The Common Agricultural Policy after 2013 - Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Committee Contents


Written evidence submitted by the Scottish Agricultural College (SAC)

INTRODUCTION

SAC (Scottish Agricultural College) welcomes the opportunity to contribute to the Environment, Food and Rural Affairs (EFRA) Committee Inquiry into the impact of Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) reform on UK agriculture.

SAC is an innovative, knowledge-based organisation that supports the rural sector through research, education and expert consultancy services. SAC wishes to see, and contribute significantly to delivering, a sustainable agricultural and rural land use sector in Scotland. SAC staff work in a broad range of areas (for more information see www.sac.ac.uk) and our responses to the questions below reflect this broad expertise, but draw on specific research projects where appropriate.

Several SAC staff have contributed to this submission which has been co-ordinated by SAC's Rural Policy Centre (www.sac.ac.uk/ruralpolicycentre/).

GENERAL COMMENTS ON THE COMMISSION'S PROPOSALS

The Commission's Communication proposes three different options for the future of the CAP which can be summarised as: Option 1 which introduces further gradual changes to the current policy framework; Option 2 which captures the opportunity for reform and makes major overhauls of the policy; and Option 3 which involves more far-reaching reform of the CAP with a strong focus on environmental and climate change objectives. The Communication does not offer a great deal of detail on any of the three options, or how they might be implemented. Some initial comments:

Option 1 seems to suggest only minor changes to the current CAP and it is likely that following this approach will simply delay inevitable reform. Farmers across Europe are expecting the 2013 reforms to bring major changes and it seems the Commission could take advantage of that and make some crucial changes in setting the future direction of the CAP, which will help to satisfy the wishes of both producers and consumers.

Option 2 shares some similarities to the recent Pack Inquiry in Scotland (see http://www.scotland.gov.uk/Topics/farmingrural/Agriculture/inquiry).

Option 3 represents a more radical shake-up of the CAP which would create significant economic, environmental and social implications as rural business managers attempt to adapt to the type of regime that would result from implementing this option.

In terms of responses to the Commission's proposals and to the Committee's specific questions, SAC would refer the Committee to the recent Pack Inquiry and its Report into the future of agricultural support in Scotland. The report includes a large amount of background information about the agricultural industry and current levels of support in Scotland, and sets out one possible approach to tailoring financial support to agriculture and rural development in Scotland post-2013. The Inquiry's interim, short-term recommendations and final reports, and background evidence papers, are all available via the Inquiry website at:
http://www.scotland.gov.uk/Topics/farmingrural/Agriculture/inquiry.

How will the Commission's proposals affect the ability of UK agriculture to be competitive in a global market?

All three options imply an underlying requirement for increasing productivity and efficiency on farms. There is a wide variation in performance across farms in the UK within farm type and even within size bands and all three options would help to focus attention on improving resource usage. This is perhaps most explicit in the second option whereby the New Zealand experience suggests that market reform may lead to an improvement of efficiency with little loss of farms (although ancillary industries may suffer).New Zealand is generally considered an exemplar for withdrawal from public funding for agriculture as, since 1987, the farming sector has operated under no public subsidies, aside from money allocated towards supporting research and development. Whereas some structural change occurred after the removal of subsidies, it is notable that agricultural productivity increased by an average of 5.9% per annum since the removal of subsidies, whereas before, gains were around 1% per year.[22] This has to be treated with caution, however, as the UK (or Scotland) is not New Zealand, but some residual effect must lead to reducing the variance in performance.

In recent research work on efficiency,[23] SAC found there is a great deal of efficiency to be realised within size bands (ie. smaller farms could get more efficient without changing size). Hence Option 1 on redistribution may promote this if it were structured to support resource use efficiency.

The recent Pack Inquiry in Scotland argued in favour of maintaining direct payments to enable Scottish farmers to remain competitive in the global market. Until decoupling is adopted across the global agricultural market, Scottish (and indeed UK) farmers will not be able to compete.

