The Common Agricultural Policy after 2013 - Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Committee Contents


Written evidence submitted by Country Land and Business Association (CLA)

CLA GENERAL VIEW OF THE REFORM PROPOSALS

1.    The CLA's 35,000 members in England and Wales are all directly or indirectly affected by the Common Agricultural Policy. We have been heavily involved in the debates over the last two years leading to the publication of this Communication. As the paper was only published on 18 November we have not been able to consult our members so these comments are provisional.

2.    The CLA's public reaction to the document has been to say that is broadly on the right tracks. The paper suggests three rather sketchily explained options: (i) some adjustment and more equity; (ii) major overhaul of the policy and (iii) far reaching reform to move away from income support and market measures. It seems clear to us that the right option is the middle one and indeed this is the only one on which any ideas are explored by the Commission. The status quo in option 1 does not respond to the real reform pressures, and option 3, what has been describes as the "British/Swedish" vision of eliminating Pillar 1, has plainly commanded no general support despite being on offer for five years.

3.    The main indication of the direction of Commission thinking is in the section entitled future instruments. The Commission is adamant that the CAP must retain the two pillar structure but we have suggested not being dogmatic about the character and purpose of the two pillars or talking about good and bad Pillars.

4.    A key part of Commission thinking is that the new CAP must do more for public goods, and furthermore that this should be focussed in the next reform by an overhaul of Pillar 1. They are not proposing further shift of resources to Pillar 2. There is no suggestion of more modulation - compulsory or voluntary. This marks a significant change in direction to the strategy since 1999. Second the paper seems to be suggesting that the "targeting" in Pillar 1 should have two components. The first a general approach across the whole territory (perhaps akin to English entry level stewardship, or the Austrian base level of stewardship), and the other is support for farming in what we currently call the Less Favoured Areas.

5.    These broad ideas were more or less exactly the approach suggested to the Commission in the CLA response in July through our European organisation. So we naturally applaud that this is the Commission's suggested direction.

6.    This said, the paper is very light on details and there are many very important points with which we have serious difficulty. These concern: payment ceilings, any narrowly defined concept of active farmers; the balance between the proposed new components of the single payment; the obsession with annual payments for multi-annual commitments in Pillar 1; the treatment of LFAs; the lack of detail about any redistribution of funds within and between the pillars and the fate of modulation, and the scope for distorting competition by remaining coupled payments. We also point out that our support for the broad direction of reform and commitments to providing more public eco-system services is conditional on the appropriate resources being available to cover the real costs of their delivery.

TURNING TO THE QUESTIONS POSED

Impact on UK's agriculture's capacity for being internationally competitive?

7.    The main CAP measures helping competitiveness are in the current axis 1 of pillar 2, there are no new measures spelled out in the document. So the proposals are broadly neutral in this regard. It is of course of concern to farmers that if they are asked to provide non-market environmental or indeed 'social' services in addition to being competitive producers of food, fibre and energy, then they must be properly paid for such services or this could indeed impede their international competitiveness in agricultural products. But also see paragraph 10 below.

Do the proposals ensure fair competition within the single market?

8.    They have to. This is imperative and it is the Commission's job to ensure that fair competition in the Single Market is maintained. This is one reason why it is right to consider putting the broad-application, basic, stewardship programme into Pillar 1. This ensures it has common rules across the EU as proposed in the mandatory Greening component. But of course the more the CAP is involved in the complex business of paying for environmental co-products of agricultural production the more complex this task inevitably becomes. This is why it is vital that there are common programmes and standards applied within a common agricultural policy. Inevitably farmers in each country will always suspect that EU rules are being more rigorously applied in their own territory than in other Member States.

Will the proposals achieve the right balance between productivity and sustainability?

9.    There is no structural reason to suggest these ideas will prevent this right balance being struck but there is plenty of scope for the negotiation process to push too far in one or other direction. The big underlying proposition in this reform is that the current balance in the CAP is insufficiently weighted in the direction of environment sustainability. However, we must remember that agricultural produce are highly tradable and many other big agricultural producing and exporting regions are seemingly not as concerned with the sustainability agenda as the EU. There is a very real danger that we could overload our producers, impeding their economic competitiveness and thus sustainability. Again it gets back to the appropriate resources for delivering the higher environmental services mandated. The resource question lies outside the CAP reform in the EU Budget debate. Our fear is that the UK will set extremely high ambitions and expect them to be delivered from an unreasonably low budget, which will merely export the unsustainable food production somewhere else.

Will the proposals redress the imbalance in support to different sectors created by historic supports?

10.  The difficulty in answering this question is that there is no strong consensus about what the ideal balance of support should be. There will be disagreements about the distribution of supports as between the crop and livestock sectors; between the uplands and lowlands; between paying for environmental services and agricultural production. Also the proposals are encouraging further discussion about small versus large farms, and of course the "equity" of the distribution between member states and, by extension, between regions within member states. As a member organisation with members crossing all these divides it is very difficult to be definitive. There is no doubt that these distributional discussions will be at the heart of the discussions of this reform. There will inevitably be losers and gainers from the reforms; that is the nature of redistribution and so differences in view about whether imbalances have been redressed.

