The Common Agricultural Policy after 2013 - Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Committee Contents


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 39-74)

GEORGE DUNN AND GREG BLISS

8 DECEMBER 2010

Q39   Chair: Thank you very much indeed for joining us. You are most welcome. I understand that Mr Dunn will be joining us. If you will bear with us, there may be a vote, in which case we will have a very short interruption. If you are happy that we proceed, may I ask you to introduce yourself and, in his absence, Mr Dunn, who I am sure will join us just as soon as he can.

Greg Bliss: I am Greg Bliss. I am the National Chairman of the Tenant Farmers Association. We are the body in England and Wales that works solely for tenant farms and those who work within the tenanted system of agriculture. George Dunn is my Chief Executive. He is the real expert on tenancy law. I am the farmer and layman, really.

Q40   Chair: You are very welcome. Just at the outset, both in the present CAP and looking to the Commission Communication for Future Reform do you think that we have the balance right? Do you there is too much focus on the environment and the birds, and perhaps not enough on farmers, in the measures that the Commission is proposing?

Greg Bliss: As the Tenant Farmers Association, we certainly worry about the greening of the CAP. I think we need to look very hard at what we are trying to produce. If we are going to produce enough food and achieve the food security to feed us, we do have to be careful that we get the balance right between food production and environmental protection, or this basket of public goods that we talk about, which includes all of these things. I think there is a risk that we might lose sight of food production, particularly in the way it balances amongst the other EU members, in terms of the way they work to their own budgets in terms of modulation and that sort of thing. We could find ourselves disadvantaged in this country if we do not have the right balances.

Q41   Chair: I know that you have previously said that the landlord tenant sector is unique to England and Wales. Do you believe that is an issue going forward in the current proposals for current CAP reform? Do you think the concept of landlord tenant, as we understand it here, is one understood by the decision makers in Brussels?

Greg Bliss: I do not think it is particularly well understood. We have had some communication into Brussels and we have a specific case. However, in this country, the landlord tenant system works in such a way that there is quite a large risk of the landlord taking quite a lot of benefit from the payment in this country, through whatever measures he puts in place in terms of the tenancy that we work under in this country. In Northern Ireland and Scotland the rules are different, but in England and Wales there are several situations where benefit from the CAP can bypass the active farmer and go straight to the landlord through clauses written in the tenancies. We are very clear that we want the active farmer, that is the tenant, the man who is taking the risk, to take the payment that comes out from the CAP.

Q42   Chair: Excellent. May I just pause to welcome Mr Dunn. You are not late; we are early. Thank you for allowing us to continue, George. You are most welcome.

George Dunn: No problem.

Q43   George Eustice: One of the things that I know the Commission is looking at in this current reform is the tightening up on the definition of an active farmer. I wondered if you could say what you think an appropriate definition of an active farmer would be.

George Dunn: I will start with the premise that we are looking at people who are involved in an agricultural activity or keeping land in good agricultural or environmental condition. We would then say that in order to identify the person who should be the recipient of the CAP support, they have to meet three criteria above that. Firstly, that they are in occupation of the land concerned; so they are not a contractor and they are not providing a service to the owner. Secondly, that they are in day-to-day management control, and that means taking the decisions about what happens on the land over the year. Again, this means that it is not a contractor who is taking the decisions from the owner. Thirdly, and most importantly, they are taking the entrepreneurial or business risk of operating that land; so they are not just taking a fixed fee or a rent, they are actually taking a risk in operating that land.

What we would say is that we are not expecting there to be a great amount of information provided at the time the application is made to prove that you are this individual. It should be self-assessed criteria by which people are then aware that they will be open to inspection upon at a later date, should they be selected for an inspection. It would create the circumstances within which, agents, for example, who are advising people on their applications, would be very conscious of their own PI cover if they were advising people to do things that make them fall outside that criteria of an active farmer. Therefore, it is not something that we would see as a great regulatory burden up front.

Q44   George Eustice: Do you think that it should exclude people that do not actually earn their living from the land, or even directly engage with agricultural production? I know earlier when we spoke to the RSPB, they were saying that there had been some discussion of whether their field was for butterflies or sheep, which affected the definition.

George Dunn: The CAP was developed as a mechanism to support the farming community and to provide food security and other environmental benefits. We would absolutely say that it is right that the applicant should be the person who is carrying out the agricultural activity of keeping land in good agricultural and environmental condition. That rules out things like golf courses and football pitches at one end, but also people who are simply involved in biodiversity management. It has got to have some aspect of agricultural activity to it.

