- Public Administration Committee Contents


Memorandum from the Hay Group

This paper does not attempt to answer all the Select Committee's questions—although we would be happy to do this—but concentrates instead on a few observations and suggestions.

COMMENTS ON EXECUTIVE PAY IN THE PUBLIC SECTOR

  Committee Members, MPs and members of the public are understandably concerned about the value for money they get from public sector pay. We believe that the best way to improve value for money is not to complain about specific salary levels or bonus payments but to look at the market as a whole and concentrate public and regulatory attention on a small number of practicable reforms.

First, therefore, some comments about public sector reward systems:

1.   The Public Sector is not one market

  Public sector organisations occupy a broad spectrum. In practice they operate very differently and it will not help them or the taxpayer to lump them all together. For example, the Senior Civil Service is largely recruited from within the ranks of public servants rather than in the open market. Unsurprisingly, they have the lowest base salary levels of all main public services.

Local government offers higher salaries for jobs of similar weight and challenge, but this is because chief executives, directors and heads of service are recruited in the open market across the UK. In addition, as the Audit Commission has noted, pay has begun to reflect the performance of councils as measured by Comprehensive Performance Assessment and there is a demand for senior managers who have helped to improve local authorities ("Tougher at the Top?", Audit Commission discussion document July 2008).

  Universities recruit their Vice Chancellors in the international market—mainly from other higher education institutions—and they select the heads of business schools from among international competitors and the private sector. The pay of university heads has increased significantly in recent years and heads of business schools receive more. In both higher education and business schools, international measurement systems are available which enable recruiters to identify people who are associated with the best performing organisations, just like they can in local government but this time on the international stage.

  So even in the public sector, pay levels reflect the openness of the market and the track record of the individual. The point is underlined by experience in the Senior Civil Service, which recruits a minority from the wider market. That minority is paid around 20% more than those who have been promoted within the service (Government Evidence to the Senior Salaries Review Body, December 2008).

2.   The sector includes a wide range of organisations

  Policy towards the public sector in recent years has created a spectrum of organisation types. In part, this spread reflects the level of control from the centre of government, in part the opportunity and responsibility to operate commercially.

For example, central departments and the agencies which they fund are relatively closely controlled and are subject to the standard Senior Civil Service pay arrangements. There are various public bodies which have earned greater autonomy and are more likely to determine their own pay arrangements at executive level such as academy schools, foundation trust hospitals and agencies operating as Trading Funds. Then at one further remove from direct control are public corporations and government owned companies, which determine pay themselves throughout their employment structure. As public sector organisations become more independent and commercial, they are more likely to operate in the open recruitment market and to see a need to match wider market practice in salary level and the configuration of the total employment package.

  These differences are reflected in the NHS in England. The directly managed part of the NHS including Strategic Health Authorities, Ambulance Services and Primary Care Trusts—is covered by the national framework for Very Senior Managers, which is reviewed annually by the Senior Salaries Review Body. Provider trusts which do not have foundation status set executive pay locally. Foundation Trusts also set executive pay locally, have further pay freedoms and certainly pay more than the Very Senior Manager system, although their governance arrangements (including for remuneration) are regulated independently by Monitor.

  While the position in the NHS is a little confusing, it makes sense to relate autonomy in setting pay to the acquisition of other policy and commercial freedoms.

3.   There is an overreaction against performance related pay in all its forms

  There is a long tradition of hostility in most of the public sector both to linking salary progression to performance and to the use of bonuses. The Senior Civil Service, senior jobs in local government and the commercial public sector are exceptions, but outside these groups it is often argued that linking performance and pay does not suit the work and culture of the public sector.

Suspicion of performance related pay has grown recently as a reaction to the bonus culture in City institutions and certain banks and the combination of high bonus payments and obvious performance failures. However, the investment banking sector is not typical of how performance-related incentives operate in the private sector. Just because a few organisations pay far too much for the wrong things does not make the whole principle bad. In addition, in spite of indications to the contrary from recent publicity, a good system of bonuses and incentives takes care to encourage people to do the basics well and then to achieve more on top. It does not reward them for meeting a few targets while ignoring the main features of the job.

  Most important, it is only sensible to relate rewards to performance. The alternative is to pay people the same whether or not they perform—which is not even common sense, let alone good use of public money.

  The real difficulty with public sector pay is that it is not sufficiently related to performance. The negotiated pay systems covering the majority of public sector staff, generally up to quite senior levels, are still dominated by incremental pay structures which reward length of service and discourage effective performance management. Some executive pay also bears little relationship either to the performance of the organisation, or the top team or the individual.

  The most obvious example is the NHS, where many top salaries are supposedly set based on market rate and little use is made of bonus payments. The approach is exemplified by the Remuneration Report from one of the country's largest Foundation Trusts, which states: "No element of the executive directors' remuneration is performance related". This cannot be right. It is essential to provide a clear definition of good performance, and executives should not continue to receive high salaries and good increases unless they deliver the required performance.