What aspects of the proposals should be common policy and which left to the Member States?

11.   The CLA considers that all aspect of the new proposals in this document must be part of a common policy because repatriation of measures will lead to market distortions. Note that there is no contradiction between this statement and the present feature of Pillar 2 that the balance of measures adopted from menus of options are selected by regions and member states and adapted to their conditions. The CAP has long developed the capacity to create common frameworks within which local requirements can be fitted.

Can the proposals be implemented simply and cost-effectively within a short time scale?

12.  They have to be. There is no choice in this. Note that what the CAP is seeking to do is not simple. It is perhaps misguided to elevate simplicity to be a top-level objective. The present Single Payment System at its heart was a simple replacement for a bewildering battery of commodity price supports. The core of new proposals is to better target these payments referring to sustainability. Sustainability is a subtle and complex mix of economic, environmental and social objectives. The environment itself contains some really complex interactions between biodiversity, landscape, heritage, water and soil protection and climate stabilisation. To expect this to be simple is to create false expectations. Regarding timeliness, it is vital that any new legislative proposals are agreed by the end of 2012 because we have learned from bitter experience that the Defra needs plenty of time for the administrative and IT preparations to implement changed regulations.

December 2010

Supplementary written evidence submitted by the Country Land and Business Association (CLA)

1.  Your evidence expresses concerns about payment ceilings. How would you change the negative public perception about landowners who receive very large CAP payouts?

By explaining and demonstrating with examples how large land managers contribute enormously to UK, EU and global food security and how they also provide large scale environmental management. We can cite the miles of hedgerows, hectares of copses, ponds, field margins and corners devoted to biodiversity and so on for large farms and estates.

2.  Could you expand your statement that the existing EU regulations are sufficient to prevent non-agricultural land, eg golf courses, from receiving subsidies—do you mean as applied in the UK, or across all Member States? How does this sit with the EU Court of Auditors (2009) recommendation?

We attach a note on Active Farmers we are in the course of preparing - that cites the EU regulation and the UK implementing rules which, in our view, very adequately prevent patently non-agricultural land being claimed for single payment. The UK rules based on the EU regulation could in principle be applied everywhere.

Our understanding is that one of the kinds of possible abuse could involve tenants who have stacked historical entitlements onto small areas they own. They may have given up their (usually) livestock business on the original rented land on which their historic claims were based, and may have effectively given up farming. This leaves the formerly grazed land devoid of support payments. The move away from historic entitlements will put a stop to this, so no change in definition of active farmer are necessary.

Another example of possible abuse of the system is from the millions of landowners who have had their land resituated to them in the land privatisation post- communism, but who are living in cities and not farming.

We suggest none of these sorts of cases are likely to apply in England where we are moving to regional payments. In England there has been reference to situations where the landowner makes the Single Payment Claim, yet he is not the owner of the animals grazing his land. This certainly can be the case where short term grazing licensees or people with commoners grazing rights are the keepers of the animals. But in such cases the graziers have the rights solely to graze. The roads, fences, drainage, water provision, hedge maintenance, heather burning and other grazing management, and all other environmental management can only be carried out by the active land manager, the owner. Therefore it is perfectly legitimate in principle that he can be the payment claimant. This is why it is important to have the full details of the rights and responsibilities of all parties before jumping to conclusions.

Another situation where some discussion might arise is where there is a contract farming arrangement in place. This is now extremely common in British arable farming. Here the tractor work, cultivations, planting and harvesting may be done by the contractor (who may well be a neighbouring farmer who owns or rents his own land), but the owner of the farm in question is the SPS claimant. This is perfectly sensible specialisation and division of labour involving each party deciding what aspect of his assets and management skills and interests to deploy in the business. The owner/claimant is actively involved in the management and risk taking in the farming business and he also will generally be ensuring all the farming infrastructure; roads, drains, fences and other needed plant and equipment are in place. He also will be taking care of the environmental land management. Note that the division of the public receipts will then be "shared", as they should be in a market economy, as a result of market negotiations between the parties according to the contributions and risks borne by each. There is absolutely no need or utility in EU regulations getting involved in such arrangements.

3.  You referred to EU level research on the funding needed to support environmental schemes, could you supply the reference and/or report?

The three main pieces of research we are aware of are detailed below.

(i)  An internal Defra project conducted in 2009-10, as part of their Pillar 2 planning, to think through what environmental services we want from UK agriculture, what sort of policy measures would be optimally deployed to deliver such services and the overall cost of delivery. To our knowledge this enlightened and innovative piece of research to which we gave prominent reference (with Defra blessing) in our paper "Public Goods from Private Land", was never published but they may be able to tell you about it.