Q45   George Eustice: Yes. Do you think there would be a case for restricting farmers only to one or two of the Pillars, so that people who are not active farmers might be eligible for benefits in one of the others? Pillar 2 or Pillar 1 could be reserved just for farmers.

George Dunn: I think you would have some difficulty in making that distinction between the two Pillars, because obviously a lot of what you do in Pillar 2 relies upon there being a fundamentally basic agricultural activity going on in that holding, to which you are adding particular management criteria to provide biodiversity and keep land in good environmental condition. We can absolutely see that there may be individuals outside agriculture per se who need public support for other types of activity, but we do not think CAP is the place within which they should necessarily sit.

Q46   Neil Parish: I think you have partly answered the question. I am going to ask you a slightly different question. In your Vision for Agriculture, you said: "Measures must be put in place to ensure that support payments do not become capitalised into land values." That is very laudable, but how do you stop it? Because once the landlord knows that the payment is coming to the tenant, he or she is going to want that reflected in the rent, I would have thought. How do you want to get this vision across, and do you see anything in the Commission's proposal to help you in that?

George Dunn: The Commission proposal lacks the necessary detail for us to be able to answer your question precisely, on that aspect. One would expect it not to have too much detail at the moment. It is difficult to see which way the Commission document will go once we have the legal texts in draft next year. However, there are two specific things that could be done to assist. The first is that, if it is absolutely clear that the only applicant for Pillar 1 or Pillar 2 is the sort of applicant who I have been describing, the landlord has to then enter into a proper negotiation with that tenant about how the rewards of those schemes are going to be provided. Currently, the marketplace in agricultural tenancies is very slim, and there are many more people seeking land—and Greg will tell you about his area, I am sure—than there are offering land. Even if landlords are able to take the SPS benefit and the Pillar 2 benefit, people are still willing to pay very high rents simply to get access to land. By putting the tenant farmer in the prime position to be the applicant will immediately change the necessary negotiating ethos.

  The second thing is that we need to put rules in place to stop individuals from acquiring SPS entitlement rights, or whatever comes next, over and above what they need for their application. We are already aware of many landlords who are asking tenants to give up Single Farm Payment entitlement at the end of their tenancies, for little or no compensation, and then renting that back. We believe that that should be outlawed, as well as stockpiling entitlement to rent out with land elsewhere. Those two things, particularly, could help sufficiently. It is not going to take all the value back.

Q47   Neil Parish: You would say that the entitlements belong to the tenant then, would you?

George Dunn: The entitlements belong to the tenants, yes. That was a battle that was fought over the 2003 reforms when we were looking at whether the entitlement should be a land-based entitlement that needs a farmer to activate it, or a farmer-based entitlement that needs land to entitle it. We plumped for the latter, but we would very much see the entitlements remaining in the hands of the active farmer.

Q48   Mrs Glindon: This is not quite a wish-list question, but what would your organisation hope to achieve in this round of CAP reform?

George Dunn: I think that is a wish-list question, isn't it? It is quite interesting that this reform is being conducted against a very different basis to previous reforms. There is not really the WTO impetus that there was in the last reform, or the reform before that. I know that the budget issues are still important, but they are not as important as they were when the CAP budget was more than half the total amount of spending in the EU. We think this is going to be a much more principled reform than we have perhaps seen in the past, particularly with the involvement of the European Parliament and a greater degree of democratic control over the decision making. There could be much more of a principled approach to the whole CAP reform debate. I think our key messages are: food security; benefits to the active farmer so that he is recompensed going forward; issues to deal with volatility in both output markets and input markets; and help for competitiveness structural issues, including retirement and new entrants. These would be the key messages.

Q49   Mrs Glindon: What are your views on the feasibility of the Commission's three options?

George Dunn: The Commission often do this, don't they? They give you three options and go for the middle one. I think that is exactly what we have got this time. The Commission is quite clearly not wedded to options one and three; they want option two. From our perspective, the document is broadly welcomed, because it seems to have a great resonance with what we have said in our 2020 Vision report, which Mr Parish referred to earlier. A lot of the concepts that are in the Commission's communication, we were talking about a few months before in our 2020 Vision document. Therefore, option two seems to us to be the most appropriate way forward.

Q50   Neil Parish: Regarding policies at the EU level: what is there that would enhance the competitiveness of agriculture, especially in the UK? Also, what is your position on capping of the larger farms? Would that make agriculture more competitive, or how do you see it affecting the tenanted sector?

George Dunn: I will take competiveness and you can talk about capping, Greg. On the competitiveness issue, the Commission's document is very helpful when it talks about the problem that agriculture has to be a strong player in the marketplace and its own supply chain, because of the concentration in the retail and the input supply sector. Competition is about how agriculture provides itself with a fair return in its own supply chain; that is part one. Part two is about how agriculture in the EU fights its corner against third-country agricultural systems, within the context of the WTO, where perhaps things are not being produced to the same environmental, animal welfare or water quality standards to which we are producing at home.

