The Impact of Spending Cuts on Science and Scienetific Research - Science and Technology Committee Contents


Memorandum submitted by Jonathan Haskel (FC 73)

How much does publicly funded research contribute to UK economic growth?[109]

  Universities undertake two major tasks: teaching and research (the third being the administration required to manage these processes). There are then at least two possible mechanisms whereby these tasks affect economic growth:

    (a) Teaching. More skilled students raises the human capital of the workforce and so growth.

    (b) Research. New knowledge spills over to other sectors, raises their knowledge capital and so leads to new products, services, methods of production etc.

  This note attempts to quantify the second of these effects and thus the impact of a cut in public support for research. The first effect is quantified in Haskel (2010).

The impact of publicly funded university research on the economy

  How much does the knowledge from university research spill over and so affect growth in the private sector? The problem with estimating this is that the private sector is itself generating knowledge via its own investment in R&D, software and other knowledge spending, so one has to separate out the role of this and that of universities, plus other effects such as knowledge from abroad etc.

  First some facts. UK companies spend around £12 billion per year on R&D. The UK government spends around £10 billion on R&D. Such public spending Britain ranks 9th in public support for higher education, in the form of grants to universities and research councils for research, among OECD countries, relative to 16th in 1996.

  That reported public spend on R&D consist of about 33% spend on research councils, 33% on defence R&D, 20% on civil R&D (ie in non-defence Government departments) and the rest being the general support to university research (funding distributed according to RAE performance). The research council money is then obtained by universities in turn by competitive allocation. It is spent on funding the discovery of new knowledge paying for researcher time and equipment. Such new knowledge must be made publically available. Of that research council money, over 90% goes on engineering, natural sciences and medicine. Funding for social sciences and the arts is about 6% of the total.

  In Haskel and Wallis (2009) we have attempted to measure the extent to which such public support raises private sector growth. Again, this is not the only metric; medical support for example might raise life lengths or happiness, but this is the metric we choose. We do so because it is argued, by those who wish more taxpayer support to be forthcoming, that the ideas created by publically funded research are freely available and so can be commercialised by the private sector. If this is so, then the private sector should not mind funding such knowledge. If on the other hand, the private sector is asked to fund knowledge that provides them no advantage, then taxpayers have reason to be unhappy.

  Measuring the effect then of public sector knowledge on private sector growth is a tricky undertaking, for one has to control for all the other factors that might affect private sector growth. The most obvious ones are the accumulation by the private sector itself of its own knowledge, via investment in R&D, software etc. plus the accumulation of other inputs, such as hiring more labour and employing more machines. Thus the starting point is to try to measure that part of growth not accounted for by own investment in knowledge, capital and labour; this is called total factor productivity growth (single factor productivity is output per unit of labour input, total factor productivity is output per unit of labour, capital and own-knowledge input). Total factor productivity growth is then that part of private sector growth determined by factors not directly funded for by the private sector. So it could be determined by publically funded knowledge from UK universities that is free to everyone. Or it could be determined by knowledge freely available from anywhere in the world, be it publically funded by other countries or privately funded, but leaking out of the private sector in those countries. The medium of such knowledge spillovers could be the internet, or foreign trade or foreign direct investment. Attempting to parse out these possible effects is what our study tries to do.

  The main finding is set out in Figure 1.

Figure 1

Smoothed TFPG and RCouncil R & D spend


Note: Research council spending is as a proportion of GDP, lagged one year.

  The vertical axis shows total factor productivity growth (TFPG). In 1987 for example, the upper left point, this was 2.5% (each point is a year). The horizontal axis is spending on research councils in the previous year (as a proportion of GDP). The scatter shows the line of best fit and is upward-sloping. That says, in words, that increases in public support for R&D via research councils is associated with increases in private sector TFPG a year later (a very similar picture holds for lags of two and three years). Of course the relation is noisy and other factors are likely occurring, but the points turn out to lie sufficiently close to the line to give a statistically significant relation.

  The point can be further illustrated below. These show cross plots with the other spending categories, civil and defence R&D. There is not as strong a relation; in fact, the relation is statistically insignificant.

Figure 6


  We can further use the slope of the line to determine the contribution of research council spend to GDP. Current spend is around £3.5 billion. The slope of the line suggest this gives around £60bn additional market sector output. If, to be conservative, one halves this, one gets a contribution of publically funded research to GDP of £30 billion, which is about 2% of GDP. Put another way, if support for research councils was cut by, say £1 billion from its current £3 billion, GDP would fall by around £10 billion.

REFERENCESJonathan Haskel, (2010), "How much do UK Universities contribute to UK Economic Growth?", draft paper, available on request from c.edlin@ic.ac.uk

Jonathan Haskel and Gavin Wallis, (2009), "Public Support for Innovation, Intangible Investment and Productivity Growth in the UK Market Sector", draft paper: http://www.ceriba.org.uk/bin/view/CERIBA/PublicSupportCeriba

Jonathan Haskel

Imperial College Business School

January 2010






109   The views set out in this note are solely those of the author. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2010
Prepared 25 March 2010