  Finally, insofar as public service has operated performance-related, non-consolidated bonuses, these have tended to be focused on individual rather than organisational performance. As such they are much harder to justify to external stakeholders than arrangements related to the value the organisation itself delivers.

4.   Stakeholders should have information but not all public bodies provide it

  There has also been debate about the right of the public to clear information about the pay of executives in the public service.

The clearest rules and practices of disclosure are in the commercial public sector and the NHS, where top team salaries, bonuses and pension entitlements are published—although the salaries are often in bands rather than actual figures. There is also a strong element of disclosure in: the Senior Civil Service (where permanent secretaries' salaries are published and information about the top 5,000 or so civil servants is released each year); police forces, where salaries are set and publicised nationally; and universities, which state the remuneration of the Vice Chancellor and list other senior salaries in bands.

  The exception among major organisations is local authorities. They do not generally publish annual accounts in a format which members of the public can obtain and understand, nor do they disclose the remuneration of the top team. Most public information about executive pay in local government comes from press articles and freedom of information requests by individuals and lobby groups.

  It is arguable that all organisations funded by the public should have a common duty to disclose executive remuneration at least to the standard required of a PLC. At very least, there should be a duty placed on local councils to make available the remuneration of the chief executive and directors.

  Whilst there is some evidence that pay disclosure creates pressure for pay increases from executives, there is also strong evidence (from both the public and private sectors) that transparency improves the decision making of remuneration committees. On balance pay disclosures are of net benefit to the setting of appropriate pay packages, even leaving aside the governance arguments for such disclosures.

5.   Remuneration Committees should consider the terms and conditions of senior executives

  Many public sector bodies have—or are working towards—single sets of terms and conditions that apply across the whole workforce. Whilst "single status" is a useful principle for the wider employee population, it is debatable whether this approach should apply at top executive level. In our view, senior executives should be employed on service contracts with terms and conditions that are appropriate to their roles and which reflect the significant pay they receive. As a specific example, it is inappropriate for senior executives to be eligible for generous redundancy payments.

6.   Pensions are a separate issue

In recent years, the private sector has moved away from final salary pension schemes because their cost is unsustainable. Whilst a proportion of longer-serving private sector executives are still in final salary schemes, some companies are looking to end even these legacy entitlements—a process that is likely to be accelerated by the changes to pensions taxation set out in the 2009 Budget.

Meanwhile, although there have been changes in entitlements, the major public sector schemes still offer final salary or at least (for new joiners) salary average schemes, with index linking and at modest employee contribution rates. The cost of many schemes has been pushed-up by above inflation salary growth in parts of the public sector and the tendency to target pay increases into consolidated salary. For a long-server the pension costs of any salary increase will far outweigh the value of the salary increase itself.

  There has already been public and media comment on the gap between public and private sector pensions and disquiet on this point can be expected to grow. We believe that this point should be separated from concerns about pay and given proper attention in its own right. Public sector pay is not necessarily too high but simply too detached from performance. But the public sector pension bill is extremely high and, sooner or later, the gap between different parts of the economy will have to be reduced.

  However, we would note that the pension gap between public and private sector is much less evident at senior levels. This reflects the private sector practice of providing proportionally higher pension benefits to senior executives.

  Suggestions on public sector pensions policy go beyond the scope of the Committee's inquiry and we therefore do not include any below. However we would observe that a potential solution that might be acceptable to all stakeholders would be as follows:

— insofar as public sector pension provision continues to be linked to final or average salary, these arrangements should be capped at a given level of salary (say, £30,000); and

    — provision on the slice of earnings above this level should be on a defined contribution basis.

SUGGESTIONS

  Our suggestions are simple:

    (a) There should be no attempt at greater intervention in the public sector market, diverse as it is or at capping the salaries of particular groups. This will simply constrain rewards for specific organisations and limit their access to talent.

    (b) The regulatory framework for executive pay in the public sector should concentrate on three areas:

    — The requirement for a full and published policy on executive remuneration and a clear process for setting and reviewing it, overseen by a properly constituted, trained and advised Remuneration Committee.

    — A consistent requirement for disclosure of executive remuneration which applies throughout the public sector (ie organisations which are wholly or mainly funded by direct or indirect public grant). This requirement should include local authorities. As part of this requirement, the practice of disclosing salaries in £5,000 bands should be replaced with disclosure to the nearest £1,000 in line with private sector practice.

    — A duty on Remuneration Committees to relate pay to performance (of the organisation, team or individual, as appropriate) and to explain in their policy statement how this link works.

    (c) Where public sector executives receive pay and benefits that are competitive in the wider external market, their terms and conditions of employment should also reflect conditions in the external market.

May 2009




 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2009
Prepared 21 December 2009