There is another question about the extent to which British agriculture is competitive, as opposed to the other 26 Member States of the Union and their agricultural systems. So we will try and take those three. The Commission's document, with which we agree, indicates that the reason why we continue to need a Pillar 1 is that agriculture has a weak position in the supply chain and is unable to really have its costs of production properly covered, with an element of profit, in the supply chain which exists. Pillar 1 is vital to ensuring that farmers can remain competitive in their own supply chain. However, we also see the need for some form of ombudsman adjudicator to be able to parachute in to supply chain situations, and look at whether or not that supply chain is acting in a morally or ethically efficient way.

  In terms of the position with regard to the rest of the world, again the Commission's document recognises that other countries are perhaps able to export commodities into the EU that are perhaps not produced at the same high standards that we expect at home, but consumers find it difficult to distinguish between the two products. Therefore, again, Pillar 1 support in that market, border support, is important for competitiveness in global terms. If we are going to have these higher standards, we need to protect those higher standards and not undermine them by exporting our environmental and animal welfare issues abroad. That is very important.

In terms of the British agriculture against other Member States, we are quite pleased that this document has not considered it appropriate to have considerable renationalisation of agricultural policy, because that would lead to a large degree of different levels of payment. We would see that we need equal levels of modulation, equal level of cross compliance and equal levels of decoupling across the EU to prevent a particular Member State from having a particular advantage in an area because it decides to favour that area. We know that there are other reasons why other Member States will have more or less competitive agricultural systems. That can be because of the taxation regime that they are operating under or because of the planning system that operates in those countries. However, in terms of the CAP, the more that we have agreed at an EU level, from our perspective, the better. That is perhaps not a straightforward answer to your question, but we see those elements as all very important.

Greg Bliss: If you look at Pillar 1, when you look at how many agricultural producers are actually producing, and living, below the official poverty line, it just makes you realise just how important Pillar 1 is, particularly in the tenanted sector, where they have to pay a rent before they take any drawings. Take Pillar 1 away, and I think you take you snatch the rug from a huge proportion of the tenanted sector. The tenanted sector needs encouragement rather than being drawn back.

In terms of capping, the TFA are ambivalent over whether to cap or not to cap. This is the third time that it has come up in CAP reform; the time for it has maybe come. I guess it would encourage a splitting of businesses, and we do have some larger members who might be affected; but generally within the TFA's membership, they would all be below a cap, if you guess that cap is going to be at somewhere around the €300,000 mark. Therefore, capping would not be a huge issue for the TFA, but in terms of how it reacts with the structure of agricultural businesses in the UK, then it would have a bearing on us in terms of how it affected our members who were involved with those businesses.

George Dunn: The figure of €300,000 is what was floated.

Neil Parish: I think that is right. I think that is the existing one. It will probably come down from that, I expect. It is still probably €250,000, anyway.

Q51   Chair: Can I just return to what you said there about the poor position of farmers in the food supply chain and making the farmer remain more competitive? You mentioned, in particular, the role of what is now called the Adjudicator, previously the Supermarket Ombudsman. Do you believe that there should be a role for the CAP? Do you believe you are being disadvantaged in this country by not having a mechanism at EU level to protect the place of the farmer in the supply chain?

George Dunn: The debate is, firstly do we need an adjudicator? We have all learnt the new acronym, GSCCOP, the Grocery Supply Chain Code of Practice adjudicator, have we not?

Chair: It just trips off the tongue!

Neil Parish: It is very catchy.

George Dunn: Yes, it is. We believe that we do need an adjudicator. The question is at what level that adjudicator should be introduced. Up to very recently, we know that the political masses in this country were not particularly keen on having a formalised role for such a person. We are now pleased to see that is firmly on the agenda. We are expecting a draft Bill for that. Effectively, we are much further ahead in the UK than we would be within Europe. However, it was not very long ago that Europe was probably ahead of the game in terms of where we were when they were thinking about these issues, when our Government was well behind the game on that front. So, we don't really mind where it comes so long as it is a fit for purpose individual with the teeth to be able to get into the issues that we need to see changed.

Q52   Chair: What about the question of a potential complainant being worried about, or losing, their anonymity if they make a complaint?

George Dunn: We would suggest that the organisation, or the adjudicator, operates less in a reactive role and more in a proactive role, in the sense that it can decide on a Monday morning which supply chain it wants to look at and which particular retailer or processer arrangement it wants to dip into. It should have the ability to say to that processor or retailer, "We are coming to see you on Tuesday. We want your books open and we want to see your arrangements with your suppliers."

