlement about policy and about the strategy and strategic priorities and implementation is one involving political party governance alongside large NGOs. However, at the moment when democratic parties are in power then they seek to marginalise the NGOs from the policy process as far as they can. Ironically, it is only when you have military governments that they are concerned to have strong alliances with NGOs as part of their reach-out to the constituency.


  Q86  Richard Burden: Maybe, Dr Greeley, you will have something to say about this. If that would be the kind of settlement that donors should be looking at, what in practical terms would that mean as far as donor policy is concerned? How would that be different to what happens now?

  Professor Wood: I think it is not realistic at the moment to propose to governing political parties that have won through the ballot box—and I think actually fairly in this last election—that they have got to share their winner-takes-all approach with a set of NGOs in a significant strategic way. However, it does raise this question—what do we think about NGOs? Are we saying that they are guides to policy, they are innovators, they show the way, but in the end they are not the ones to do the macro-delivery, or are we saying they are big enough and significant enough in Bangladesh to bring them far more into the policy and implementation process. I think that is the strategic dilemma.

  Q87  Richard Burden: And you ultimately come down on the second of those?

  Professor Wood: No, I think I come down ultimately on the first of actually hanging in there with democratic parties and state responsibilities.

  Chairman: I think we might pursue this in some more detail. Mark Hendrick?

  Q88  Mr Hendrick: Just on that point. You are saying the opposition are not playing ball and therefore they are not doing their job as an opposition. Government is not doing the things it should be doing because if it was doing them you would have no need for organisations like BRAC. When we were in Bangladesh and we met with BRAC, the head there Abed was saying that he does not want to get involved with governments because then he is showing political bias to one party or another party. How do you get round this?

  Professor Wood: I think he is right. That is why I opt for the first of the two solutions but I simply open up a second one.

  Q89  Mr Hendrick: If you are saying then let us not be reliant on NGOs, this is a job of government and government is not doing it, and we stop supporting NGOs like BRAC, then what is going to happen? The whole place is going to go even further down the drain, surely?

  Dr Greeley: We are not doing justice to NGO thinking on this issue. Abed and his colleagues at BRAC are extremely aware of the need for transition. If we take for example the education sector, last year DFID agreed to support a new programme with BRAC and BRAC put in a budget to the donors of over US $450 million and the donors rightly turned round to BRAC and said, "Why should we give you $450 million for primary education when we are also giving $800 million to the government under the primary education development programme, phase two, at the same time? What is the point in doing this?" BRAC had developed an idea of public/private partnership in their original documentation and this was very much a response to pressure from donors to demonstrate that they were working with government. In fact, we tore up that draft and we rewrote it completely because it is not up to the NGOs to say, "We are going to form a partnership with government." Government has to come to the NGOs and make that request, so what, in effect, happened in the outcome of all this was that BRAC said, "Okay, we will continue to provide education services where the government cannot reach, in remote areas, to ethnic minorities, to the poor. We will continue to support the training of government staff in the teaching programme and we will try to ensure that there is a process of transition so that in five years' time we will not be looking at BRAC schools but we will be looking at BRAC teacher training and BRAC support to government systems." I think they are very aware of it, but the timing of transition and the modalities of transition do depend upon initiatives from the government and there is a critical role for the donors to play in supporting that transition in ways which do not undermine the political neutrality of the NGOs.

  Q90  Andrew Stunell: This is a very interesting line of enquiry. We have focused rather on BRAC, which is clearly quite an exceptional organisation. There are of course many other NGOs operating in the education sector, for instance, and in some cases it seems to be almost the other way round in that the government does not really acknowledge the work that the NGOs are undertaking. Could you say something about that relationship between the government and NGOs in general when it comes to the delivery of health and education and whether that relationship is sufficiently robust?

  Dr Greeley: I think it is important to distinguish amongst the community of NGOs in Bangladesh. There are lots of them. What we have seen, for example in the education sector, was that upon occasion when the government decides that its chosen modality for service delivery is through the NGOs, as it has in some of its urban education programmes, that what happens is that politically minded individuals set up NGOs in order to access these programmes, and the record shows this has happened for example with major World Bank programmes in the education sector with really very, very poor outcomes for children. I think talking about NGOs in general is risky but if we talk about some of the bigger NGOs that have been there since shortly after independence, such as BRAC and some of the smaller partners which are supported and nurtured by international NGOs, then we are looking at organisations that can deliver quality services. I am a strong supporter of DFID and others providing them with resources to do that. It seems to me it is not reasonable that we should put achievement of the MDGs and the removal of extreme poverty on hold until the political process in Dhaka has sorted itself out, which may take a very long time.