Overall, a strategic approach is required to policy-making that promotes a more competitive, market-oriented agricultural sector at the same time as addressing environmental and other concerns, including the operation of food supply chains that often prevent farmers from receiving a fair share of the added value of their products.

Do the proposals ensure fair competition for British agricultural products within the European Union?

Option 2 outlines the introduction of more equity in the distribution of direct payments between member states. This would contribute towards fairer competition between British agricultural products and the EU. However, market distortions exist between countries as a result of other factors, including variations in animal welfare standards and other legislative requirements.

More broadly, it is essential that across the food supply chain, a more equitable and stable distribution of value is obtained.

Will the proposals achieve the correct balance between productivity and sustainability?

Option 3 focuses on greening the CAP whereby efficiency and productivity become part of a wider suite of indicators. Option 2 may be the reverse of this as it may encourage farms to become larger which would certainly have an impact on social sustainability. However, Option 1 may provide the opposite, and perhaps redistribution may lead to support for High Nature Value farms (which are usually small by standard criteria) and hence ecological improvements. On the other hand, this approach may undermine the UK's ability to respond to future food security concerns.

Work by SAC staff in collaboration with partners in 2008 explored the environmental impacts of Pillar 1 reform and the potential implications for Pillar 2 funding.[24] The report of this work can be provided on request.

More generally, a competitive and sustainable agricultural industry is important in underpinning rural communities across the UK, but particularly in some of the more remote communities of Scotland where agriculture remains a critically important industry, in both economic and social terms. Taking into account the diversity of the industry across both Scotland and the UK, CAP reform in line with Option 2 (which includes a greater emphasis on targeted measures and encourages the addressing of economic, social and environmental challenges) might be perceived to be the preferred option.

Do the proposals place the UK in a good position to help meet future food supply challenges?

Again, the focus on productivity would help this. Future food supply challenges very much depend on what happens elsewhere around the world. However, there is growing consensus that population growth, climate change, diminishing resources (especially water and oil), differential economic development around the globe and interactions between these factors will increase pressures on food supply. This situation will increase market and production risk in agriculture, potentially exacerbating the problems. Agricultural policy has traditionally addressed the particular risk management problems that farmers face, creating a more stable business environment that encourages investment and thus maintains consistent supply. The challenge of increasing risk in future food supply must be competently addressed by policy. There is a danger of this aspect being given inadequate provision in all policy options, arguably more so in those that focus away from food production. Promoting global free trade in agricultural commodities at a time of rapid change without attendant market volatilities and associated crises will be a key objective for future policy. It is therefore essential to expand on the details of the "risk management toolkit" proposed by the Commission, examine all the options involved and ensure that the concept is underpinned by on-going research and development.

The recent Pack Inquiry highlighted the dependence of Scotland's agricultural industry on direct payments. In broad terms, SAC believes that the principle of decoupling as a means of freeing farmers to react to the market is sound. There may, however, be situations where some form of coupled support is the best and most efficient way to deal with a particular problem and to maintain the profitability and competitiveness of farms. If the working of the market led to the collapse of the livestock sector in an area, coupled payments might be justifiable to ensure food supplies or to support the sector and ancillary industries in a period of transition.

A recent report (2008) by SAC ("Farming's Retreat from the Hills")[25] has highlighted the potential economic, environmental and social impacts of the decline in livestock numbers in the hill and island areas of Scotland. There are potentially negative impacts on local communities of livestock depopulation and while there are a variety of ways for dealing with these problems, one option could be some form of coupled payment.[26]

More broadly, it is critical that funding for science and innovation in universities and other research organisations and institutes is maintained to underpin actions to meet future supply challenges. This research is critical across numerous areas, including the production of crops and livestock but also wider issues such as climate change, biodiversity, water quality etc.

Will the proposals redress the imbalance in support to different sectors created by the historic basis of payments?

It is unclear if by sectors, the Committee means enterprises. If so, it could be argued that Option 1 aims to achieve this, whilst Option 2 with more market reform could lead to the opposite.

More generally, SAC would reiterate arguments made by others (including the Pack Inquiry) that the further we move away from the reference period that underpins the historic model, the more difficult it is to justify such an approach to direct payments.