Q53   Chair: Without naming a company, we all know that if you take potatoes and a contract for chips, or apples, or whatever the product is, it is the supermarkets that hold the power. Do you believe that the mechanism is there? It was put to us last week in our briefing session in Brussels that there is this fear that no supplier in their right mind wants to make a complaint because they will lose their contract if that comes out. I was in DG IV as a stagiaire and we used to read about these dawn raids. Whoopee, it gets a lot of publicity and then everyone goes back to sleep. But someone could lose their potential contract, so do you have a view as to what the solution could be?

George Dunn: We do not see it as being a complaint-driven operation. We believe that this should be a much more proactive operation, so that all retailers and all processors know that they are subject to inspection by the adjudicator, on the terms of the Grocery Supply Code of Practice, at any time within a short notice period. That puts retailers, processors and others in the food chain on notice that they could have someone coming to look at their books and arrangements within 24 to 48 hours. You would get a better operation of the Supply Chain Code of Practice across the piece, rather than dealing with a particular point where there is a single complaint from an individual, who, as you rightly say, would be nervous about putting their head above the parapet.

Q54   Chair: Would you accept that it should perhaps be proactive the other way, by swooping on producers and asking how their negotiations are going and what contracts they have in place?

George Dunn: They will obviously want to take evidence from whomever they like, but we think we will protect individuals if it is not a complaint-driven operation but is a proactive engagement of the Supply Chain Code of Practice and how retailers and processors are implementing that.

Chair: Thank you. That's very helpful.

Q55   Tom Blenkinsop: The long-term investment sustainability for farmers, whether it be predominantly retail or commodity speculation, by which farmers originally used to try to maintain long-term investment in the industry, has not borne out. Would you say insulation from market signals through a risk management toolkit would reduce the competitiveness of the agricultural sector?

George Dunn: Well, maybe Greg, as an active farmer, could speak a little bit about the volatility that he has experienced in both input and output prices over the past few years. He can give you an idea of the sort of issues that we are facing, and then we can see how those might fit into a risk management toolkit.

Greg Bliss: A lot of people have talked about risk management. In terms of running a business, wheat has traded from £95 a tonne to £206.50, or £211 as I heard the other day for January. In this season alone, fertiliser started off at £160; it is now back in the £300s. In terms of supermarkets again, if you have got a supermarket contract delivering, then people are held to that contract, even with the weather that we have been having recently. If people cannot deliver their contracts, then they are bought against. The supermarkets are bumping prices up and I would say that they are profiteering on the basis of the weather and none of that money is trickling back. It is very difficult to plan. We use all the tools that we can, but with extra volatility you get extra cost. The means that we have in terms of options and forward contracts are very expensive, with the cost of insurance. For example, people are not willing to insure wheat for 20% of the cost of a tonne, as it may be. If you deal in vegetables, you cannot buy an option in a tonne of vegetables; you have got to actually own the contract and buy it. Then you have got all the risks of call-up costs as the market alters until you come to sell.

We have very little time to do that sort of thing, and if you are sitting on a tractor and not sitting in front of a screen, you miss the chance. This is where the CAP, as it was, worked so well in terms of intervention. Everything was simpler and it smoothed the whole thing out. In terms of working for the EU as a whole with regards to cost, it did not work; but it certainly worked for agriculture. Somewhere between the two there has got to be a balance, I think.

George Dunn: I did have a meeting today with a member of the Commissioner's Cabinet and asked, "What is in this toolbox, apart from intervention and insurance?" The answer was, "That is it at the moment: intervention and insurance." I don't think that there has yet been a great deal of thought being put into what those tools look like in the toolkit. Certainly we have seen insurance markets operate to a lesser or greater extent in America and other parts of the world. We have had intervention before; it may not be WTO compatible to continue with some forms of intervention. There is a great deal of work to be done on that issue, but we believe that volatility is a big concern. We always said that when we moved from the direct payments that we had under the old system of CAP, towards the decoupled system, that the farming activity itself would be subject to a much greater degree of volatility. As Greg has explained, boy, have we seen that over the past five years, and that is only likely to continue. We need to find some system that provides for the buffers to be put on, so that investment decisions can be made long term.

Greg Bliss: It is where you put the value of food security, I think. If you support farmers and you smooth the volatility out for them, it keeps farmers in agriculture and keeps them producing, so you have got your food security. You may never have a particularly profitable agriculture, but you have got happy consumers because they have got a cheap food policy and it keeps ticking over.