  Q91  Andrew Stunell: Which way round does this relationship actually work? What seemed to us was that the NGOs spring up and then the government kind of accepts them or not rather than the government initiating a process, but tell me about these political NGOs, are they party-based NGOs?

  Professor Greeley: They are set up by individuals with connections to the political parties who are willing to pay to politicians to get access to financial resources through programmes such as the hard-to-reach out-of-school children programme.

  Q92  Andrew Stunell: So it is a way of siphoning off some money rather than delivering an education?

  Professor Greeley: It is a way of siphoning off some money. You have to be careful which NGOs you work with. It is a very mixed bag in Dhaka.

  Q93  Andrew Stunell: Do you think at the strategic level the government of Bangladesh has come to terms with how to form those relationships and monitor those relationships?

  Professor Greeley: No, it has not. It has an NGO watchdog which has had good leadership on occasion and which has had reasonable relationships with some of the bigger NGOs. It could potentially fulfil that role and be an effective watchdog. It has the law behind it, it has clout, but it is not trusted because it is perceived to be political in the way in which it goes about its business.

  Q94  Andrew Stunell: Does the government intend to have a pro-poor preference in terms of the way it supports NGOs in their programmes in different areas?

  Dr Greeley: Yes. If you take the example of their support to microfinance, the government runs a major apex body which supplies microfinance, targeted only at those NGOs which are targeting the poorest households. Government has been able to have quite a decisive influence, in fact, on the way in which a particular sector has developed and helped it to develop in a pro-poor way.

  Q95  Andrew Stunell: I think we were offered a fairly rose-tinted picture of the work that NGOs did on the one hand, in contrast to what the government was able to do on the other. You are painting perhaps a more realistic picture. Would you like to comment on where the advantage of governance lies in delivering a pro-poor policy in a rural village in Bangladesh between money channelled through an NGO and money channelled through, say, the Department of Education.

  Professor Wood: One issue that really has to be understood about Bangladesh, and it affects how you think about NGOs, in the way that Martin has been saying, but it also affects how you think about government, is that you have prevailing cultural forms of doing business. These are patron-client type relationships that stretch across the country and they are extended kinship groups controlling different bits of business and so on. You are never looking at open, transparent relationships in the way that projects are selected and in the way that money is managed and handled and invoiced and all the rest of it, and it is terribly important to acknowledge that NGOs are no more insulated, in the ways in which they work on the ground, from those prevailing cultural forms of doing business, than the government. There is an organisational culture which is strongly patron-client, strongly kinship/friendship/contact-based, and that operates, as it were, beneath the surface of the formality. That is the case for non-government organisations, as it for government. When we talk about issues of governance and democracy and accountability and so on, we are really talking about trying, as it were, to take formal political and development actors, detach them, as it were, from the prevailing cultural forms of doing business that surround them, and they of course have to meet those expectations and pressures within their own societies, within their own families, amongst their own clients, so you can have very flashy, formal-looking organisations at the apex, but the reality on the ground will always be influenced by these cultures of doing business. One of the things that we have particularly noted in research over the last few years is, for example, the phenomenon of the mastaan. I do not know whether anybody mentioned this to you, but we used to think of mastaan as simply gang leaders in urban situations (recognising that power in the countryside in the past was landlords and money lenders and so on) but we are now seeing what we call a `mastaanisation' of the countryside; that is to say, these political brokers connected to political parties and connected to business, connected to projects, contracts, engineers who are taking the big infrastructure contracts. The way in which that is done, the way in which labour is managed on rural works programmes and any contract, is all filtered through these kinds of relationships, and it is pervasive. That is why this is a long haul business and—while I remember to say it—why you need people in DFID in Dhaka who have that field exposure and understanding rather than keep churning people over on a three-year basis who really do not see all of that.

  Q96  Chairman: BRAC is such a unique organisation.

  Professor Wood: But not insulated from what I have just said.

  Q97  Chairman: No. That was part of my question. It is huge in Bangladesh and internationally, and there are a number of aspects of that we want to explore. On the point you have just made, before I ask a general question and then bring in John Battle, there is the Public Procurement Bill which is being brought through. I am anticipating your answer would be, "What a good idea, but it will take years to take effect," but what is your general view about how effective it can be?

  Professor Wood: For your efficiency, I suggest you really do ask that question to Pierre Landell-Mills.

