The role and performance of Ofsted - Education Committee Contents


Memorandum submitted by Bob Prince MA

BUDGET AND THE "POLITICAL FOOTBALL", EDUCATION

If there is any merit in cutting budgets in education, then prime candidates for cutting must surely include the backroom services including inspection, curriculum development* (see para 14), and testing.

1. Within primary and secondary education the most feared and hated department of government is OFSTED. Previous to its invention the function of school inspection was carried out by the benign and (some might say), largely ineffectual, Her Majesty's Inspectorate (HMI).[1] The Inspectorate prior to OFSTED had the merit of being, in real terms, extremely cheap to run and had an in-built control of costs. If budgets were tight, fewer inspections were done and then, only needed, if real problems arose within particular schools. Inspections of schools were carried out under the management of the local authorities.

2. OFSTED however, has been conceived as an altogether different tool of government and as I hope to demonstrate does not have as its primary purpose, the monitoring of the performance of schools (and other organisations). The primary purpose of OFSTED has been to impose a politically based ideology on the education system within the UK. I do not propose at this point to discuss the merits, or otherwise of the ideological regime other than to identify it. I do hope to shed light on the question as to whether we need OFSTED at all.

3. OFSTED was created in 1992 by John Major's government to enhance the work of the HMI. The over arching political ideology operated by this and the previous Conservative administration at this time was broadly, to find ways of enabling markets, rather than the state, to provide economic solutions to problems of government. Using market economics as a guiding principle of government the problem arose, as to how the principles of the market could be applied to social functions, such as education run by government.

4. Education was a particularly difficult problem. As a proportion of the revenue spent by government the education service was an enormous slice. What was more intractable was that even though education cost such a lot of money, the tax payer had no way of understanding what value they were getting from education since the outcomes were to a large extent un-measurable. Furthermore, education experts were divided as to what constituted success when applied to education. Most education professionals were agreed that the one thing education was not about, was to supply the market with functionaries with which to run the commercial life of the nation… it was much more than that.

5. Government by market economics was faced by an ideological impasse when applied to education. How could it apply market principles when (after all), it was supplying money to an education establishment demonstrating serious reservations about the application of market economics to the field of education? The solution adopted was to run an education service bound to a systemic analogy with the market with measured outcomes (profits) driven by the possibility of catastrophic failure, school closures (bankruptcy), or "special measures" (administration).

6. As a measure of the effectiveness of schooling, exam results attained in the final years of secondary education prior to 1992 left much to be desired. Pupils, whose early education was unsatisfactory, were just not represented by those results and therefore, exam results had little relationship to the quality of schooling in the early years. Conversely, a good early education meant that the final results might reflect just that, rather than the quality of secondary schooling. The old 11+ examination, which at least exposed primary education's role in measured results could not be re-adopted because of the lack of political will to reinstate selection for secondary education. The government of the time therefore introduced the electorate to a whole new set of concepts in state education provision.

7. The first of these was parental choice. If a child's school did not perform satisfactorily parents could take them to another school, just as in the market people could take their custom elsewhere.

Secondly, continuous measurement of the school's (not the child's) performance with annual testing of every year (except the 1st) of schooling measured against targets set by the state and not by the school (SAT).

Thirdly, inspection by both education professionals & professionals drawn from business and other outside interests (OFSTED).

8. It is my belief that, SATs results become analogous to the currency of an education market with currency value being set by the target for each year of pupils' education.

9. I also propose that in the same way, OFSTED inspection became analogous to the audit carried out for shareholders with the primary purpose of making sure that the company (tax payers) derive maximum profit from their investment. OFSTED inspections therefore become an extremely powerful way of defining the detailed running of schools, the meaning of their activities and cultivating wider public perception of the value of particular schools to their communities. Publication of the results of OFSTED inspections and the derived SAT results is seen to have a direct relationship to application for school places, which in turn, affects the viability of the school. In theory… we have a market.

10. How expensive is that market to run? How strong is the value of its currency? Do its customers get the best value for money? Do they really know what they want? Are they the real customers?

I cannot hope to answer these questions, although, in relation to expense there are some answers. The unavoidable costs of the education system are: Accommodation (except where distance learning is a viable option). Teachers. Media (books, materials, wax tablets…etc.). All the rest is advisable but not necessary and not always necessary in the forms that have been adopted.

11. It would for instance, be unwise to abandon an overall inspection system for schools where expectations of standards in education are national rather than local. Is it necessary to minutely inspect as frequently the detailed performance of every school as we do now? Could we not trust schools to be run by professionals and only inspect them if there is cause for concern? The latter course of action would be dramatically less expensive than the current regime.

12. The SATs assessment, is perceived by teachers as disruptive, often meaningless and inaccurate as a method of measuring schools and pupil's progress. Perhaps the greatest criticism of the SA Tests is they have little to do with the outcomes of education, many of which take a whole lifetime to develop. Pupils do not progress in a linear fashion in their perception and understanding of life, although, evidence of progression makes for a satisfying statistical pattern. Anecdotally, SAT tests are prone to statistical manipulation by all those involved, at all levels of the administration of education, because, it is in everyone's interest to demonstrate progress, year on year by individuals and by whole schools.

13. It is not surprising that the teaching profession is almost in a state of mutiny on the question of whether SATs should be carried out. The tests are expensive to administer, (although perhaps not as expensive as decreasing the pupil/teacher ratio, a measure, which would really be effective in increasing literacy levels within schools). There is therefore a serious question as to the cost effectiveness of SATs as they are now run. If they are not producing meaningful evidence of achievement, why assess in this manner at all?

14. *In tandem, national curriculum development also seems to have expanded under successive administrations to the point to which, its cost-effectiveness is open to question. I do not however have sufficient knowledge of its detailed operation and costs to discuss it here.

15. It seems that in a field, which is in essence all about content, that of education, ideology has run roughshod over the content itself, restricting it to specific targets to be satisfied by specific timescales.

16. OFSTED should therefore be recognised for what it is, a tool for imposing a political ideology on the field of education. Even if one broadly agrees with the principles of that ideology the organisation is an expensive luxury which does not deliver front-line services to its clients, school-children.

17. Without some form of inspection possible some schools would, over a period of time, decline as management slipped into complacency. However, we should also trust that, classroom teachers are highly motivated civil servants whom, almost all have the best interests of their pupils at heart. We should therefore, abolish OFSTED and its "currency" SATs and return to the regime of a much smaller cohort of (nationally managed) inspectors who only step in when problems emerge.

September 2010


1   http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Ofsted. Back


 
previous page contents next page


© Parliamentary copyright 2011
Prepared 17 April 2011