If you are going to make profit in agriculture and have a competitive agriculture, that is probably not the answer. I do not have a silver bullet to do that; it has to be somewhere between the two where people can pick the top of the market, but there is a certain amount of luck involved in that at the moment. I am not just farming: I am a currency speculator and I have got to deal with the soft commodity speculators and all the people in between who are taking what is generally a fixed margin.

George Dunn: There are certain things that we can do domestically as well, without having to bother with CAP. For example, if you are a tenant farmer in a modern context, your average length of term today is three and half to four years. In a marketplace as volatile as it has been, this is not a very safe place to be. Whereas, if we had tenancy agreements that were 10 or 15 years in duration, then individuals would be able to ride the bad years with the good years. We are certainly talking to the Government about how we can encourage landlords, through the taxation system, to let longer term and to provide that greater period of time over which to deal with volatility. Because if you are on a three-year farm business tenancy, and you have had two bad years because of harvest and your price goes down or fertiliser goes up, you are going to come out of that arrangement as not a very happy tenant farmer.

Q56   Tom Blenkinsop: Do you support the retention of voluntary coupled support in Pillar 1?

George Dunn: We would not support the retention of it being voluntary on Member States, because we think that would lead to the sort of competitive issues that I have mentioned to Mr Parish. If different Member States are providing differential levels of support, then it could lead to serious problems within the internal market for how those commodities are traded. We would not want those to be voluntary; we would want everybody to have the same level of decoupling across the piece.

Q57   George Eustice: I want to just pick up on this issue about insurance not being cost-effective. I am just curious as to why we have not got more developed markets in hedging or futures contracts in some of those other sectors. If you look at coffee and sugar and other international traded commodities, there is a very, very efficient futures market that allows people to hedge their bets and protect their income. Is it just that, because of the CAP, perhaps traditionally there has not been a culture that you need to defend yourself against volatility, and so it has just not developed? Or is it just the case that it would never be a big enough, or liquid enough, market?

Greg Bliss: I think when you are talking about things like coffee and sugar, you are talking about some very big players. When you are talking about wheat at the farm gate, then you have only got to look at all the options for fair trade coffee: there is the same issue. These guys are selling a small amounts off the farm into a world market and getting very little for them. I think you have a point when you say we have been used to wheat being a set price into intervention, and it being balanced by that.

Certainly as a tenant farmer, I am in a situation where I have some land that is half of my holding. In five years' time or in three years' time I might not have the security of that tenancy. What happens if I sell wheat forward and then I do not have the land? If you have an annual renewing tenancy you can only afford to sell a year ahead, so in that way, you are more or less bound to take the market and you have to be a prudent tenant. You have got to pay your rent, and so you might have to sell something early for cash flow reasons, which does not allow you to perhaps take advantage of a future price that you may think would be considerably better. There are a lot of other issues with short-termism in tenancies that preclude us from taking a much longer term view.

George Dunn: I do not think that it is all sweetness and light in the sugar and coffee sectors. It was not that long ago that we were looking at the African, Caribbean and Pacific countries that got a reasonably good deal under the EU Lomé agreements, saying that because of the WTO case against the EU on sugar, they were no longer going to be competitive in the world market against the likes of Brazil for selling their sugar. There are some very big players who are playing the market very well, and cornering the market, but that does not mean that it is absolutely okay for everybody in the market place. There are a significant number of producers in both those two sectors who are losing out.

Q58   George Eustice: The other thing I just wanted to ask you about is how important you think food security is as an element to be considered in the discussions about CAP reform. There has been some dispute. You have obviously got some groups who are still pushing very hard for the greening of Pillar 1 and much more emphasis on Pillar 2 and agri-environment type schemes, and you have also got this Scenar study that suggests that you could actually remove direct payments altogether and it would not have a huge impact on the amount of land that was farmed in Europe. Have you got an idea, at your end, of how big a consideration it should be in this current review?

Greg Bliss: I think food security has always been a fundamental plank in what we have been saying in terms of the basket of public goods that we provide. I know that a lot of people have said it is not, it is the environment, but I think that it is a fundamental part and a mainstay of that basket of public goods that agriculture provides. Without food security and the ability to do as much as we can to support ourselves, you can't eat butterflies and birds. I know that they are important, but you do need to have a balance. It seems to me that if you do not have a certain amount of production, the environment is very soon forgotten when you have issues with shortage; for example, there have been food riots in other parts of the world. People can soon forget the environmental side of things when it is driven. I think if you have a much more balanced approach, the environment does not get pushed aside, because we have a vibrant and productive agriculture that is pushing towards a good chunk of our own food security.