(ii)  A paper, Estimating the scale of future environmental and land management for the UK, conducted by ADAS and SAC for the Land Use Policy Group (LUPG) in December 2009 examines the costs of farmers providing the desired environmental services in the UK. The conclusions of this research were that the costs were approximately three times greater than the current UK expenditure on delivering public goods through environment schemes, ie about £1.98 billion compared to about £700 milliion on agri-environment.

(iii)  We have informally heard that there is a currently a DG Environment project which has similar objectives as the LUPG study but for the EU27. There are no results available from this study which we understand is still underway.

This sort of research is of course very difficult and has to be based on difficult assumptions. But nevertheless we strongly believe that rational decision making should indeed start from the goals society wants; estimates of what it might cost to deliver such goals and then decisions about budgets allocated to different tasks.

4.  Do you think the sort of compulsory environmental activities proposed by the Commission, such as crop rotation or set-aside, will deliver real and demonstrable environmental benefits?

Across the EU27, certainly they would provide significant and worthwhile environmental benefits. We are in no doubt about this. There are farming systems in operation in a number of parts of the EU where these basic practices are not used so the mechanisms listed under the Mandatory Greening (MG) could improve environmental performance.

Our point is that some Member States—including the UK—especially England—already have well developed entry level stewardship schemes which already do most of these things and are thus already seeing their benefit. Indeed we would claim ELS goes well beyond what is proposed for mandatory greening, especially if the Campaign for the farmed Environment is then added. We would not want MG therefore to cause difficulties for precisely the countries (UK, Austria and Sweden for example) who are already doing the right thing to have the greatest difficulty. Our view is that this greening s best done in voluntary, multi-annual contractual arrangements and not as the Communications speaks, of mandatory, annual non-contractual arrangements. There is much to play for here to protect UK interests, but we don't quarrel with the Commission's aims.

5.  Your evidence refers to the role of the CAP in paying for the provision of public goods, specifically environmental, by land management. By extension, where do you draw the line between land managers that are not necessarily farming, and other activities that use land and may provide some public goods as well?

We have tried to address this in our answer above on active farmers. In essence we should let the land manager decide what mix of food production and environmental services he will supply. The market determines the price of food and collectively through the processes of determining the CAP budget and payment rates for environmental public goods the "public" decides how mush to incentivise the delivery of the public goods. This is fundamentally no different than the way we decide how much public health or educational services we are going to deliver, except here the environmental public goods are competing for land use and managerial time with food production.

Our point is that there will be some farmers who almost exclusively produce food (eg on the very best land or in protected crops) and at the other extreme there will be environmental land managers who almost exclusively provide environmental services (but just have some animals to provide the grazing to maintain grassland swards and the treading function - eg to keep bracken down). Most "farmers" lie between these extremes depending on their conditions and mix of land types. The policy and payments can in principle deal with this whole range. But we must not in a decoupled payment system try to dictate the mix to the person who knows best and who is taking the business risks, the land manager.

6.  Do you think that the "food security" (referring to quantity and quality) needs of European citizens are better served through increasing EU production, or enhancing trade networks?

Both, there is no either/or here. European contribution to global food security demands we protect and develop our food production capacity (not our current production. The latter is decided by the commercial decisions of farmers based on current costs and returns). Our production capacity is based on keeping our agricultural land in good agricultural and environmental conditions (a very intelligent phrase in our view), and keeping our farming infrastructure in good order, plus our knowledge and skills base and the flow of Research and Development. But open trade networks are also an intelligent global food security mechanism. Climate induced food shortages will generally not all happen everywhere in the world at the same time so the more developed is the infrastructure for trade (roads, ports, handling facilities, shipping, insurance) then the faster the global system can react to shortage wherever it occurs.

Of course anything which inhibits trade slows down this response and makes it harder for markets to ration out the available supplies. Note that whereas twenty years ago some of the biggest inhibitions to trade were pernicious import restrictions like variable import levies (long since abolished in the EU), and state trading systems, now the biggest source of trade instability is the use of export restrictions—and potentially land grabs which try to take trade outside conventional international trading systems.

7.  What criteria could be used to allocate national ceilings, both for pillar 1 and pillar 2, more objectively between Member States?

Because the criteria have to be based on robust data which is available for all 27 Member States we think that the obvious criteria are based on agricultural area (utilised agricultural land), a proxy indicator of costs of living or wage levels like GDP per head, and perhaps if the policy goal is increasingly emphasising the public goods the environmentally designated areas or areas engaged in environment schemes. If greening is to apply more to Pillar 1 in future (it is already in there, and is of course the main part of axis 2 of Pillar 2), then there is little point in using different criteria for the two pillars. Indeed we urge a very pragmatic approach to these structures. They should serve policy goals not inhibit them.

January 2011


 
previous page contents next page


© Parliamentary copyright 2011
Prepared 14 April 2011