  Q98  Chairman: All right, if you think so, we will come back to that. The meeting we had with Dr Abed. BRAC is an inspirational organisation, although perhaps a little paternalistic and patronising in some of its approaches, but it is difficult to imagine what Bangladesh would be like without it. DFID perhaps understandably said it wants a strategic alliance with it. You have partially answered that question, saying, "That's all very well, but you have to build the state up as well." Do you think DFID is in danger of going up the wrong track, or do you think it is possible to do that whilst building up the state or, indeed, necessary to do so? Is it also a shortcut: BRAC is so big, DFID is a big organisation, it is very easy to deal with BRAC, it saves all the trouble of dealing with lots of other NGOs (who are clients of BRAC in many cases.) Do you think DFID is moving on the right path there, or is it in danger of going down the wrong path?

  Dr Greeley: It would appear to be a sensible move from both DFID and BRAC's perspective, in that it should reduce the transactions cost of doing business. DFID has several different contracts with BRAC at the moment, supporting a variety of their programmes, but that could be centralised. It appears to be a major advantage. I worry that this is looking at it too narrowly and looking at it just from a DFID and BRAC perspective. How carefully has DFID thought through the consequences of the ways in which a government might look at this relationship? How well have we thought through how the rest of the NGO sector—which is very important for service delivery as we have been discussing—looks at this? What signals does it send about the relative importance of the NGO sector versus the state in the thinking of DFID Bangladesh? Whilst I can understand the reasoning behind it, it is making a major statement about British understanding of the development path in Bangladesh, and I worry that all the implications of that have not been thought through.

  Professor Wood: I am very glad Martin said that, because he is closer to BRAC then I am, but that very much is my view. It is worth saying, also, that about 10 years ago DFID went into an over-privileged relationship to BRAC, supporting its microfinance work, and supporting the evolution of the BRAC Bank, and I had a lot of arguments with DFID at that time because by setting up the relationship exclusively with BRAC to enable the bringing about of the BRAC Bank, DFID effectively undermined other negotiations that were going on to create a bank for the NGO sector as a whole, to enable a whole lot of other microfinance organisations to move into the same banking relationships with the poor as Grameen obviously already had and BRAC was able to evolve. I think that DFID at that time behaved quite non-developmentally across the sector and I think on our over-privileged relationship with BRAC it will do the same.

  Chairman: Thank you.

  Q99  John Battle: We visited BRAC's Challenging the Frontiers of Poverty Reduction programme. We went out and saw a pre-school, we went to a village where a woman called, if I remember rightly, Chanka told us that she had lost her husband to TB. She had nothing and there was a scheme to give her a grant, that enabled her to use good husbandry—from chickens to goats to cows—to get enough money by selling milk to get a loan to put a tin roof on her home. Then we met the village Poverty Reduction Committee that was managing this. We sat round and I was impressed by BRAC's blending of livelihoods, legal advice—as well as barefoot medics, barefoot lawyers—and for women in the Muslim context as well. That blend was quite impressive, but I have come away asking: if I liked the community development/integration that is going on, what impact does it really have? They have coined the phrase "the ultra poor" but what impact is BRAC having in Bangladesh on tackling the percentage of ultra poor, making sure they get access to resources and development? Are they the only ones in the game? What are the main challenges in seeking to expand the programme? How large is it? Really whether it is making a structural impact on poverty reduction targets nationally.

  Dr Greeley: This programme emerged from a recognition that the main vehicle for poverty reduction in Bangladesh had been the delivery of microfinance services. Research demonstrated that the ultra poor, the extreme poor, were not getting access through these services. BRAC took a long time developing that programme. I am really pleased that the Committee had the opportunity to visit this in the field. It is one of the most important programmes in Bangladesh. It was very influential in the development of DFID's other programme, the Chars Livelihoods Programme. Many ideas were borrowed and it has also been useful for those partners working in DFID's Shiree Programme in partnership with the government. The important thing about this programme is that it is an innovation that provides an alternative model to two main pathways to development. It is not a programme of pure social transfers, it is not a programme of economic empowerment through the market, it is a blend of those two. By providing a grant element initially and the support for health and for legal services, it provides the basis for households which otherwise would not be able to do so, to engage effectively in the market. It is a one-off lift-me-up, a promotional safety net. It is a model which is now being copied in seven other countries. It is called a graduation model, somewhere between the social transfer and the market-based approach. The research on the long-term benefits to the clients is coming in now. There are some very scientific studies underway. The initial evidence is extremely positive. The most positive element that visitors time and time again repeat is the transformation that they observe in the behaviour, attitudes and aspirations of the clients. If you see these households, particularly the women in the households, prior to programme participation and after they have been there two years, it is absolutely incredibly. You will not need to look for science. You can see it in their eyes. You can see the transformation.


1   Subsequent to this meeting, I addressed the APPG in Dhaka on 7 and 8 December 2009, and to my surprise, there was all-party membership. Back

2   Fajle Abed, Director of BRAC. The book referred to is Freedom from Want by Ian Smillie. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2010
Prepared 4 March 2010