Q59   George Eustice: How important do you then think the Pillar 1 direct payments are to ensuring that food security? To be a devil's advocate, there are those who would say, "If you look at New Zealand in the '80s, they just took away all of their subsidies altogether, and the farms adjusted and were able to compete in world markets without support."

George Dunn: New Zealand is often cited as an example of where subsidies were removed, but New Zealand also did quite a lot of other things, including devaluing their currency and altering their banking system and everything else. There was almost a big bang; it wasn't just about agriculture in New Zealand. I think if you were to talk to New Zealand farmers today, they would tell you what a tough environment it is to be farming in today's terms. It is not just all about the quantity of the food; it is about the quality of the food, which we have talked about before. Certainly there is a clear demand for animal welfare, higher environmental standards, food of local provenance and so on. From our perspective, Pillar 1 provides that return to farmers that is not available to farmers in the marketplace, because it is very, very difficult to price those costs into the goods that you buy on a supermarket or retailer's shelves, yet we are expected to bear them. So, Pillar 1 is vitally important to that.

If you take a sector like the dairy industry, for example, we have seen a great exodus of dairy producers in Great Britain over the past 10 years or so, and most of those decisions are made on the basis that when they come to the point of reinvestment, there is not enough in the game for them to be able to make a return on the investment; to be able to make a return on the investment you have got to put in a new parlour or a new dairy, and so on. If you remove any support that we are getting from the single payment scheme from that equation, they would go much earlier, because milk prices only just match the day-to-day costs of running those businesses in most cases. In a lot of cases it is below, unless you are a dedicated supermarket chain. We would see a rapid removal of a lot of farmers.

Q60   Mrs Glindon: I just want to go on a bit more about competitiveness, the sustainability issue and greening. The Commissioner said that there is a false dilemma between being competitive and sustainable. Do you think both are possible to achieve?

George Dunn: A false dilemma is an interesting phrase, because if you are requiring individuals to be farming to a certain level of standard, and you are not properly recompensing them for the costs of those standards, that is not sustainable. You need to have a transfer from another part of society—and that happens to be the CAP and the public purse at the moment—which supports that level of production. We already have cross-compliance. People would argue that statutory management requirements are only obeying the current law, but we have also got the good agricultural and environmental conditions (GAEC) requirements, which go beyond the current law, and we have got Pillar 2 payments as well. All those elements are important to support the fact that direct payment is needed, so that individuals can get a proper return from their production.

If you look at economic theory, it will tell you that as economies grow, less of a proportion of the national income is spent on food, because we only have a certain size of stomach and we can only eat so much. We tend to spend our growing incomes on other things. Okay, we might eat higher quality or eat out a bit more, but in terms of the basic foodstuffs, less and less of a proportion of the national income is spent on the basic foodstuff elements. That means as economies grow, farmers are always going to be behind the curve. They are not going to be able to take advantage of the economic growth in other parts of the economy. If you want them to be able to sustain their businesses into the long term, there has got to be transfer payments from society, and that is what direct payments effectively are. Unless you want to see a fundamental change in the way that we do farming in this country, so that it is ranched or is based around single operators in large areas with potentially lower quality produce because of the way that it is done, then we need to retain the systems that we have got.

Greg Bliss: That was going to be my plank: if you look at the way people would make money in the situation that George explained, you lose everything. You would lose quality of food, you would lose quality of environment and you would lose employment and people living in the countryside, because the jobs would not be there and it would be run on a completely different basis.

Q61   Mrs Glindon: What green measures do you think could be included in Pillar 1 that would improve the environmental sustainability, but would not have an adverse affect on the agricultural competitiveness?

George Dunn: If you don't mind, I would not start where you are. We do not think that Pillar 1 needs further greening from the extent that it already is greened. I know that the Commission thinks otherwise and they want ecological set-aside and permanent pastures introduced. However, Pillar 1, from our perspective, already has a large green element with the cross-compliance requirements. We believe that to add anything more into that situation would tip the balance too far towards the environmental and away from the food security argument, which would cause real detriment to the industry.

Greg Bliss: The other issue with that, of course, is if you are on a tenancy paying a rent, every acre of land or every hectare of land that you have to take out of production is a loss of income to you and the viability of your business, given that you are paying rent on that land. Suddenly, if there were ecological set-aside of 10%; that is 10% of your land that you are paying a rent on. You do not get a decrease in rent on that, regardless. It would be anti-competitive for tenant farmers. It would be a big bash to their business.

George Dunn: It seems so strange that we are expecting this industry to supply things to the general public on a free of charge basis, which is effectively what we are saying should happen. Currently farmers get recompensed to a certain level for making food to high standards within the environment that they are producing in, and now we want them to do something else, but we are going to do that by not giving them any more recompense to provide that. We are expecting them to simply bear that themselves for the public benefit. We would not expect any other industry to provide that sort of model, in terms of providing those goods.