What aspects of the proposals should be made a common policy, and which are best left to Member States?

SAC believes maintaining a common Europe-wide policy is important, as too much discretion to member states risks creating a system in which the design and implementation of the policy across member states becomes hugely variable, thus increasing complexity and potentially distorting competition. This common EU framework is arguably particularly important in terms of direct support and market measures (ie Pillar 1).

At the same time, it is important to recognise that some flexibility is required, including in the use of measures such as the national envelope whereby regions within member states have the flexibility to target funds at key issues and areas.

The increased flexibility could potentially be used to provide some form of additional support for livestock farmers and crofters in High Nature Value areas (large parts of Scotland could be classified as High Nature Value farmland). Recent work by SAC2 has highlighted the decline in livestock numbers and the potential impact on farming, biodiversity and communities. The greatest changes in livestock are taking place in those areas that also have the highest nature value, but which are also vulnerable to wider economic pressures. The degree to which the national envelope should be used to target such problems will depend on the degree to which they are addressed through other mechanisms (eg in Pillar 2).

It should also be noted that increased flexibility in the use of the national envelope has potentially redistributive effects with money effectively taken from all Single Farm Payments and redistributed towards specific sectors or areas. Clarity of objectives will be crucial in using the national envelope in the most equitable and transparent way.

Can the proposals be implemented simply and cost-effectively, within a short time-scale?

Option 3 suggests a requirement for more indicators which are expensive to collect and the present system (eg using the Farm Business Survey or Agricultural Census data) is inadequate at capturing these effects. Option 2 may represent the cheapest option, which could be argued to be the main aim of creating a more financially sustainable CAP. Taken at face value, Option 1 which advocates gradual changes to the CAP is likely to be the least costly option.

The existing CAP is a complex policy and it is important that changes to it do not increase the burden of bureaucracy on farmers, nor increase the costs to other stakeholders. Maintaining common elements to the policy ensures that there is lessened risk of costly variations in design and implementation between member states.

More generally, it is important to reiterate that agriculture and land management receive support and are regulated because the sustainable production of food and management of land cannot be left to the market alone. Governments intervene in the sector through the CAP to deal with various forms of market failure, such as situations when the market cannot secure food supplies or when agricultural incomes become very low and threaten the sustainability of food production. The CAP is therefore a tool for dealing with different forms of market failure and, given the importance of ensuring sustainable food production and land management, there will continue to be a role for government intervention in some form.

Historically the majority of CAP funding has been channelled into Pillar 1 although some have argued for a gradual movement of money from Pillar 1 to broader rural development and environmental measures in Pillar 2. As the issue of food security becomes increasingly important, securing food production must continue to be a high priority.

In this context, assuming that all three of the EU options retain the two Pillar structure, SAC believes that the current structure whereby one pillar aims to secure food production and the other aims to support rural development and environmental measures, provides a workable model (notwithstanding criticisms of this as creating an artificial distinction between agricultural support and rural development). Any future policy changes to the structure and objectives of the CAP to pursue any of the three options outlined by the Commission will require a robust and clear evidence base.

January 2011


22   Federated Farmers of New Zealand (2002) Life after Subsidies: The New Zealand Farming Experience 15 Years Later. Available online at: www.fedfarm.org.nz. Back

23   This work is currently being finalised. Some of the findings were presented by Dr Andrew Barnes at the Defra-AES conference in December 2010. Dr Barnes' slides are available online at:
http://www.aes.ac.uk/index.php?do=events&sub=events2. 
Back

24   ADAS, SAC and RPA (2008) Estimating the Environmental Impacts of Pillar 1 Reform and the Potential Implications for Axis II funding. Back

25   This report is available online at:
http://www.sac.ac.uk/ruralpolicycentre/publs/thrivingcommunitiespublications/retreatfromthehills/ 
Back

26   An update of this report is currently being prepared and will be available on the Rural Policy Centre website
(www.sac.ac.uk/ruralpolicycentre) by the end of February 2011. 
Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2011
Prepared 15 April 2011