Q62   Mrs Glindon: Is including environmentally friendly measures in the direct support payments the most effective way of improving sustainability in farming?

George Dunn: We argue that they are there already. The current CAP mechanisms, with Pillar 1, the cross-compliance and the elements from Pillar 1, matched with Pillar 2 with all the various schemes for ELS and HLS, are already in place. We do not need to over-egg that pudding any more than has already been done.

Q63   Dan Rogerson: In your evidence you did not really talk about the budget. Are you campaigning for the budget to stay the same?

George Dunn: Yes, we have not got any particular view that the budget should move one way or the other. We cannot see necessarily that the budget is skewed too much one way or the other, so our view would be that it is sustainable at the current level.

Q64   Dan Rogerson: Would you be concerned if Defra do what do what they say they are going to do at the moment, and look to reduce the budget?

George Dunn: Yes, we would, absolutely. Definitely.

Q65   Dan Rogerson: Finally, you have talked in general terms about your views on the Pillars. How do you think the budget should be allocated between Pillar 1 and Pillar 2, and then within Pillar 1, between income support and environmental measures?

George Dunn: Let us take Pillar 1 and Pillar 2 first, and that will differ between Member States because of historic reasons as to how much money they have in their direct funding. The UK has always come out unfavourably in terms of the amount of direct funding it has had, and therefore it has had voluntary modulation to prop it up. There perhaps needs to be a greater degree of consistency across the EU about the percentage of the budget that goes into Pillar 2. From our perspective, we are certainly concerned that farmers are expected to be modulated to a higher degree than other Member States, apart from Portugal, which is using it to a certain extent. But intrinsically, this is an area where we do not have too much skill, in terms of the budget area. We are not campaigning for it to change either up or down.

Q66   George Eustice: When it comes to Pillar 2, is there an issue in that it is something that is much harder for tenant farmers to access? A lot of the schemes tend to be more geared towards owner-occupiers or landowners.

George Dunn: There are a number of aspects and I do not want to bore you for too long in relation to my answer, because it is a particular hobbyhorse for the TFA and us at the moment. The first place is that the rules on management control are a problem, in that if you are a landlord and you are able to pass scheme conditions through a contract or tenancy to a tenant farmer who is farming your holding, has occupation over it and taken the entrepreneurial risk, then you can do that in this country. You cannot do that in Wales, but in England certainly. We think that is wrong. There are many landlords who are claiming agri-environment scheme money, because they can do it by contract or tenancy. Secondly, there are those tenants who are on agreements, as I explained earlier, of less than five years. Most agri-environment schemes require at least a five-year commitment, if not longer. If you are on a tenancy agreement of less than five years, you need to get your landlord's counter­signature on your application. Those counter­signatures are not always easy to come by, because of the landlord's unwillingness to bind himself to something beyond the end of your tenancy. Then we have got the problem, which we have had in the Uplands, for example, where you change the scheme from Hill Farm Allowance (HFA) to Uplands ELS, and you change the nature of who the applicant is, because the landlord has traditionally claimed for ELS on some land in the Uplands. The tenant loses HFA payments, and he cannot get into Uplands ELS, because the landlord is already in ELS on that ground, so he's stymied from getting in.

  Yes, you are right, there is also an element of the interests of the Pillar 2 schemes being about the capital of the holding: the hedges, the ditches, the features and the trees, which tend to be the ones that are excluded from the tenancy agreement in terms of the tenant's responsibility. There is a concern that they are not always geared towards the active farmer.

Q67   George Eustice: Would it almost be better for you if you put more money in Pillar 1, but made it greener? So you did do the greening of Pillar 1.

George Dunn: Yes, but that is not going to happen. Politically, that is simply not going to happen.

Q68   George Eustice: Should it happen? You probably would like that to happen.

Greg Bliss: I think we would much rather have the active farmer. The sensible conversation is that the landlord's income and his recompense is always within the rental agreement. The active farmer takes advantage of all the schemes and then has a grown-up conversation with the landlord, and the landlord takes his income through the rent, rather than taking everything away from the active farmer and him being just left with his own income. That is by far the simplest way of doing it, rather than turning it around and trying to move things from Pillar 1 to Pillar 2. I think it is best to have an active farmer arrangement where he can access all these schemes and then the landlord and he, within their tenancy agreement and their rental, divide it on that basis. Rather than the landlord having sway over it, he can do it in a sensible rental agreement.

George Dunn: It is a much more realistic position to believe that we could get Pillar 2 to work better and more fairly than it does now than it would be to suggest that Pillar 2 should be abolished in favour of a bigger Pillar 1.

Q69   Chair: If the 2011 budget is not agreed this year, would that create problems for your members if we proceed on twelfths?

George Dunn: Again, I had a conversation with a member of the Commissioner's cabinet, and asked him that question about what happens if the budget is not there? Whilst he would not give me the technical detail, he said, "It will be fine." Now, the EU budget arrangements are a little bit beyond our ken.

Q70   Chair: We thought we were quite well briefed last week. What we would like to know is how it would impact on you if it did not proceed by twelfths. It probably will not happen, but would it be very bad news for your members?

George Dunn: We have not got an answer to that question, to be honest. It is beyond our ken.

Q71   Chair: No, that is fine. Earlier this afternoon we heard that UK farmers could become more competitive by selling value-added products, which make use of higher environmental standards. Do you agree? Do you think UK consumers would pay, even if it was labelled up, "This is someone who has participated in an EU agri-monetary scheme?" Do you think that would work?

George Dunn: Greg will be able to talk to you about the commodity markets that he is involved with and the sorts of contracts that he has got with potato processors and so on. What I would say is that there will always be room in the marketplace for people who want to supply very high environmental, animal welfare, provenance foods to a very niche market. But I am afraid the vast majority of people, despite what we hear and see in the press, still buy on price. The vast majority of commodities sold through supermarkets are sold on price. There have been consumer studies done where people have been asked, before they go into a shop, what they are going to buy in terms of animal welfare and the environment, and then what is in their baskets on the way out does not really fit very well with what they said they were going to buy on the way in. That is not necessarily because they told lies, but when they get into the supermarket they are faced with a plethora of choices on a shelf, they have got the kids screaming behind them, and they lift what they think is the right thing. There may be co-mingling of commodities so that you have got English and foreign commodities on the same shelf. So there are lots of issues as to why we do not necessarily think it is going to be a big issue for most people, particularly where you are making commodity products.

Greg Bliss: I think it is a very limited market. You seem to have a choice: you either produce on a large scale on a small margin or you produce on a small scale and increase your margin. You work just as hard and your marketing has to be just as good. You will find that even on large-scale commodity production, they will provide another hoop for every one that you have had to jump through. Once you get up to Tesco Gold Standard you can spend three days in your office doing your welfare check and making sure that you have no child labour on your farms. It is quite interesting because you do not realise just how many hurdles you have to jump just to get through, just in assured schemes.

George Dunn: If you look at it in detail and take, for example, the milk market. I challenged Sainsbury's on this the other day. Sainsbury's have a dedicated supply chain with 300 or 400 farmers who supposedly provide milk, and they can make great claims about that to their consumers as they walk through Sainsbury's stores. But in fact, all the milk that Sainsbury's get comes from a processor who is pooling the milk with other producers. It is exactly the same milk.

Q72   Chair: I know George probably strayed on to this, but is there any further action that you think is required to actually help and recognise the system of land ownership and management that we have in this country, in terms of CAP reform?

George Dunn: I think at an EU level, we just need to make sure that there is sufficient scope within the regulatory texts when they come to identify the rightful recipient of any CAP support financing. So long as we have this concept of the active farmer developed, that will recognise the fact that that individual is the person who is the rightful recipient.

Q73   Chair: That is really helpful. Off the wall and on a different matter, obviously my area and many other parts of the country have been very badly affected by the weather. Have you been contacted by your members about problems with actually feeding animals and the cost of feeding animals, bearing in mind that this weather normally does not happen before January and February?

George Dunn: Well, the issue is much wider than that.

Greg Bliss: We have got sugar beet that is in the ground and frozen that will never get in for process, and there are thousands of acres throughout the east that are in that same situation. That is just a loss of income through bad luck because it was not harvested. It is not just sugar beet; everything that you cannot get into the field to get is just going by the wayside.

George Dunn: We have got people who are finding it difficult to get their milk collected and people who are finding it difficult to get out and feed their stock. There are a plethora of issues.

Greg Bliss: With wheat going up to £200 a tonne, the cost of feeding chickens isn't chicken feed.

Q74   Chair: I am particularly concerned about the sheep on the moors and that more of them will be kept out. Of course, whether the farmers can even get to them is another matter.

Greg Bliss: Well the hay price has doubled and the straw price has doubled since this weather came on, and that is if you can get it delivered.

Chair: That is helpful information. Thank you very much for being with us, and I am sure we will be in contact again.


 
previous page contents


© Parliamentary copyright 2011
Prepared 15 April 2011